Lives of Labor
Work in a Maturing Industrial Society
PETER N. STEARNS
For Patricia, who helped the whole thing
©1975
ISBN 0-8419-0192-9
CONTENTS
Tables vii
Introduction 1
Part I: The Framework for Labor
1. The Evolution of the Labor Force 19
2. Job Choice in a Maturing Industrial Economy 45
3. Unemployment 85
Conclusion 114
Part II: Forces for Change
4. Technology 121
5. Relationships with Employers 148
6. A Frenzied Pace 193
Conclusion 229
Part III: Reactions and Compensations
Introduction 239
7. Reducing Work Time 241
8. Off the Job: Family and Consumption Patterns 269
9. Protest 300
Part IV: Towards the Future of the Working Class
10. Conclusion 335
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
I would like to thank the American Philosophical Society and the Social Science Research Council for grants that supported much of the research for this book. The Research Councils of the University of Chicago and Rutgers University provided valuable assistance as well, as did the Computer Laboratory of Rutgers University. Research on workers' aging was part of a larger project supported by the John Simon Guggenheim Memorial Foundation.
A number of people helped in the chore of pulling together statistical data: Lawrence Gurman, Robyn Levine, Roseann Erck, and Howard Zehr. For some calculations I was fortunate in having a domestic putting-out system, and my thanks go to Deborah Stearns, Nancy Uttrachi, and Duncan Stearns. My typist, Margaret Harmon, was consistently helpful. I am, finally, grateful to Patricia Branca Uttrachi for her careful reading of the manuscript and her many suggestions.
TABLES
Chapter 1 :
I Evaluation of the Industrial Labor Force
(Manufacturing and Transport Occupations) 24
II Patterns of Industrial Growth: Summary and
Comparative Tables 26
III Women in Industry: Summary and Comparative Tables 30
— IV Employment of Children 34
V Domestic Manufacturing Workers and Employers 37
Chapter 3:
I Annual Unemployment Rates 91
II Trends in Unemployment 102
Chapter 5:
I Differences in Company Size 155
II Company Size: Comparative Suggestions 156
HI Evolution of Company Size 157
IV Evolution of Company Size: Summary 161
V Strikes for Dismissals (or More General Personal Issues) 184
Chapter 9:
I Demand Rate 305
II Industrial Variations in Leading Demands, 1899—1914 306
III Evolution of Strike Rate 314
IV Industrial Strike Rates, 1899-1914 316
Part IV:
I Characteristics of Industrial Categories 341
Appendix: Chapter 1
I Distortions in Census Data: Employed Personnel
Alone Compared to General Totals 358
II Patterns of Industrial Growth 360
HI Women in Industry 365
IV Married Women in Industry 369
Appendix: Chapter 9
I Britain: Evolution of Strikes, 1899--1914 372
II Britain: Rate of Demands and Results in Key Industries,
1899-1914 374
III Britain: Rate of Demands and Results in Key Industries,
over Time 375
IV France: Evolution of Strike Rate, Demands, Results 377
V France: Industrial Incidence of Strikes 379
VI France: Evolution of the Rate of Strike Failures 380
VII Germany: Evolution of Strike Rates and Results 381
VIII Germany: Incidence of Demands and Results, by
Industry, 1901-1913 383
IX Germany: Losses per Demand 385
X Germany: Lockouts, 1901-1913 385
XI Germany: Trade Union Statistics 386
XII Germany: Trade Unions, Demands and Results 388
XIII Germany: Trade Unions, Patterns in Selected Industries, 1901-1913 389
XIV Belgium: Incidence of Strikes and Strike Demands 390
XV Belgium: Patterns in Selected Industries, 1899-1913 392
XVI Belgium: Demands and Results, 1899-1913: Strike
Losses 394
INTRODUCTION
This is a study of work, and workers' reaction to work, from the 1890s until World War I, in four countries: Britain, Belgium, Germany and France. The topic is obviously not unprecedented. Earlier studies of industrialization commonly discussed the outlines of the work situation, stressing such elements as hours of work, safety conditions, and employment of women and children.1 More recently, scholars such as E. P. Thompson have attempted to get at the nature of the industrial work experience, the psychic as well as material aspects that would strike a worker entering factory employment for the first time.2
Studies of this sort are immensely valuable and form an important precedent for the present effort. But with rare exceptions they have focused on the first stage of industrialization, when it seems reasonable to assume that the encounter between traditional concepts of work and the pressure of the factories was most abrasive. Relatedly, the emphasis has been on difficulties, of adaptation, on the compulsion under which workers were placed to convert them to effective instruments of industrial labor.3
Far less attention has been given to the more mature period of industrialization that opened up after the 1870s. Some outlines are familiar, of course. The growing size of the unit of employment presumably heightened impersonality at work and encouraged a more rigorous supervision of the labor force. New technology intruded even into the artisanal trades, converting some, such as shoe manufacture, into factory operations and reducing or altering skill levels in others. In all branches of manufacturing, this was a period of speed-u p, in which human arrangements were changed, beyond the requirements of machines themselves, in an effort to increase productivity.4 At the same time, some of the problems that have preoccupied labor historians during the earlier period now had a reduced impact; notably, the standard of living rose, though its extent can be debated, particularly for the years of inflation that opened up after 1900. Yet with rare exceptions the details of this framework have not been filled in. Economic historians have dealt only fleetingly with the workers, while labor historians have been consumed by a desire to trace the intricacies of rising socialist parties and trade unions.
It seems increasingly obvious that social historians must shift some of their attention from the early industrial period to more recent times. Fascination with the first shock of change has obscured the treatment of the more immediate background to our own age. At the time when concern for the quality of work is spreading once more, it is desirable to know something of the evolution of labor as industry matured. This study is not just a somewhat more proximate slice of a familiar subject. The evolution of industrial work was not steady during the nineteenth century. Many workers were brought into an essentially industrial work system, not in the first phase of industrialization but only at the century's end. Others had been forced into new kinds of labor much earlier, particularly in the factories, but had developed systems of adaptation, in the work place itself, that were challenged severely after the 1880s. Both aspects of this new stage of adaptation form vital parts of this study.
Among the workers newly encountering an industrial work system, there were three major types: new migrants, traditional unskilled groups, and artisans. Newcomers were constantly pouring into the factories. Particularly in Germany and Trance, this frequently reproduced the interaction between traditional work patterns and a new and intensiye work system; the contrast may indeed have been more vivid than ever before, given the sophistication of the technology and management that could now be applied even to new workers.5 Ironically, this was not the group of workers that felt the greatest strain at work. New, unskilled workers from an essentially traditional background, like Silesian miners employed in the Ruhr, could manifest far less anxiety about their industrial setting than their colleagues who had greater experience on the job. Among other things, they were accustomed to long hours on the job. Agricultural workers in East Prussia, for example, still worked from five in the morning until sundown, with only two hours' respite.6 Many immigrants felt tension in the new setting, but their pattern of life frequently allowed immediate redress, for, sometimes at their own choice, sometimes by compulsion, they alternated periods of work and leisure. In essence, by changing jobs and moving they restored some of the aspects of seasonality to which they had been accustomed. Thus large groups of workers, even in advanced industries such as metallurgy, fought with some success to preserve a traditional concept of work.
At least as interesting to our purposes are workers touched by new expectations or prodded into them by radical changes in the work setting. These could include immigrants, like the Dorset agricultural
laborers who poured into the mines of Wales, attracted by clear notions of rising pay rather than being forced out of the countryside by sheer population pressure.7 They embrace many unskilled workers who become part of the working class toward the end of the nineteenth century precisely because their traditional systems of labor are challenged. Dockers in Hamburg found their work becoming newly-intense during the 1890s. They previously had maintained solid ties with surrounding villages, but now they had either to abandon the countryside or suffer absences from their families for days at a time. For the docks were now mammoth in their extent. And the pace of work picked up, with new loading machines and more rigorous supervision.8 Their reaction was to mount an unprecedented protest effort, asking for regular and reduced hours. But this too posed problems, for it violated traditional work patterns that called for periodic, rather than regular, physical output.9 The next decades, and not only in Germany, would see recurrent tension between pressures from the outside, including a new technology, a traditional willingness to accept long but irregular periods of labor, and a new system of regular, limited, but intense work which industrialization and the labor movement both had to encourage. Similar tensions crop up in other areas of transportation work, including even the railroads, and among unskilled construction and factory workers. We are aware of them through movements for reduced hours, such as the London dock strike of 1889 or Scottish railway agitation during the 1890s. We can, by studying work itself, go beneath these important movements to ask why they proliferate in this period and not before — for the number of workers who suddenly declare that twelve- or fourteen-hou r work days have become inappropriate, despite their long standing in the trade, is astonishing — and what they mean in terms of the Larger work experience.
Journeymen, such as bakers or skilled construction workers, had clearly undergone intense stress in the first phase of industrialization. The work systems we find them defending around 1900 were not purely traditional. But part of the furor that has been eloquently described by labor historians of the earlier period involved trades that were dying; those that survived maintained strong traces of traditional protective devices. Hence English craft unions — in construction, furniture, hat manufacture, brass, — had long regulated hours and amount of production, the number of apprentices per worker, and so on.10 Artisans maintained traditional residential patterns, either clustering in the center city, as Charles Booth found to be the case
among London bookbinders and shoemakers,11 or, as often in Germany and Belgium, commuting from surrounding villages. In either case, work had been their life; center-city artisans lived, drank, and played around their work experience, intermarrying with their own.12 Artisans from the villages alternated rural and urban work, with similarly little time for activities unrelated to the work experience. All of this was now challenged, most obviously by intrusions from the outside such as new, mechanized equipment that spread for the first time to virtually every artisanal trade, but also by new expectations on the part of artisans themselves, as they sought more time for family life and new kinds of residential patterns.13
In terms of exposure to machines and to more regular, routinized work methods the working class was becoming more united by 1900 in all the advanced industrial nations. The reactions of key groups were not the same, for the ability and desire to develop compensations off the job varied as did the extent of pressure on traditional patterns. But there was something of a common framework, which carried over into protest efforts. For, unlike the first period in which artisans struggled to end the industrial revolution, reaction to the new work patterns now took shape within the industrial system. Unskilled laborers, a bit newer to the game, occasionally ventured an anachronistic protest against the whole system — as in sporadic acts of Luddism — but they too largely worked within the order. Protest in a broad sense encouraged further accommodation to industrial work, and while this was not always to the workers' disadvantage it did leave many with a sense of dismay.
Factory workers had undergone a steadier pace of change in technology and work organization since the early industrial period, but for those with lengthy factory experience the nature of work altered more dramatically during the decades around the turn of the century than at any point since the installation of factories themselves. Skilled workers in the factories were particularly challenged, for their ties with an artisanal mode of production had by no means been shattered. This applied to new workers in German machine-building plants from a small-town craft background or to shoe mounters everywhere who tried to defend traditional skills in a new factory setting, as well as to British turners or fitters who faced new challenges from automatic machinery and the semi-skilled who could operate it or to the iron moulders who still insisted on a seven-year apprenticeship. The erosion of proudly-won skills was a common theme throughout the advanced industrial countries. English engineers resisted the imposition of American production systems, claiming that English machine skills were the best
in the world.14 British shipbuilders maintained that certain kinds of work were 'theirs by custom.'15 Workers in textiles and mining, where technological innovations were less marked, nevertheless faced steady pressure to increase production, ranging from persistent efforts to increase the number of looms per worker, in weaving, to even more general efforts to use a piece rate to heighten work intensity.16 Traditional respites from work, already challenged by early industrialization, were now brought under rigorous scrutiny. Welsh mine-owners tried to abolish 'Mabon's Day,' an annual holiday, while British mine companies generally pressed workers to end their tradition of 'playing' on Saturday.17 In Belgian as in British mines, customary meal breaks were reduced, while in the factories foremen's supervision became more intensive. Even British textile workers, for all their factory experience, encountered a new level of work; previously able to nap periodically on the job, they now found themselves driven to a new level of constant labor which could, as with miners, eat into traditional respites.18
There is no need to argue that changes in work were more disruptive in this period than in the early industrial revolution, though in certain industries this was clearly the case. What we are talking about is the creation of the modern work system and, to an important extent, the modern worker himself. The early industrial period was marked by the passage of traditional types of workers and the reaction against the whole advent of modernity. It was full of drama, but it constituted more the death of an old working class than the making of a new one. The cluster of changes in work systems that developed toward the end of the nineteenth century in the most advanced industrial countries was accompanied by other developments that set the workers apart from their predecessors, without breaking with traditions entirely. This was the period when education became general (though it lagged in Belgium, with important effects on the reaction to work). Everywhere workers' birth rates began a rapid decline. Protest movements of course developed a real mass base for the first time. All of this forms something of a package, with the work experience a possible key.
The 1890s admittedly constitute only a convenient point at which to embark on this study. The breakdown of artisanal work patterns can be traced in London to the late 1870s, while for English textile workers the pressure to increase the pace of work was more intense in the 1880s than in the 1890s. But by the 1890s the conversion to new work systems was fairly general, across all four countries considered. Discussion of the next twenty years covers a manageable cross-section
of the reaction to the new forms of work, as well as the steady proliferation of new pressures. The introduction, at the end of the period, of American-devised efficiency systems, particularly in metal-working and machine-building, reveals the connections between this period and contemporary manufacturing work. The World War extended the changes that had already been outlined, but there is no claim that it marked a decisive break. The War disrupted the data base for a study of this sort, eliminating some useful sources such as normal strike records and many trade union publications; but again this should not be taken as a judgement that the mature of work dramatically changed. For the whole point in examination of the history of labor in the two decades before World War I is to assess the origins of a new but durable work experience.
In the early 1900s a survey by Adolf Levenstein revealed the following reactions to work: 60 percent of the miners reported no joy in work, while 15 percent found pleasure in their jobs, and 18 percent were indifferent; among textile workers the rates were 75, 7, and 14 percent, while among metal workers they were 57, 17, and 17 percent. Alfred Williams, a worker in a locomotive plant in Swindon, discussed the impact of new machines and the piece rate only a few years later. He found his colleagues exhausted, with no energy to enjoy life off the job; but they felt they had to go on working, for there was no alternative. One worker, whose wife locked him in his room to enforce a rest, escaped through the window to get "back to his job.19 Vignettes abound: Flemish miners refusing to join a strike because they found it normal to continue working.20 The weaver who reported to Levenstein, against the majority, that, 'My daily work really gives me pleasure because I don't do it slavishly, but like all my jobs, with love and awareness.'21
This study deals both with adaptation and with inability to adapt. Its essence is simple, however complex and ambiguous the conclusions may be. With a generation or more of industrial work behind them, did workers find the changing work experience m ore or less onerous than before? This is not, despite Levenstein's statistics and Williams' impression, merely a tale of woe. Tempting as it is to seize on the frequent expressions of torment, it would distort the capabilities of workers themselves if we ignored the means by which they could come to terms with hardship. The important groups of workers who did maintain means of enjoying their jobs should not be ignored. Why, even in Levenstein's figures, the differences in work enjoyment among the three industries considered? For the workers who found decreasing
pleasure in work, there were some means of compensation, notably in new enjoyments off the job and the development of new protest outlets.
Both of these latter factors will demand attention after the work experience itself is assessed. In one of the only efforts to date to discuss the nature of work in a mature phase of industrialization, Eric Hobsbawm posits the increasing conversion to a market mentality toward work, which accepts changing technology and organization — a non-traditional work experience — in exchange for increasing rewards.22 Several studies in the mid-twentieth century confirm this notion of development, where factory workers view their jobs mainly as instruments and live for the time they have away from work.23 Yet we cannot move automatically from the conversion Hobsbawm describes to the contemporary materials, and in some countries such as the United States many workers continue to express pleasure in work itself.24 We do not know in what order various categories of workers effected the instrumental conversion and why. In a previous essay I have tried to portray important groups of workers who were subject to non-traditional work experiences and yet incapable of a full transition to an instrumental view.25 At the other extreme, as Hobsba wm himself notes, we must not neglect the workers who found interest in the new technology and pace of work. Above all, as we realize how much of the pre-industrial work mentality had survived, even in Britain, into the early twentieth century, a careful examination of the ambiguities of the transformation to a new view of work may suggest complexities even in the approach of contemporary workers toward their jobs.
That protest outlets increased during the turn-of-the-century period is obvious. Much of the source material on which this study relies comes from protest situations. And conclusions about the nature of work in a maturing industrial society undoubtedly illuminate various conventional topics in labor history. Some insight into the reasons for different kinds of socialism, for example, emerges from examination of various work settings. Union policies and strike patterns directly relate to problems at work. We shall return to an assessment of protest in the concluding section. But it must be stressed that the study is not designed solely as an explanation of protest. We are fully as interested in, if often less knowledgeable about, workers who did not protest as in those who did. Unrest is treated as it flowed from the work situation, relieving some of its tensions and exacerbating others, and not, save in the concluding remarks, for its own sake.
And this is not merely a history with the politics left out. The study
has not been based extensively on the kind of cultural materials — poems, songs, and so on — that have gained such favor after the work of E. P. Thompson. This partly reflects lack of time on the author's part, given the extensive geographical area investigated, and to this extent it represents a weakness in the data base. But too much reliance on such evidence is risky in any event, because of the familiar problem of representativeness. The most soulful German miners, the young intellectuals in the Welsh mines who went to Ruskin College, the French worker poets may have articulated more general concerns, but they were unusual types. Some were demonstrably more upset about their work than their fellows were. Max Lotz, who described his horror at work in the mines so vividly, talked to be sure of the 'secret rage' that animated his colleagues, but he also described their phlegmatic character and their inability to feel, much less to articulate, his kind of torment: 'The miners are commonly made of thick, grainy wood.'26 If for the early period it is chancy to qualify the evidence articulate workers produced, given the lack of abundant alternative materials, for this period it is essential. The dramatic phrase can easily obscure the common experience. This is not, as will be seen, a declaration that most workers were contented clods. It amounted to five percent of the total in some instances (as suggested by Florence Bell's study of the number of workers in Middlesbrough who read widely), but often to less than this; in Germany, where most workers did not even use union libraries, less than ten percent of all books borrowed from their libraries was other than escapist fiction.27 The perceptions of the worker intellectuals were distinctive at least in degree, and the culture they produced has therefore not been given special place.
Hence there is nothing on workers' "theater and little on the labor press (though the latter has been extensively consulted). When we turn to the question of recreational outlets, as they developed as a complement to or compensation for the work experience, this may be seen as an unfortunate omission. There is a bit more on general popular culture, particularly sports, for a discussion of changing work patterns necessitates conclusions on the kind of leisure ethic workers could develop. But there is no pretense at a full survey of the relevant materials. Treatment of family developments falls into much the same category, for while important conclusion s can be suggested not enough is yet known to claim definitive coverage. This was a crucial period in working-class family life, as the reduction of the birth rate suggests, and the interrelationship of family patterns with work is obvious.
Twentieth-century studies that claim that family problems are more likely to cause work difficulties than the converse might suggest the family as the principal entrée into working-class culture, rather than the job itself. This study will postulate that it was in the period around 1900 that the balance was swinging toward family concerns, but that the disruptive effects of work could still predominate. But again, while going beyond the work experience into its links with a more general culture, we cannot pretend to offer a thorough assessment of this culture.
We can legitimately excuse some of this incompleteness with the standard invocation of having to start somewhere, given the absence of much historical attention to working-class life in this later industrial period. But there is no need to take too apologetic or tentative a tone. Despite the precedents cited earlier, work has received little historical attention, and if its study illuminates only a part of working-class life, it is a vital part. We have spent far more time on developments off the job: the standard of living and the labor movement being the most obvious cases in point. As we grope even in the present day to understand what a worker sees in his work, with immensely confusing results,28 a historical focus on this phenomenon alone seems overdue. We know a bit about the traditional expectations that early workers brought to their jobs, their willingness to work long hours at a slow pace, and their lack of a modern sense of time. We know something more about the kind of work ethic that management hoped to foist upon them.29 We know something about individual disputes that developed over work patterns. But the overall reality of wo rk and the varieties of response it elicited remain elusive.
The question of varieties of reaction will preoccupy us consistently. What might seem the most obvious analytical approach to th is question will not be used extensively. This is a cross-national study, rather than a rigorously comparative one. We will not, save in some final conclusions, try to isolate distinctive national experiences. I have dealt with the inadequacy of the most common national characterizations for working-class history in this period in another essay.30 We will note subsequently, for example, that German workers, far from being unusually assiduous, were less work-oriented in the modern sense than British, whose productivity was higher in almost all the modern industries. German workers hung around the job more, but it is much more sensible to explain this by their more recent exposure to industrial work than by some peculiar German Arbeitsfreude. Hence the most fruitful comparisons concern recency of industrialization. We
will be paying particular attention to Germany, as an area of rapid changes in work systems for a population still highly traditionalist, in contrast to England, where work changes involved a population with much greater industrial experience. But the purpose is more to explain stages of development than particular national patterns, for given industrial categories could depart from any general norm. British construction workers, for example, were less open to change at work than French or German, as they talked of 'the likes of us' and found it difficult to contemplate progress.31 It is within industrial categories, not across whole nations, that comparison is most revealing.
Hence our efforts to encompass variety will stress key groups of workers, who may then be compared regionally and nationally to determine secondary characteristics. Most obviously in the case of journeymen but also among textile workers, metallurgists, railway workers, and even dockers, a certain selectivity operated in determining entrance to a type of work, and this was becoming more pronounced with the maturing of industry. With varying combinations of voluntary choice and compulsion, certain mentalities and even physical types tended to cluster in the main working-class occupations. Along with differences in the organization and technology applied to work, these differences produced varying reactions to work changes and efforts to develop compensatory enjoyments. Related to these categories are distinctions of age and sex, which will also be given prominent place. The work experience of women and the attitudes they developed to the job were different than those of men, while older workers took a different stance from the young.
Nevertheless, while variety must be treated in any analysis that is more than a collection of laments, we can begin with something of a common framework. All four nations considered had advanced industrial economies. Changes in technology and business organization were not substantively different in any of the four. France, long seen as an industrial laggard, had in fact an experienced working-class nucleus and a comparable pace of productivity increase during the nineteenth century as a whole.32 Its inclusion, at first sight perhaps unusual because of the common confusion over per capita and total growth rates, raises no real analytical problems. Even France's distinctive working-class protest tradition, manifest in this period in revolutionary syndicalism, neither reflected nor provided a really distinctive pattern of work.33 Oddly enough, apart from differences due to length of exposure to an industrial economy, it is Belgium that produced the most distinctive worker experience, for despite long industrial exposure
much of the Belgian manufacturing labor force was not urbanized by 1900. Nevertheless, the framework established by advanced industrial capitalism covers all four countries considered and provides our starting point. Further comparison, particularly with the United States, where so many changes in work experience were now originating, is obviously desirable, but we can begin with this grouping.
More tentatively, we can suggest a few common ingredients in the culture that workers themselves brought to their jobs and indeed their whole lives. Despite the tremendous variety in situations, to which we return in the next chapter, workers tended to share a considerable fear Of change. They were easily convinced, more often than not correctly, that change would cheat them. They had seen previous changes redound to the benefit of their employer. They remembered, from their own experience or that of their fathers, periods of massive unemployment that seemed the result of change; recollections of the crisis Of the 1870s were commonly echoed in the 1890s decade, which then produced its own proof that change could be dangerous. And even sophisticated workers, capable for example of advanced forms of protest, had not shaken off the sense that what was traditional was good.
Hence a judgement of work in terms of past standards made almost universal good sense. In 1902 workers at Krupp complained about new arrangements at work, saying that they 'expected justice' from the company; and the management, recognizing what was meant, urged that changes in old work customs be introduced more subtly.34 South Wales miners in 1907 claimed in court that they deserved regular overtime, and the extra pay resulting, again as a matter of tradition.3 s Tradition at work commonly dictated a certain slowness of pace in most factories as well as artisan shops; this was true even in British metallurgy, where it was attributed, well after 1900, to the persistence of craft customs.36 It dictated a sense that a certain amount of work deserved a set price. Hence workers in a Halifax metal plant found it perfectly natural to strike on behalf of a colleague who had refused a wage because he found it unfair 'for the amount of labour in it.'37 German artisans expected to follow the customs of the place (ortsublich was the adjective commonly used) in the amount of work they did.38 And the approach was shared by a host of other kinds of workers. Even relatively recent developments could be assimilated into the cake of custom and vigorously defended, for the cast of mind here inhibited a sense of constant change. Hence miners would agitate when work arrangements such as the time of rising from the pits after
completion of a piece of work, introduced a few years before, were altered, claiming great antiquity for the 'customs' they sought to preserve.39 Factory workers could join their employers in concealing violations of safety laws from government inspectors, again from a desire to hold on to what they had against outsiders.40 Even workers normally designated unskilled had their sense of tradition on the job. German dockers had a strict demarcation of tasks, differentiating types of goods loaded, work on the ship as opposed to that on the quay, carting, and so on, and they were as capable as any other group of pointing to the special customs of their job.41
And the traditional bent extended beyond work itself. Workers' wives could protest a new system of pay because it called for new thinking. Belgian miners' wives thus resisted the replacement of weekly with biweekly paydays; the employers claimed this reflected simple lack of budget knowledge, but the mentality involved went deeper.42 Within the home, male workers not uncommonly resisted any alteration in decor or furnishings. Traditionalism could extend to diets. A London wife reported: 'My husband, he'll eat nothing but boiled bacon, or a chop, or a bit of fat beef over pertaters; if it won't run to that, "Gimme a bit o' braun' cheese and I'll know weer I am," he'll say.'43 And certainly» the traditional attitude covered the common approach to medicine. Workers typically remained Loath to call in a doctor, even when their wages might have sufficed.44
At an extreme, traditionalism led to apathy, a sense that life was hopeless and beyond control. Many German workers dreaded the future or claimed that God or fate would rule their lot; such was the outlook in the Daimler automobile plant, near Stuttgart, where not a few workers said they 'hoped they would die first' when asked about the possibility of changes in the future.45 At least as typically workers were unable clearly to answer questions about the future, even about how they intended to provide for their old age; there was simply no basis for thinking about such things. Where religion remained, as with many women workers, ignorance was not without comfort: T put my fate in God's hands ... then everything will be all right.'46 More commonly one cannot escape the conclusion that workers could not bear the thought of looking far ahead, because no one would provide for them.
But traditionalism had another side to it. Workers had a pronounced sense of their own dignity, closely associated with the traditions of their jobs. During a Belgian miners' strike in 1901, the rumor spread that a hated employer had called his workers 'vagabonds'; the miners,
deeply offended, responded by trying to stone the man.47 Workers in Belgium and elsewhere were revolted at the notion of classifying themselves as unemployed, some maintaining that to do so would lose them all claims to respectability. Unskilled workers, whatever their feelings of worthlessness in the past, produced frequent statements of their sense of dignity. French carters insisted that they be treated as something more than 'beasts of burden,' while sailors announced that 'they are not pariahs, having the same right as any man to aspire to improve their lot.'48 The language of British workers bristled with references to their manhood, which they often associated with defense of their rights against their employers.49
Thus in stressing the deep-seated traditionalism of the workers we are far from claiming that workers were passive creatures, incapable of understanding the changes that were occurring about them. And of course traditionalism as we suggest it here is a very vague term, for it is obvious that some workers were able to adapt to new situations, developing new aspirations of their own, far more rapidly than others. It is in many ways far-fetched to embrace, in a single generalization, uneducated Flemish artisans who returned to their native village after every work-day and manifested few interests beyond those of a customary peasantry, with, say, London or Parisian printers who were adopting many of the trappings of the lower middle class. Yet the theme of traditionalism must recur frequently in a discussion of work, und it does cut across national and professional lines. Workers measured their present by their past, and this gave them deeply-felt standards of what was appropriate. It left many of them more than a bit handicapped in developing new aspirations for the future. Even when they had hopes for a better life, they often realized that the hopes were futile or left the hopes deliberately vague, as with the many German workers who, bothered by persistent sociological pollster s — another sign of modern times — simply talked of wanting 'something better in the present life.'50
The turn of the century period gains much of its drama from the confrontation between workers' values, still largely turned toward the past, and a new tide of change. A culture that had been painfully established or re-established after the first shock of industrialization was now challenged. What work was, what wives were for, what children were for all had to be rethought. Out of the variety of responses to these challenges came a recognizably modern, though highly differentiated, working-class life style.
Notes
1. Jurgen Kuczynski, Darstellung der Lage der Arbeiter in Deutsch-land von 1871 bis 1918, 2v. (Berlin, 1962-67); on women's work, Margaret Hewitt, Wives and Mathers in Victorian Industry, (London, 1958).
2. E. P. Thompson, 'Time, Work Discipline, and Industrial Capitalism,' Past and Present (1967>, 56-97.
3. Herbert Gutman extends this theme into the later nineteenth century for the United States by stressing the adaptation required of each successive wave of immigrants: 'Work, Culture and Society in Industrializing America, 1815—1919,' American Historical Review, (1973), 531-88.
4. David Landes, The Unbound Prc*metheus (Cambridge, 1969), 301-23.
5. Peter N. Stearns, 'Adaptation to Industrialization: German Workers as a Test Case,' Central European History (1970), 303 ff.
6. Arno Hoffmeister, Die wirtschaftliche Lage der Landarbeiter im Ostpreussen (Halle-Saalen, 1908).
7. Brimley Thomas, 'The Migration of Labour into the Glamorganshire Coalfield (1861-1911), Economica (1930), 298 ff.
8. Ferdinand Tônnies, 'Hafenarbeiter und Seeleute in Hamburg vor dem Strike 1896—97,' Archiv fur Gesetzgebung und Politik (1897), 673 ff.
9. E. Prancke, 'Die Arbeitsvexhaltnis se im Hafen zu Hamburg,' Jahrbuch fur Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung, und Volkswirtschaft im Deutschen Reich (1898), 943-50.
10. See, for example, Journeymen Felt Hatters, Annual Report, 1891.
11. Over half of whom lived in the center city. Charles Booth, Life and Labour of the People in London (London, 1897), X, 25.
12. Gareth Stedman Jones, 'Working-Class Culture and Working-Class Politics in London, 1870—1900; Notes on the Remaking of a Working Class,' Journal of Social History (1974).
13. Thomas Bell, Pioneering Days (London, 1941), 61; J. Zitzlaff, Arbeitsgleiderung in Maschinen-Unternehmungen (Jena, 1913).
14. Amalgamated Society of Engineers, The Lockout in the Engineering Trade (London, 1898), 3.
15. Royal Commission on Labour, Digest of the Evidence, Group 'C (Textile, Clothing, Chemical, Building, and Miscellaneous Trades (London, 1893, C 6894), II, 30.
16. At an extreme, the piece rate could multiply worker output by 100 per cent in five years, as was the case in Belgian glass manufacture between 1903 and 1909: Asa Briggs- and John Saville, eds., Essays in Labour History (London, 1 960), 1 38.
17. H. Stanley Jevons, The British Coal Trade (London, 1915), 835; Miners' Federation of Great Britain, Executive Committee Meetings, 1909.
18. Arthur Shadwell, Industrial Efficiency (London, 1906), I, 114 ff.
19. Alfred Williams, Life in a Railway Factory (London, 1915), 183 ff. ; Adolf Levenstein, Aus der Tiefe, Arbeiterbriefe (Berlin, 1908), 54 ff.
20. Archives de la Sûreté publique de la province de Liège (Archives de l'Etat, Liège), Carton XV, report of 1913.
21. Levenstein, Tiefe, 90.
22. E. J. Hobsbawm, 'Custom, Wages and Work Load, in Labouring Men (New York, 1964).
23. John H. Goldthorpe et al., The Affluent Worker in the Class Structure (Cambridge, 1969); Robert Blauner, Alienation and Freedom; The Factory Worker and His Industry (Chicago, 1964).
24. Work in America (Cambridge, Mass., 1972), passim.
25. Stearns, 'Adaptation,' passim.
26. Levenstein, Tiefe, 60 and passim.
27. Mrs. Hugh Bell, At the Works (London, 1907); Adolf Weber, Die Lohnbewegungen der Gewerkschaftsdemokatie (Bonn, 1914). For more extensive comments on the sources used, see the bibliographical essay.
28. It is plausible to argue both increasing pleasure and increasing distress in factory work since World War II: see Goldthorpe, Affluent Worker; Ferdynand Zweig, The Worker in an Affluent Society (New York, 1962); Sar A. Levitan, éd., Blue-Collar Workers (New York, 1971), 30 ff., 160 ff. See Conclusion.
29. Sidney Pollard, The Genesis of Modern Management (Cambridge, 1964).
30. Peter N. Stearns, 'National Character and European Labor History,' Journal of Social History (1970), 95-124.
31. Raymond Postgate, The Builders History (London, n.d.), 38.
32. Francois Crouzet, 'Essai de construction d'un indice annuel de la production industrielle française au XIXe siècle,' Annales: Economies Sociétés, Civilisations (1970), 56—101.
33. Peter N. Stearns, Revolutionary Syndicalism and French Labor (New Brunswick, N.J., 1971).
34. Gerhard Adelmann, éd., Quellensammlung zur Geschichte der sozialen Betriebsverfassung: Ruhrindustrie unter besonderer Berùcksichtigung des Industrie- und Handelskammerbezirks Essen (Bonn, 1960), I, 306.
35. Jevons, Coal, 528 ff.
36. D. L. Burn, The Economic History of Steelmaking, 1867-1939 (Cambridge, 1940), 147.
37. General Union of Braziers and Sheet Metal Workers, Annual Report, 1913.
38. Zentralverband christlicher Holzarbeiter Deutschlands in den Jahren 1908/09 (Cologne, 1910), 65.
39. N. Dethier, Centrale syndicale des travailleurs des mines de Belgique (Brussels, 1950), 27.
40. M. Loane, The Queen's Poor (London, 1905), 88.
41. Paul de Rousiers, Hambourg et l'Allemagne contemporaine (Paris,
1902), 249 ff.
42. Association houillère du Couchant de Mons, Historique de la grève du Borinage (Mons, 1911), 7.
43. M. Loane, The Next Street but One (London, 1907), 28.
44. Shadwell, Efficiency, I, passim.
45. Fritz Schumann, Auslese und Anpasrung der Arbeiterschaft in der Automobilindustrie (Leipzig, 1911), 18.
46. Ross Kempl, Das Leben der jungen Fabrikmàdchen in Mùnchen (Leipzig, 1911); see also Heinrich Herkner, Problème der Arbeiter-psychologie (Leipzig, 1912), passim.
47. Fr. Vercruysse, La Contribution belge à la statistique internationale de chômage (Liège, n.<L), 37; S. H. Scholl, De Geschiedenis van de Arb eidersbe-weging in West-Vlaanderen (Brussels, 1953), 4.
48. Adrien Veber, 'Mouvement social,' ±a Revue socialiste (1901), 361, 362, statements by individual workers in the 1901 port strikes, in Le Havre and Marseilles.
49. Peter N. Stearns, 'Working-Class in Britain, 1890-1914,' in M. Vicinus, éd., Suffer and Be Still (Bloornington, 1972), 113.
50. Max Morgenstern, Auslese und Anpassung der industrieller Arbeiterschaft betrachtet bei den Offenbacher Lederarbeitern (Breiburgi. Br , 1911), 110.
PART I THE FRAMEWORK FOR LABOR
CHAPTER 1 THE EVOLUTION OF THE LABOR FORCE
Establishing the cast of characters for a study of the working class is no easy task, yet it must be attempted for it provides both the framework for further analysis and the outlines of the job structure within which workers operated. Beginning with the premise that manual, non-agricultural labor demarcated both a class and a distinctive work experience, even a brief study of occupational structure introduces the theme of diversity. While modern industries commanded an increasing share of the working class, older sectors, including a large domestic manufacturing segment, did not yield quickly. Rapid growth itself produced diversity. Expanding industries like metallurgy and mining drew in people who abandoned their ties to the countryside reluctantly if at all. Railroads and street car lines allowed many new workers to maintain rural residence; around Hannover some iron workers came in from 30 to 40 kilometers away. Similarly, in one iron factory near Charleroi, over half the workers lived in a variety of towns distant from the plant. Even in England, where the industrial labor force was undeniably more fully formed, residential distinctions persisted; a railroad factory near Swindon found only the skilled workers living in town, while the laborers usually lived in the villages and came in on the train.1 Clearly, commuting was less of a jolt than moving, but it therefore perpetuated important divisions within the working class. The stabilization of the industrial economy, after the first decades of frenzied growth, often made it more difficult to recruit new workers, for the worst rural misery had been skimmed off; hence an increasing resort to foreigners, who brought their own rural attachments with them. Polish workers in the Ruhr, for example, made a concerted effort to keep their traditional costumes and festivals.2 Diversity of customs and residence affected the crafts as well. Thoroughly urbanized Parisian construction workers every summer faced colleagues who wandered in from small towns. Ten to twenty percent of the workers in craft centres such as Antwerp and Liège lived outside town, while in Frankfurt a full 72 percent of all masons lived in villages around the city.3
Thus diversity and the necessity of dealing with strangers and strange ways on the job were important elements of the work situation still. They loom larger in Germany, with its fast-growing economy, than in
England, but they were not negligible anywhere. And if the number of newcomers to industry was less overwhelming than it had been before, some of them seemed stranger, if only because of the distances they could now travel, and the chance to complain was greater. Attacks on foreigners, on country people, on domestic manufacturers, and on women at work abound, and though the y are often out of proportion to the real number of strangers on the job they reflect serious dissonances within a working class that was still incompletely formed. Dockers in Barry and elsewhere called for a national strike against Chinese labor, while sailors in Marseilles struck several times against foreign, particularly Arab, workers.4 German miners complained that their foremen were treating them more harshly because of their impatience with foreign workers, who understood little German; it was easy to carry over a cursing intolerance to the native labor force.5 British union organizers, though rarely faxed with real foreigners, could still point up the gap between urban and rural manufacturing workers. When a 1909 law required the establishment of conciliation boards in putting-out trades such as chain-making, machine lace manufacture, and wholesale tailoring, the worker representatives were virtually inarticulate, incapable of understanding the notion of dealing directly with employers.6 German and French bakers and tailors split between a modern group that fought customary ties with the craft master, and a large traditionalist segment that wanted nothing better than to live in and court the boss's daughter. Divisions in background, residence, and outlook abound, and no structural outline can capture all of them. We can, however, hope to convey some of the constant jostling with newcomers - newcomers, if not to industry itself, at least to the type of industry they were now involved in — that remained an important fact of life in most branches of manufacturing. Here is part of the background of the organized labor movement itself, which could provide some protection against strangers; a letter from a London worker caught the mood:
We must keep the question of who we shall work with to decide among ourselves, and not allow the employers to say that we shall work with non-unionists, blacklegs, or any other undesirable persons.7
Strangers became more menacing because of another, newer trend within the working class as a whole: the growth of the class was slowing up. Fear of dwindling opportunities was of course not new for artisans,
who had often anticipated the problem before it hit home. Important branches of industry were still growing lustily. Again, diversity complicates any generalization. But the slowing up of growth in the factory population was new, and it touched huge segments of the working class. Despite industrial growth only 12.1 per cent of the male manufacturing labor force in France was under 24 in 1911 compared to 19.1 per cent in 1896. If, then, a general point can be ventured beyond the invocation of continued, often abrasive contact with newcomers, it is that the working class rather generally became conscious of limitations to opportunity — opportunity not in the middle-class sense of chances for advancement, but in the more genuinely working-class sense of being able to continue doing what one had started out doing. Some workers were directly displaced from their jobs. Far more had to help their sons or daughters decide to enter a different trade. Reshuffling, more than new growth, was coming to characterize industrial work.
The outline of occupational structure and its evolution is of necessity purely descriptive, heavily numerical, and complicated. What follows is based on national census materials from the four countries under study.8 The material raises a host of obvious problems. It is not congruent chronologically; here the twelve-year gap between German censuses and the absence of material after 1907 are particularly unfortunate, among other things exaggerating comparative German growth because the 1895 census picked up the effects of the mid-'nineties crisis while that in 1907 predated another serious recession by a full year. Occupational categories varied from one country to the next and changed within the same country, complicating comparisons across time as well as across national boundaries. The French census of 1911 is indeed almost unusable because of its erratic job classifications and the absence of breakdowns by sex.9 More normally, as in Britain, census categories steadily improved in precision, but it remains impossible fully to rectify earlier fuzziness.
Furthermore most of the general tables, designed for economic more than social analysis, do not distinguish among workers, clerical help, and employers, which muddies any study of the working class per se.1 ° Here, some controls are possible concerning the labor force as a whole (though not for more specific categories such as women, where figures, invariably include employers as well as workers).11 Clerical employees cannot be sifted out. Presumably their numbers advanced; by 1906 in France they ranged from 1.4 percent of the total work-force in artisanal industries like wood, to 12.2 percent in highly-organized chemicals, but given the absence of figures from other censuses trends cannot be
clearly established. Employed personnel can, however, be sorted from employers in several cases, and with interesting results. Until about 1900 the presence of employers in the general census listings tends to reduce growth rates, for the work-force was increasing more rapidly. The one exception concerns stagnant or depressed industries — particularly crafts (French leather, French and English construction between 1901 and 1906) but also English textiles in the late 1890s. Workers normally escaped a sinking ship more rapidly than employers, so that general census data either minimizes the decline in numbers or conceals a loss of workers outright. Workers had greater need to abandon a deteriorating industry, but in some cases, perhaps, more choice in the matter than a small owner. After 1900 the general census data, where it distorts at all, exaggerates overall growth. Despite important tendencies toward rationalization, the number of employers was growing more rapidly than that of workers. This was true even in highly-organized sectors such as French, and Belgian mining or English shipbuilding where, despite consolidation or perhaps because of it, managers outstripped workers; it was certainly true in the crafts, as the number of small owners grew (as in French and British metals) or held firm as when the labor force shrank. But here the distortions caused by the presence of employers in calculations simply reduce the visibility of major trends; they do not conceal the trends or seriously alter the comparative judgements from one country to the next. And if they do tend to inflate the size of the crafts compared to the factory sectors, this is partially offset by the larger clerical contingent in the latter.
In general it should be clear that judgements on trends are fairly solid, even where absolute numbers leave serious doubts. Comparisons across time are therefore far firmer than those from one country to the next, where a whole variety of differences in the bases of calculation may intervene. Comparisons among industries are at an intermediate level of probability; they are not exact, if only because of the inclusion of non-worker elements, but they correctly indicate general orders of magnitude. It should also be noted that detailed studies of the breakdowns in the printed censuses could greatly improve the precision of our picture of occupational structure while, in my opinion, rarely changing the picture itself.
The number of people engaged in industry or transportation grew steadily between 1890 and 1914. Germany had the highest growth rate, followed by Belgium, France, and England. The French growth rate was bouyed by an unusually rapid gain in transportation; industry alone was more sluggish, for here as in England and to a lesser extent Belgium,
reshuffling was more significant than absolute growth. Except in Britain, where the industrial-transport sectors already commanded 90 percent of the population, the importance of industry in the occupational structure steadily advanced, which meant a steady if modest pull of newcomers, mainly from agriculture, into the working class. Here France held its own, suggesting that its slow overall growth was in large part a function of the general demographic lag. Finally, in all countries offering more than two censuses in the pre-war decades, the: decline in rate of growth after 1900 is marked. (Table I.)
Breakdowns for the major industries help explain both some of the peculiarities of the national patterns and the general evolution before and after 1900.12 (Table II.) The industries themselves behaved rather similarly. Belgian miners faced declining opportunities, compared to the national average, whereas mining was a big gainer elsewhere. German transport behaved oddly. Efforts to improve efficiency, as on railroads, may have limited growth, and the German ports did not draw the hordes of new dockers characteristic of France and Britain; but the statistical comparison is almost certainly the result of census error. Everywhere else transportation was a burgeoning sector. Metals and machine building consist, quite simply, of far too many diverse segments; here the German distinctions between the two industries is useful. Machinery gained ground everywhere, led by electrical equipment and vehicles.13 Traditional metal work, in contrast, lagged; hence in France, between 1901 and 1906, lock manufacturers gained but .8 percent (and the number of workers alone probably shrank) while automobile manufacture increased by over 180 percent. Among the generally low growth industries, France stands out in its rapid curtailment of artisanal sectors (wood, leather, food) which still enjoyed modest gains elsewhere.
In terms of the large categories, then, construction, transport, and mining gained ground rapidly. So in fact did machine construction, but it was held back by metals which was by far the larger employer (its labor force more than twice as big, in Germany, in 1895). Printing and paper, a smaller employer, enjoyed more modest growth. Chemicals and metallurgy were spectacular gainers, but averaged a relatively small percentage of the total industrial labor force.
Generally below the national average in growth were artisanal, small-shop sectors two of which — wood and food — were substantial employers of labor. Clothing, in 1890 the province of craftsmen and women working at home, grew little and textiles, in most cases even a bigger employer, grew scarcely at all - yet these were still among the
Table I Evaluation of the Industrial Labor Force
(Manufacturing and Transport Occupations)
three or four largest users of workers in 1911. In other words, the modest but steady average growth rate of the industrial countries resulted from dramatic differences among major industries — no great surprise, perhaps, but an important fact for workers themselves.
Specific national growth patterns resulted in part from peculiarities in the industrial balance. It should be noted that Table II B, taken from the end of the census periods, tends to homogenize the national figures, for two decades of differential growth had already reduced certain peculiarities. Important distinctions remained, however. Because of relatively meager resources, France had only half the percentage of miners of the other industrial countries; this would seriously affect the 'average' characteristics of the French labor force, as in the question of overall growth where France was deprived of the full impact of a rapidly-expanding sector. Germany's high growth resulted in considerable measure from its existing specialization in metals and machines (which, of course, growth only heightened); Belgium similarly benefited in metallurgy. But Belgium also had a large textile sector, which Germany lacked. French specialization in crafts and clothing (though with food processing excepted) obviously hampered overall labor growth at this point but provided a pool from which other industries might gain. Britain's apparent bulge in food processing results in part from a more inclusive census category. Germany's concentration in construction probably has greater base in reality, for this was a less efficient industry in Germany, while a harsher climate required a larger labor pool since winter work was more limited. Differences in printing follow interestingly from national literacy rates, but they were not, of course, particularly significant for the general labor force. Overall, differences in the rank order of industries point up the peculiar situation of Germany, where four of the top seven industries were rapid gainers of labor. Elsewhere considerable concentration in artisanal sectors (France, Belgium) or in stagnant factory industries (Britain, Belgium) made the reshuffling of workers more important than the recruitment of newcomers to industry. Except in France workers were not being forced out of major categories, but growth rates were so slow that many of their children would have to decide to enter other lines of work. In fact, of course, the distinctiveness of Germany was less marked than the figures show. German sons and daughters were also being pushed out of important traditional sections of metals and textiles, for the craft/rural tone of German manufacturing was at least as pronounced as in France still in 1900. And where reshuffling seems called for on paper it did not necessarily occur in practice. French
Table II Patterns of Industrial Growth: Summary and Comparative Tables
A. Annual growth rates, major census categories
Belgium (1890-1910) |
Germany (1895-1907> |
Britain (1891-1901) |
France (1896-1911) |
|
High rate Construction |
4.1 |
3.6 |
1.6 |
1.7 |
Chemicals |
7.1 |
4.1 |
3.9 |
4.6 |
Printing, paper |
3.3 |
5.1 |
2.4 |
2.9 |
Metallurgy |
7.2 |
4.9 |
- |
4.5 |
Mixed, generally high |
||||
Mines |
1.5 |
5.7 |
2.7 |
3.1 |
Transport |
11.6 |
-3.5 |
2.0 |
8.4 |
Metals/ machines |
1.1 |
13.4 |
2.4 |
2.3 |
Mixed, |
(machines only) 3.6 (metals only) |
(to 1906 only) |
||
generally low |
||||
Food |
2.4 |
2.4 |
2.2 |
.4 |
Wood |
2.1 |
2.7 |
1.9 |
-.1 |
Leather |
2.9 |
2.9 |
1.3 |
-.3 |
Clothing |
.7 |
2.6 |
.8 |
1.1 |
Low Textiles |
.8 |
1.7 |
.3 |
.3 |
B. Percentage of total industrial labor force in major industries, last census date
Belgium (1910) |
Germany (1907) |
Britain (1911) |
France (1911) |
|
Construction |
10.5 |
17.8 |
10.0 |
11.7 |
Mines |
9.0 |
7.3 |
10.5 |
4.8 |
Transport |
10.8 |
2.8 |
13.9 |
13.6 |
Metals & machines |
7.5 |
19.1 |
14.4 (incl. metallurgy) |
6.6 (in 1906) |
Metallurgy |
5.5 |
2.5 |
1.4 |
|
Textiles |
15.4 |
9.7 |
11.6 |
14.2 |
Clothing |
13.7 |
9.9 |
11.3 |
17.3 |
Food |
5.6 |
8.9 |
10.6 |
6.9 |
Printing & paper |
2.1 |
1.8 (printing alone) |
3.4 (printing, 1.6) |
2.8 (estimate) |
Chemicals |
1.8 |
1.4 |
1.7 |
1.6 (estimate) |
Wood |
7.9 |
6.4 |
2.8 |
9.2 |
Leather |
1.1 |
1.8 |
1.0 |
4.4 |
metallurgy, for example, found it difficult to recruit craftsmen from other industries, particularly because the metal trades were still vigorous enough to provide a haven. So French heavy industry, like German, had to recruit unskilled rural labor extensively.
One further remark about the concentrations of labor can apply to all the mature industrial countries. All the biggest industrial categories had a strong traditional component, even in 1911, whether they continued to gain ground or not. Construction, one of the leaders, increased its labor force in part because technical innovation was modest. Employment in metals and certainly in textiles and clothing lagged somewhat but it was still substantial; yet much of this work occurred in small shops or at home. Mining had its own traditions as did major branches of transportation (in British transport, road, employment was almost double that of railroads and water combined, yet it had undergone relatively few changes in method).14 And the outright artisanal sector, as in wood-working, remained considerable. The most obviously modern industrial sectors, such as chemicals, were still small, even though their growth rate propelled them forward rapidly. A long background of artisanal production plus the earlier stages of indus-trialization left a massive population in industries in which change occurred rather modestly (but could be all the more shocking for its contrast with a traditional framework) or in which stagnation or decline were painfully forcing workers to choose new careers or at least to fear for the future.
The theme of painful readjustment applies particularly to women workers, for the changes in the labor force affected their traditional concentrations in manufacturing with unusual intensity. In the 1890s there were marked similarities in the situation of women in manufacturing labor. France employed the highest percentage by far, for 32 percent of its manufacturing force was female. But this resulted almost entirely from the unusual preponderance of women in the manufacture of clothing and the large size of this industry in France. In other words, French women worked disproportionately, but mainly in the home.15 In shop and factory industries such as printing and metalwork they did not loom as large as their counterparts in Belgium and Britain. Their substantial total employment in France is significant, a function in part of the need for labor, given the demographic sluggishness, that forced employers to seek women in their homes whenever the nature of the industry allowed; and it may have had a significant effect on the women involved. But it was relatively traditional in its reliance on family environment. Germany in the 1890s suggests an even more
traditionalist framework. The low percentage of women in the labor force reflects above all the slight importance of textiles and clothing in the German economy, but percentages in other industries were low as well. Belgium and Britain were quite similar. Belgium stands out as the only country still using significant numbers of women in the mines, but its employment of women was at a slightly higher rate than Britain's mainly because of the greater importance of the clothing industry. Employment of women in chemicals and printing/paper was advanced in both countries (as in France) in contrast to Germany; in Britain (as in France) women had begun to make some inroads in the wood industry. But everywhere the overwhelming fact was the concentration of women in only three industries: clothing, textiles, and to a lesser extent food processing. And only in textiles were they extensively employed in factories.
A variety of forces converged to alter this situation — if slightly — by World War I. The stagnation of textiles and clothing meant that the employment rate, if not the absolute number, of women in manufacturing would automatically decline if they did not find alternate jobs. In fact women's employment in these industries, as generally in food processing, increased. Men were better able to flee the declining jobs and, as the main wage-earners in most families, had more need to do so. In France the employment rate of women held up mainly because they were able to switch from textiles to dressmaking; no great initiative was necessarily involved though the rise of clothing sweatshops meant that many women were changing locales.16 Only in France would this alternative work, and even here a rapid rise in the percentage of young manufacturing workers (48 percent under 24 in 1911 compared to 33 percent in 1895) shows that older women now chose, or were forced to drop out. Elsewhere the increase of women in textiles and dressmaking was not sufficient to keep women abreast of the general increase in the labor force and in the female population.
In addition to considerable economic compulsion, women's employment was facilitated by two other factors which will receive fuller consideration in subsequent chapters. Technological changes in industries such as engineering, printing, and furniture manufacture (wood) reduced skill requirements and opened the way for new recruitment of women. Many employers were eager to take advantage of this, given the lower wages women commanded and, in some cases such as Germany, the difficulty of finding unskilled male workers in sufficient number. Finally, many women became more eager to work outside the home, partly of course in r esponse to new opportunities.
Decline or stabilization of the servant population in France and Britain suggests the interest of unmarried girls in alternate employment.17 The rapid rise of married women in the factory labor force in Germany and probably France denotes another kind of change in attitude, even more fundamental in terms of working-class culture.18
Against a rapid readjustment of women to the new occupational structure stood their ties to the home, which could restrict their ability to respond to new jobs or to leave their accustomed areas, as well as deter both themselves and their husbands from contemplating their entry into a factory. And on the job, vigorous opposition from male workers, and often organized labor, could be expected. Belgium provides a case study of what happened when the opposition was strong and, in all probability, the change in women's consciousness insufficient to break through it. The percentage of women employed in manufacturing actually declined in Belgium, as the textile and clothing industries faded. Women responded mainly by taking an increasing role in these stagnant sectors. They were actually pushed out of printing and chemicals, in terms of their relative standing. This was common in chemicals after the 1890s, as males gained a greater role. In printing it reflected the Belgian lag in adopting new composing machines, which opened the door to semi-skilled labor, and the related strength of craft unionism in the industry. Finally, the Belgian working class, unusually concentrated in a rural residential environment, was hardly conducive to new occupational strivings either by wives or by daughters. So, though there was some absolute growth, Belgian women did not keep pace.
France produced a rather similar pattern, all the more surprising given the shortage of labor generally. Here there was some ground gained in paper/printing, but women fell back, relatively, in metals and chemicals. An increase in leather could reflect technological change, but this was a sick industry and more probably women were brought in, often as domestic or small-shop workers, because of their low wages alone. French women mainly opted for traditional jobs, so that their distribution in the labor force changed very little. The maintenance of a high level of female labor thus did not indicate significant new developments in the setting for work. One must assume that the relative vitality of the French clothing industry, in terms at least of employment maintenance, plus the absence of other motivations to seek new kinds of work, discouraged venturesomeness, except among new numbers of teenage girls.
In contrast, Britain and Germany showed some modest break-
Table III Women in Industry: Summary and Comparative Tables A. Annual Growth Rates (in brackets, general growth rate):
Belgium 1890-1910 |
|
Metal or metal/machines |
4.9 (1.1) |
Machines |
— |
Printing or printing/paper |
2.7 (3.3) |
Chemicals |
5.2 (7.1) |
Textiles |
2.6 ( .8) |
Dress or dress/cleaning |
1.2 ( .7) |
Food |
2.7 (2.4) |
Leather |
10.6 (2.9) |
Wood |
10.6 (2.1) |
National Total |
2.2 (2.4) |
B. % Totals in Major Industries at Last Census Date:
Belgium |
France |
Britain |
Germany |
|
Metal or metal/machines |
3.5 |
6.4 |
5.4 |
6.2 |
Machines |
- |
- |
- |
4.8 |
Printing or printing/paper |
19.8 |
30.2 |
36.3 |
19.1 |
Chemicals |
13.3 |
27.1 |
22.8 |
16.2 |
Textiles |
60.6 |
55.0 |
65.1 |
50.0 |
Dress or dress/cleaning —— |
.67.5 |
89.1 |
63.3 |
52.2 |
Food |
10.5 |
19.5 |
34.2 |
22.1 |
Leather |
20.1 |
16.2 |
26.0 |
9.5 |
Wood |
4.2 |
6.4 |
10.9 |
6.1 |
National Total |
22.6 |
33.1 |
23.0 |
18.7 |
D: Changes in % Totals in Major Industries:
Belgium 1890- 1910 |
France 1896-1906 |
Britain 1891-1911 |
Germany 1896- 1907 |
|
Metals or metal/machines |
1.6 |
.1 |
1.2 |
2.0 |
Machines |
— |
— |
— |
1.6 |
Printing or printing/paper |
-2.3 |
2.0 |
6.0 |
6.6 |
Chemicals |
-3.4 |
-3.0 |
6.8 |
1.9 |
Textiles |
16.2 |
4.3 |
2.3 |
4.7 |
Dress or dress/cleaning |
4.9 |
2.3 |
-.4 |
5.1 |
Food |
6.0 |
.9 |
5.9 |
6.1 |
Leather |
12.2 |
2.3 |
4.9 |
3.6 |
Wood |
2.7 |
-.5 |
.2 |
1.4 |
National Total |
-.8 |
1.4 |
1.5 |
.9 |
France |
Britain |
Germany |
1896-1906 |
1891-1911 |
1895-1905 |
1.3 (2.3) |
4.1 (2.4) |
8.5 (3.6) |
— |
20.5 (13.4) |
|
1.8 (2.9) |
3.6 (2.4) |
12.8 (5.1) |
2.1 (4.6) |
6.7 (3.9) |
6.7 (4.1) |
.5 ( .3) |
.5 ( .3) |
1.9 (1.7) |
2.3 (1.1) |
.4 ( .8) |
3.6 (2.6) |
.6 ( .4) |
3.5 (2.2) |
6.4 (2.4) |
.8 (-.3) |
2.5 (1.3) |
8.9 (2.9) |
1.0 (-.1) |
1.9 (1.9) |
4.9 (2.7) |
1.9 (1.9) |
1.7 (1.4) |
3.1 (3.2) |
C: % of All Women in Industry at Last Census Date:
Belgium |
France |
Britain |
Germany |
1.1 |
2.5 |
3.2 |
3.4 |
_ |
— |
— |
2.0 |
1.9 |
2.6 |
5.0 |
1.8 |
1.1 |
1.3 |
1.6 |
1.2 |
41.3 |
26.5 |
30.3 |
24.9 |
41.0 |
56.1 |
28.9 |
21.0 |
2.6 |
4.7 |
18.4 |
11.8 |
.9 |
2.6 |
1.1 |
1.0 |
1.5 |
2.2 |
1.2 |
2.3 |
E: Change in % of All Women in Industry:
Belgium |
France |
Britain |
Germany |
1890- |
1896- |
1891- |
1896- |
1910 |
1906 |
1911 |
1907 |
.3 |
.2 |
1.0 |
1.1 |
_ |
_ |
_ |
1.2 |
.1 |
.4 |
1.3 |
.9 |
.4 |
.2 |
.8 |
.2 |
2.5 |
-2.2 |
-7.6 |
-2.9 |
8.6 |
1.9 |
-8.5 |
1.1 |
1.5 |
-.3 |
4.4 |
2.7 |
.6 |
.1 |
.1 |
.4 |
1.0 |
0 |
0 |
.3 |
throughs. In both, the employment of women increased as a percentage of the total and in both the balance of women in industry changed noticeably. Textiles, clothing and food processing remained the leaders, of course, but printing, metals, engineering, and wood picked up significant numbers. In Germany this often brought relative totals only up near the levels achieved already in France; change, rather than absolute development, is the notable feature. Britain went further, if only because the decline in textiles hit harder — causing a drop in the relative levels of female employment during the 1890s. Levels of employment in printing, wood-working, and to a lesser extent the metal industries were unusually high.19
The entrance of increasing numbers of women into the industrial labor force, despite the doldrums of their traditional industries, was in many ways a remarkable development. Across the board in metals and machine building, in printing everywhere save in Belgium, and widely in wood-working, leather, and food processing the role of women, and certainly their absolute numbers, increased. Women pressed forward also, though in small numbers, in construction and, in Britain, general unskilled labor, a clear sign of the hunger for new jobs once textile employment stopped keeping pace with population growth. The industrial map was not remade, but there was enough change to affect the lives of many women workers and certainly to provoke serious reaction from male workers and from the labor movement. Here was an obvious case in which the reshuffling compelled by changes in the balance among key industries caused serious anxiety as well as, possibly, some important new opportunities.
Children, on the other hand, were increasingly withdrawn from industry. In 1901, in Britain, they were a significant factor only in textiles, and noticeable also in mining, printing, and clothing. By 1911 a general and rapid decline in all industries save textiles, where the traditional reliance on young labor and children's earnings still played an important role, made child labor a negligible factor. (Table IV.) Children remained more significant in Continental industry. In Belgium, 5.6 percent of all industrial workers in 1910 were under fifteen. Available figures for Germany are more difficult to interpret, for they list children under sixteen, well after most would plan to begin an industrial job even in England. Here too, however, while there was no absolute decline, the rate of increase failed to match the overall industrial average. The massive rise of young people in a few industries - metallurgy, chemicals, engineering most notably -reflected less an increase in child labor than the means by which the
more general increase in these industries was affected. New entrants to the work-force were consciously choosing jobs with greater opportunities. Even in 1896, in France, industries that seemed desirable to enter, such as printing, metals, and even textiles, had above average concentrations of people under 24. The delay in the average age of entry to industrial work, plus the changing balance of economic advantage in the industrial spectrum, both prompted the sense of choice. Here, as with women, new concentrations may have promoted a new sense of competition; in a few cases, such as German printing, trade union efforts to restrict entry were reflected in a lower rate of growth than the general average, despite the relative vitality of the industry. But in most of these cases opportunity outweighed the tensions created by new patterns, and the big howls over the entry of young blood came in the declining trades. In these trades, efforts at exclusion, the advice of disappointed parents in the trade, and the young person's own advantage created a slow growth rate, or even, as in leather, a marked drop.
Correspondingly, in terms of the labor force involved, industries aged and, sometimes, feminized, more than they died. Beneath the large categories and without pretending even to mention all the relevant job classifications, some further sense of the contrasting fortunes of various branches of industry must be created. We can begin with the surprisingly important sector of domestic manufacturing, as a case study in decline. We must realize, again, the incomplete extent to which manufacturing was synonymous either with urban or with factory life even in the 1890s. Britain had relatively little domestic production, though we have firm figures only for 1901; by then only a few industries had more than 5 percent of its labor force outside shops or factories. By 1907 only 2.9 percent of all manufacturing labor consisted of outworkers.20 But the 1890s had seen a major battle over outwork, in industries ranging from shoes to needles; in the latter, 60 percent of all workers had been villagers in 1891, after which they rapidly gave way to new factories.21 By 1901 the decline of outwork in Britain was relatively gradual; only in printing, small metal -work, and textiles was it abrupt enough to reflect significant displacement of workers rather than natural attrition.
Germany's battle against home work is easier to trace.22 In 1895 7.7 percent of all manufacturing workers were in the home; by 1907 this was down to 4.7 percent, and the numerical decline was 10.4 percent. This was a rate that involved more than attrition. Textiles, for example, dropped from 27.8 percent to 16.1 percent in the twelve-year census interval. Metal work fell with similar precipitation, to 1.9 percent. Only
Table IV Employment of Children
A. England, Wales, Scotland, under 14:
1901 No. |
% of total workforce in industry |
1911 No. |
% of total |
% change |
|
Transportation |
38,439 |
2.7 |
27,699 |
1.7 |
-27.9 |
Mines |
14,174 |
1.5 |
8,670 |
.7 |
-38.8 |
Metals/machines |
8,305 |
.6 |
5,121 |
.3 |
-38.3 |
Construction |
2,694 |
.2 |
812 |
.1 |
-69.9 |
Wood |
1,605 |
.5 |
864 |
.3 |
-46.2 |
Leather |
1,017 |
.9 |
403 |
.3 |
-60.4 |
Printing |
4,844 |
1.5 |
2,290 |
.6 |
-52.7 |
Textiles |
57,867 |
4.8 |
53,231 |
4.0 |
- 8.0 |
Dress |
12,908 |
1.0 |
8,825 |
.7 |
-31.6 |
Food |
8,239 |
.8 |
3.798 |
.3 |
-53.9 |
Table IV Continued B. Germany, below 16:
1895 No. |
% of total workforce in industry |
1907 No. |
% of total |
% change |
% general change in nos. in the industry |
|
Transportation |
4,479 |
.7 |
7,583 |
2.1 |
69.3 |
-42.6 |
Metallurgy |
300 |
.2 |
11,082 |
4.5 |
359.4 |
58.8 |
Mines |
9,795 |
2.4 |
21,636 |
3.1 |
114.8 |
68.5 |
Machines |
22,010 |
5.9 |
55,830 |
6.1 |
153.6 |
160.6 |
Printing |
11,857 |
9.9 |
16,831 |
8.5 |
29.5 |
61.8 |
Food |
64,725 |
7.4 |
79,741 |
7.1 |
23.2 |
28.6 |
Construction |
55,166 |
4.1 |
82,633 |
4.3 |
86.0 |
42.7 |
Chemicals |
2,720 |
2.6 |
6,793 |
4.3 |
149.7 |
49.0 |
Textiles |
63,943 |
6.5 |
84,618 |
8.0 |
32.3 |
20.8 |
Metal |
77,391 |
9.6 |
113,340 |
9.6 |
46.4 |
42.9 |
Clothes/cleaning |
89,057 |
4.9 |
99,851 |
5.9 |
12.1 |
30.8 |
Leather |
72,345 |
62.6 |
15,272 |
9.6 |
-78.9 |
34.8 |
Wood |
43,330 |
6.7 |
48,410 |
6.1 |
11.7 |
32.9 |
Total |
691,841 |
7.8 |
707,864 |
6.1 |
123.1 |
38.4 |
in clothing - the woman's industry - did home work really survive, with 19.3 percent of the labor force. Otherwise the decline left most home industries filled with older workers — some aged in the industry and incapable of change, others rejects from other jobs. Some workers must have been forced out explicitly. Others had to advise their sons to seek another kind of career. The crisis in home industry was not new, but here, as in Britain a few years earlier, was its final agony. Because it had involved such a significant percentage of workers as late as the mid-'nineties, the death pangs of the system had major ramifications. Some displaced workers could shrug off their loss, when they had worked only to supplement the family income.23 In other cases there was dark despair. Female British outworkers were held to suffer unusually frequent emotional depressions, while many explicitly noted the lingering downfall of their trade.24 And apart from the sentiments of workers directly involved, the decline of home work seriously affected the outlook as well as the numbers of new workers available for factory labor.
Home work retained greater vitality in Belgium and France.25 Fourteen percent of all manufacturing workers were in the home in Belgium in 1896;26 57 percent of all clothing workers were so located. By 1910 the absolute number of domestic workers had risen by 27 percent — an annual increase almost as great as that of industrial labor generally; almost all of them (83 percent) were in textiles and clothing, most of them women. In France the percentage of workers in domestic industry fell only slightly between 1896 and 1906; here, wood, metals, and leather joined clothing and textiles in extensive involvement in this system.27 Thereafter the percentage of home workers declined in metals and wood, though not so fast as to force many workers out directly; it fell precipitously in textiles, clearly compelling many workers to drop out of industry, enter factory employment, or most commonly, switch to clothing. For the system held up in clothing and also in leather, keeping the national rate relatively steady. Its vitality was aided by a desire to avoid social legislation and the greater manipulability, in terms of pay and conditions, of a labor force isolated in the home and, sometimes at least, self-satisfied that it had avoided the perils of urban life.28 Maintenance, even revival, of home work could be found elsewhere, as in the German tobacco industry during the 1890s; here too, light, simple equipment and the need to find cheap labor that was easy to dismiss during seasonal slumps spurred the system along.29
The point is not so much to stress the immense variety concealed
Table V Domestic Manufacturing Workers and Employers
France: |
1896 |
1901 |
% of total in industry No. |
% of total in industry Mo. |
|
Metals |
16.0 101,488 |
13.1 96,766 |
Wood |
31.6 214,130 |
28.6 200,633 |
Printing & paper |
3.7 4,994 |
3.2 5,113 |
Food |
8.5 39,708 |
7.8 41,634 |
Textiles |
23.1 224.813 |
19.1 185,103 |
Clothes |
51.8 552,698 |
58.6 713,024 |
Leather |
33.8 113,156 |
36.8 124,362 |
Building |
22.2 121,000 |
19.3 101,005 |
Chemicals |
.9 5,462 |
.6 4,935 |
All industries |
25.8 1,398,618 |
24.9 1,465,614 |
% of % of total change in industry |
%of No. change |
|
Metals |
-4.8 12.3 |
96,766 -1.4 |
Wood |
-5.3 28.4 |
200,133 -1.3 |
Printing & paper |
2.4 4.4 |
7,768 51.9 |
Pood |
4.8 7.6 |
41,634 -7.6 |
Textiles |
-18.5 19.0 |
185,103 1.8 |
Clothes |
29.0 58.3 |
713,024 5.4 |
Leather |
9.9 36.5 |
121,985 -1.9 |
Building |
-9.9 19.0 |
102,667 -5.8 |
Chemicals |
-10.7 .5 |
4,878 -1.1 |
All industries |
4.8 25.3 |
1,530,397 4.4 |
Kngland:
% of total in each industry 1901 1911 |
% change in no. of workers |
|
Machines |
.5 .4 |
|
Metallurgy |
3.2 2.7 |
-3.8 |
Other metals |
4.7 3.1 |
-2.3 |
Vehicles |
7.4 4.7 |
-1.6 |
Printing |
1.7 .8 |
-36.9 |
Food |
0 0 |
|
Textiles |
2.1 1.5 |
-21.7 |
Chemicals |
.4 .2 |
within the general occupational structure as to emphasize the odd combination of persistence and rapid upheaval that characterized much of the older sector of industry as the economy matured. Almost any work system that had existed during the past two centuries could still be found, sometimes, in little pockets, enjoying a certain vitality. An untold number of workers were directly forced from their initial jobs, as in the cases of precipitous decline in the domestic manufacturing system. Far more commonly workers aged with their trade, often increasingly frustrated as the system declined, and their children were pushed or drawn into a new work setting — either relieved to escape their parents' dilemma or bitter that they could not continue the old ways.30
Almost all the slow-growth industries, and a few catchalls such as metal work, embraced sectors of outright decline or aging. Most included a large number of shops as well, only a step removed from the same process of decline and only a bit more advanced in terms of industrial organization. In 1907 33 percent of all shops in German furniture-making, and 96 percent in basket-making, had no machinery, only hand tools. Quarries in Baden had their own traditional skill categories, and the workers lived a semi-rural existence little changed from a century before. Except for a few Italians recently brought in, most were of local agricultural origin, and they kept gardens and farm animals; their companies were small and their employers often workers risen from the ranks (while some workers had been employers in their own right before). And their numbers increased significantly — by 60 percent between 1895 and 1910 — falling back only in the years immediately preceding the war.31 Of course industries of this sort were fated for decline, though there were always islands of prosperity for the small concern — like the precious metals firms in Britain — to slow the overall process.32 In Britain, between 1897 and 1907, the number of workers in shops fell from 14.8 percent of the total in manufacturing to 12.5 percent — a decline that involved relatively litle direct displacement but a good bit of switching out of the fathers' industry.33 Furniture suffered radically, falling from 44 percent to 29 percent in shops; here the shop workers declined by 29 percent, more than natural attrition could account for. But shop-employed tailors dropped only 7 percent in the decade; again, there was considerable variety. The fate of the small shop was clear — in Britain the number of such units stopped expanding after 1912, promising further reductions in the labor force involved — but its hand moved slowly. Industries such as furniture-making and clothing were long polarized between shops and machine
factories, quite apart from the lingering outworker element.
Yet decline there was in traditional settings and, even where the numbers of workers were still more heavily involved in the older industries than the new, one's eye is inevitably drawn to the high growth, mechanized, factory settings. The overall evolution, however qualified by invocations of diversity and gradualism, raises a final structural question, which at this point can be more clearly stated than answered: What was happening to skill levels in the working class? We know that a new type of worker, the semi-skilled, was rising in engineering, printing, and some other areas; while census categories prevent its being statistically traced, the growth of such industries, and of women workers in them, provide some outline. But as for the more traditional, if gross, distinction between skilled and unskilled the situation is less clear.34 In wood, leather, and some branches of food processing, slow or negative growth, feminization, and the few instances of an increase of domestic manufacturing denote a decline in skills. Again, skilled workers were not necessarily directly replaced, but entry was curtailed and the skilled group aged. This is the pattern suggested, for example, by the wide gap between the growth of tailors and of clothing manufacturers generally in Britain.35 On the other hand, several of the large, slow-growth industries, such as textiles, traditionally offered only modest skill levels, so their relative decline could have been part of an upgrading. And all of the high-growth industries involved a significant skilled component, even if aone was devoid of ambiguity. The increase of transport workers, for example, included a large leaven of dockers and road-workers whose skill levels could be quite low; but evidence from Britain, at least, suggests that the railroad labor force, which did involve significant skills, grew more rapidly than the other components in transportation. Mining and quarrying involved skill, but often of a rough sort; certainly the extractive industries recruited widely among unskilled elements and there was some sense, particularly in the quarries, that the unskilled were taking over instead of receiving proper training in a job hierarchy. Hence Welsh quarrymen tried to insist that 'the skilled quarryman is the best man to employ on every kind of rock.'36 Construction work provided an even more obvious mixture of skilled and unskilled elements. Both gained in number during the period, but both were susceptible to unusual fluctuations; everywhere the construction labor force declined significantly between 1901 and 1906, and most of the evidence suggests that, as expected, an industry subject to such fluctuations took a particular toll among the unskilled. In France the
unskilled (terrassier) segment did lose slightly less ground than the skilled, probably because of the unusual activity still connected with the construction of Paris subways. Even so there was significant loss, and the concomitant rapid rise of the transportation labor force suggests the possibility of a massive influx into dock work and hauling. When prosperity returned, however, the skilled increased far more rapidly. In Britain the unskilled comprised a smaller percentage in the first place (46 percent among bricklayers, but only 24 percent among masons) and when the slump hit they suffered far more substantially, though the rise of a new category of builders' laborers helped compensate somewhat. More consistently, over the period as a whole, the rapid decline, feminization and probable aging of the 'general labor' pool in Britain suggests the channeling of unskilled males into more specific job categories, some of which — like important aspects of dock work — were not really unskilled.37
In sum, the number of unskilled in industry and transport increased, though their vulnerability to economic fluctuations was still great. They recruited from agriculture, particularly on the Continent, and also probably from a general labor pool in the cities. New builders' laborers in Britain, for example, were a mixture of rural and urban, with the urban predominating; some had tried other jobs, others had never received training, and all tended to be older than the new entrants to the skilled ranks.38 It is improbable that the increase in the unskilled outstripped that of the skilled or that large numbers of skilled before their later years, were forced into unskilled ranks — hence the need for a distinctive recruitment base of many unskilled among the rural, the foreign, and some women. Furthermore, it is probable that the nature of unskilled work changed, becoming a bit more job-specific and involving a bit more training than had characterized early industrial society.39
But this made it all the more possible that skilled workers, even when increasing in numbers, felt a certain threat as they saw not only a rapid influx of newcomers but a diminishing gap between their attainments and those of the unskilled. This is not an issue, unfortunately, that census data can resolve, for we do not know enough about the balance in key industries such as mining or engineering. And the real historical problem involves perception as much as raw data; it must be part of the detailed examination of work, for which occupational structure provides only a framework.
The maturation of industry confronted relatively few workers with direct displacement, except in periods of recession. Where census data reveal significant numerical decline, they apply mainly to rural areas.
Far more common was attrition through aging, that could leave important pockets of older workers cut off from the bulk of the working class. In some industries, such as woodwork, many threatened workers became small proprietors instead of leaving the industry, which helps account for the rise of employers relative to workers; their existence may have profited little from this switch — which continued even after World War I in Germany - but the sense of ownership may have provided compensation not available to ordinary workers. Dis-placement was thus masked as well as limited.
For many workers the theme of expanding opportunity must have been predominant, as the rapid growth of a number of solid industries, offering high skill levels and good pay, was evident to many new entrants to the labor force. Young males benefited particularly from the resultant freedom to choose, but some young women and unskilled workers may have found new opportunities as well.
Yet the slowing of growth for the whole working class and the major reshuffling that was occurring within the industrial labor force left their mark. Generalization is risky of course, given the great diversity of situations. But large numbers of workers were exposed to strangers, some of them with a rural outlook but others with a background in mother traditional industry that was failing to keep pace. Large numbers of workers had to choose — or wanted to choose — occupations that differed from those of their parents. Parents had to worry about placing their offspring, and it is surely no accident that this period of a slowing of growth saw new working-class efforts at birth control, beginning particularly in the artisanal trades and textiles which were the first to see the threat materialize. Change there was, then, and it could be exciting and challenging; but it was not open-ended.
Notes
1. Walter Timmermann, Die Entlohnungsmethoden in der Hannoverschen Eisenindustrie (Berlin, 1906); Alfred Williams, Life in a Railway Factory (London, 1915), 11 ff.; B. Seebohm Rowntree, Land and Labour: Lessons from Belgium (London, 1911), 289.
2. Wilhelm Brepohl, Industrievolk im Wandel von der agraren zur industriellen Daseiform dargestellt am Ruhrgebiet (Tubingen, 1957).
3. Rowntree, Land, 290; Zentralverband der Maurer Deutschlands, Der Kampfum die Arbeitsbedingungen (Hamburg, 1909).
4. Docker's Record, December 1913.
5. Archives départementales des Bouches-du-Rhône M6—2050, reports of 1909—10; Max Fleischer, Zwei Krisenjahre im rheinischer Bergbau (Frankfurt, 1905).
6. Mary A. Hamilton, Mary MacArthur (London, 1925), 80 ff.
7. Operative Masons' Journal, 1 April 1914.
8. All tables in this chapter are based on the four national census series: Ministère de l'industrie et du travail (Belgium), Recensement general de la population, 1890, 1900, 1910 (Brussels, 1892-1912); Census of England and Wales, 1891, 1901, 1911 (London, 1893 — 1916); Tenth through Twelfth Decennial Census of Scotland (Glasgow, 1893-1903; London, 1913); Ministère du commerce (later, Ministère du travail), Résultats statistiques du recensement général de la population, 1896—1911; Statistik des deutschen Reichs, Neue Folge 102-19 and 202-22.
9. J. C. Toutain, La Population de la France de 1700 à 1959 (Paris, 1962).
10. A few obvious categories of dealers (in dress), innkeepers (in food) have been eliminated in all calculations on the British materials. But in other groups — e.g. metals — not only employers but also many tradespeople are included. This inflates British figures over those on the continent, where commercial categories were more fully developed.
11. See Appendix, Table I.
12. See Appendix, Table II, for more detail.
13. See Appendix, Table IA and Table IID.
14. See Appendix, Table IIC.
15. See Appendix, Table III.
16. The generally low level of growth in France between 1901 and 1906 makes the absence of sex-specific data for 1911 particularly unfortunate. By 1911 French developments were probably more comparable with those in Britain and Germany. But see note 18.
17. Theresa M. McBride, Rural Tradition and the Process of Modernization (Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Rutgers University, 1973), 143 ff., discusses the economic advantages involved in servant work that persisted until the 1870s in France.
18. See Appendix, Table IV. In Britain, in contrast, the employment of married women in industry barely kept pace with population growth. Peter N. Stearns, 'Working-Class Women in Britain, 1890-1914,' in M. Vicinus, éd., Suffer and Be Still (Bloomington, Ind., 1972), 100 ff.; On Germany, Peter N. Stearns, 'Adaptation to Industrialization: German Workers as a Test Case,' Central European History (1970), 303 ff.; Ernest Dubois, Le Travail des femmes mariées dans la grande industrie allemande (Paris, 1902). French data are far less firm; in 1895 22 and 33 percent of the women in clothing shops and textile plants were married, and a whopping 45 percent of all women in out work, but this (as the declining average age of workers in. manufacturing suggests) could
not hold steady. It is known that the contribution of women to family budgets increased at least until 1906, when it averaged 12 percent of total family earnings in the working class; but by 1914 it was down to 5.4 percent, which may reflect the immense difficulties of the traditional women's industries in France. Maurice Halbwachs, 'Revenus et dépenses des travailleurs. Une enquête officielle d'avant-guerre,' Revue d'économie politique (1921), 52. 19. Stearns, 'Women,' passim.
20. Aaron L. Levine, Industrial Retardation in Britain (London, 1967), 27 ff.
21. G. L. Allen, The Industrial Development of Birmingham and the Black Country (London, 1929), 228 ff.
22. Heinrich Koch, Die deutsche Hausindustrie (Monchen-Gla.dbach, 1913), 173 and passim.
23. Ibid., passim.
24. Select Committee on Home Work, Report and Minutes of Evidence (London, 1908 HC 246), 11.
25. Rowntree, Land 85 ff.; Fernand Baudhouin, Belgique 1900 -I960 (Louvain, 1961).
26. This percentage is of manufacturing alone — not mining, construction, or transport. The 1910 figure, for example, is but 0.9 percent of the entire manufacturing-transport labor force, which is in fact probably too low but which cannot be corrected from the census data. What needs stress is the persistence of home work, given the clothing industry above all, not the comparative rate, for it is possible but not proved that Belgium had a higher rate overall.
27. The French percentages include independent artisans; this accounts, among other things, for the French rate in construction, where self-employed, rather than domestic, workers were really involved. In contrast British figures cited here and in the text do not include self-employed, and the German material is unclear. So it must be emphasized that France did not necessarily have a much higher rate of real domestic work than Germany and not so much more than Britain as the figures here might suggest. Despite stereotypes we do not know that the French were especially addicted to domestic manufacturing outside of clothing; It is the persistence that commands attention.
28. Pierre Clerget, Les Industries de la soie en France (Paris, 19 25), 97 ff.
29. Walther Frisch, Die Organisationsbestrebungen der Arbeiter in der deutschen Tabakindustrie (Leipzig, 1905).
30. Sidney Pollard, History of Labour in Sheffield (Liverpool, 1959).
31. Fôhlich, Die Steinindustrie in Grossherzogtum Baden (Karlsruhe, 1913), passim; Bernard Schildbach, 'Arbeitstarifvertrage in der Holzindustrie,' Jahrbùcher fur Nationalôkonomie (1910), 807 ff.
32. Allen, Development, 248.
33. Levine, Retardation, 22 ff.; Pollard, Sheffield, passim.
34. Application, certainly, in the mid-nineteenth century; William Sewell, 'La classe ouvrière de Marseilles sous la seconde république,' Mouvement social (1971), 27—63.
35. See Appendix, Table IIC.
36. W. J. Parry, Penrhyn Lockout, 1900-1901 (London, 1901), 113.
37. See Appendix, Table IIC and D; Norman B. Dearie, Problems of Unemployment in the London Building Trades (London, 1908).
38. Dearie, Problems, passim.
39. In Western Europe today it takes at least five years to 'train' an unskilled worker coming in from a non-industrialized area. The category unskilled is far from being a constant, and changes in the background required almost surely developed in this period. Stephen Castle and Godula Kosack, Immigration and Class Structure in Western Europe (London, 1973).
CHAPTER 2 JOB CHOICE IN A MATURING INDUSTRIAL ECONOMY
The entrance of workers into the labor force has often been discussed in general terms, particularly during the formative stages of in-dustrialization. Attention has focused on push-pull factors: whether workers were impelled to journey to the cities because of population pressure and, sometimes, additional restrictions on work in agriculture; or whether they were drawn into industrial work because of higher potential earnings, the ability to escape parental restraints at a particularly vulnerable stage of life, the desire to abandon the monotony of village routine, and so on. Undoubtedly pressure on the land set the stage for the decision to enter industry, but for a teenager, traditionally compelled to remain within the parental orbit while waiting to inherit land, the 'pull' hypothesis has merit as well. By the late nineteenth century the terms of analysis can be refined somewhat. 'Push' still operated. Continued population growth, even though now reduced in rate, combined with the agricultural crisis, improved rural technology, and the displacement of small owners in many rural areas as a minority of peasants increased the size of their landed holdings. Traditional rural alternatives to peasant effort, notably domestic manufacturing and rural craft labor, continued to stagnate or even decline outright. As this work increasingly became the exclusive province of older workers, it offered no opportunities for new entrants to the labor force.1 Paid agricultural labor itself became slightly more attractive, in terms of wages offered, but this merely reflected the fact that increasing numbers of people were seeking other alternatives, thus shrinking the agricultural labor pool. And, vital in terms of the present analysis, the work aspects of paid agricultural service did not improve. Hours from sunup to sunrise, during the growing season, and frequent periods of unemployment combined with strict direction from employers.2 Indeed, in this latter regard, there were growing complaints that many peasants and estate managers were becoming more peremptory3 — doubtless an effect of the need to improve competitive position in a tight market; so some of the possible paternal cushions of traditional agriculture were being eliminated.
But there was less sheer compulsion to abandon agriculture than had existed earlier, at least in the sense of inability to survive in some form
of rural labor. This was reflected in the diminished rate of migration to the cities in the advanced industrial countries. In turn, this suggests that the rural people who did move were making a positive decision to seek something different, while manufacturing jobs were more and more commonly filled by people born in cities in the first place. Yet when we ask more detailed questions about why people chose the jobs they did and indeed whether they had any sense of choice at all, the element of compulsion still looms large. Growing numbers of people were seeking higher earnings and more regular work; yet many of them had little sense of positive selection in the jobs they took to attain these new goals. Here in fact, even before a job was begun, was a basis for the separation between the fruits of work — wages — and work itself. If there was little reason for the job, as opposed to other jobs, there was scant basis for enjoying the job itself. Key groups of workers had distinctive reasons for not discerning a positive choice in the jobs they took, and in combination the sense of randomness, even purpose-lessness, was widespread.
Other workers did assign reasons to their commitment to one job instead of another. They tended to cluster in the more prestigeous occupations, but they can be found in other ranks as well. Certain industries tended to attract workers with particular characteristics and goals. Some of these were frustrated, having had definite hopes that they were unable to fulfill, but others really had some sense of wanting to be in the occupation they had chosen. What we are trying to get at is the diversity of motivations that brought workers to their work, a diversity that would to a significant degree predict the kinds of satisfactions that could be derived from the work.
Obviously, materials on job choices are impressionistic, but collectively they prove fairly convincing — even though they are certainly inapplicable to every individual case. Thanks to the fervor of German sociologists, we have most detailed information on the dilemmas of German workers, a large number of them fresh from the countryside. This can be contrasted particularly with the more settled situation in Britain, where industrial experience was of far longer standing. British information is by no means comparable in detail, but it conveys a probable and somewhat surprising transition from the more fluid patterns of a rapidly-growing industrial economy.
In focusing on job choice, rather than the more general fact of being in the industrial labor force, we are exploring a rather new topic with a high element of subjectivity. The whole notion of choice may seem inappropriate to those who prefer to judge workers in terms of their
powerlessness in the overall economic structure. But one can admit the compulsions which capitalism imposed upon labor and still attempt to examine the real belief that workers — some ardent socialists among them — could have in explaining why they, personally, were doing one job and not another. Within this framework, the initial question to be asked is in essence simple: What kinds of workers felt they could account for why they had their jobs, as opposed to those who could assign no real reason? It would be tidy if we could link this question to a more general process, such as modernization, and assert that those workers who could discuss reasons for their holding a particular job had advanced farther toward a modern level of decision-making than their less articulate fellows. But the question of choice is more complex than this. A worker might have a quite clear notion of why he had a job and yet be bounded in fact by very limited regional horizons. Parental guidance was one of the most common factors cited by workers who could explain their situation, and this was indeed an important element in the lives of many workers. Yet was a worker thus guided more independent than one who could give no reason at all for his job? He might after all be a more rigid traditionalist. The definition of choice in a broad pattern of industrial change is thus difficult. And those workers who lacked a sense of choice were in no sense necessarily behaving irrationally or without cause; they may, as we will see, have made some extremely important decisions to enter the industrial labor force in the first place. But here we are back to the push-pull framework, in which the worker's own thinking about choosing his particular job is either unobtainable or never really existed at all. When we deal with workers who did think they made choices we can talk about the various kinds of factors that influenced them. In so doing we can begin to explain reactions to the nature of work itself, for anticipation would play a major role in ongoing judgements. We can further advance our understanding of the complexity of the industrial labor force. For a study of job choice, by the time that industry was reaching a certain maturity, produces a number of important conclusions. While some workers seem almost random elements in the industrial process, others played an active role in finding their occupational slot — ev en if they found themselves disappointed in it (for choice is not equivalent to satisfaction). Nor were workers, even apart from regional restrictions on the labor market, tools of simple market forces alone. Their own criteria might play down wage advantages in favor of more intangible factors, even to the point of affecting the rate and nature of industrialization itself. Nor, finally, were workers who sensed a choice
united in what to make of it. If we begin with the simplest distinctions, between workers following traditional criteria of choice and those bereft of choice, we must end with a complicated list of factors to explain why workers thought they had the jobs they had.
It is easy to identify the workers who could most readily account for choosing their jobs. The traditional crafts long stood at the top of the list of occupations to be sought. Not only sons of urban artisans but also newcomers from the countryside with some manufacturing background assumed that craft labor was to be preferred over all other manufacturing work — even at the expense of maximizing earnings. A Berlin shoemaker in the late 1880s urged his profession on his son: 'There is no need to be pressed into factories or to work outside your home and according to the steam whistle.' In shoe-making 'something of the old craft Gemutlichkeif remained.4 In France many shoemakers refused to leave their homes to enter the factory, even after machine competition severely reduced wages, for they valued their freedom, seeking not only to work at their own pace but also such simple pleasures as the freedom to smoke on the job.5 And if this choice still made sense in a declining craft, the attractiveness of high-paying artisanal jobs would be all the more obvious. In Bremen in the 1890s jobs were chosen in a rather traditional community setting. The Protestant pastor helped advise children on their profession, and of course paternal guidance played a great role. Competition for apprenticeship jobs was intense, and a boy would be very proud if he was able to win training in printing or a comparable craft; he could even hope to have a two-years' Wanderszeit (tramping period) once he completed the apprenticeship.6
Obviously the craft framework was strongest in countries like Germany where industrialization was still relatively new, but the prestige of traditional skills continued to have great appeal even in England, particularly in the villages and smaller towns. Robert Tressell described the tendency for sons to follow fathers into the construction trades in Hastings, adding that in part this derived from the fathers' desire to confirm their own worth by making sure that their sons did not rise above them.7 Parisian masons, who still clustered around City Hall and the He Saint-Louis, preserved even in a great city the kind of community structure in which entry into the crafts would be a logical job choice, urged by the fathers and accepted without question by most sons.8
Yet this pattern of selection was increasingly threatened by the end of the nineteenth century, since opportunities in the crafts did not
expand as rapidly as claimants upon them. General population growth played a role here, though urban artisans were quick to reduce their birth rate which compensated somewhat. In many trades stepped-up pressure from employers plus the introduction of new machinery reduced the quality of apprenticeship and gave a variety of newcomers access to previously skilled jobs. This was a constant threat in printing once composing machines began to spread in the 1890s. British printers' unions, having long tried to limit the number of workers who could operate the machines, had to yield to employer demands in 1895 and allow workers to learn machine skills on their own.9 Here as elsewhere there were recurring complaints that apprenticeship was decaying because the novice was no longer taught the whole skill.10 Machines in Belgian cabinet-making even more seriously cut into apprenticeship, particularly in Brussels; here, only the smaller companies continued any formal training, and these taught only portions of the traditional skill, and in bad conditions.11 The rest of the trade was being taken over by factories.
Where the factory system was not triumphant, however, dilution of apprenticeship, though often discussed, was not too serious. Printers, for example, were widely successful in maintaining a thorough apprenticeship even for workers destined for the machines. Lyons dyers, fighting the intrusion of unskilled labor, insisted on a fixed period of training and a set proportion of apprentices.12 Pressure on apprenticeship set part of the framework for the crisis of the artisanry, but other factors, including key decisions by artisans themselves, played a more direct role.
Very simply, the increasing invalidity of rural and village crafts, against factory competition, forced more and more trained journeymen into the cities. This, along with the pressures described above, prompted urban craftsmen to develop new devices for limiting entry to their ranks. The result, inevitably, was widespread frustration and confusion in job choice.
Rural journeymen had long faced declining opportunities. In one home industry after another fathers at some point had to stop urging their sons into their own profession. By the turn of the century this was occurring in shoe-making and clothing manufacture particularly, but also in metal work and in pockets of rural weaving.13 Some sons gladly escaped into the factories, where they could earn good money.14 But far more were prompted by their own background and their fathers' advice to try to get a job in the urban crafts. For many, the job choice was thought to have been made before migration to the cities occurred.
Villages and small towns continued to maintain a very high ratio of apprentices to journeymen. In France, printers in towns of less than 5000 population had one apprentice per three workers, compared to one in five in the larger cities and one in seven in Paris.15 The same pattern prevailed in Belgian cabinet-making, British construction work, German locksmithing, and many other trades. When home-town opportunities dried up it was logical to try to move one's profession to a city. A large number of skilled construction workers in London, for example, had been trained in the provinces.16 But the chances of entry into the urban crafts grew more and more remote.
Large numbers of traditionally transient workers were settling down by the 1890s. There were still the East German village masons who went every summer to the larger cities to earn big money, but generally this pattern was declining. Parisian masons still came disproportionately from the Marche or the Limoges area, but many of them lived permanently in Paris and scorned newcomers from the countryside for their willingness to accept poor wages and working conditions.17 They, and even more the members of trades such as printing, worked on devices to keep newcomers out. Craft exclusivism is of course no new theme, but it is vital to realize how effective it was still around the turn of the century. Everywhere construction workers sought to define their skills with increasing precision. French construction workers turned against formal apprenticeship altogether, limiting entry mainly to their own sons whom they trained themselves. Glovemakers in Limoges won an agreement in 1904 limiting the training of apprentices to urban workers alone and forbidding the assignment of any work to new rural journeymen; for three years there was to be no new apprenticeship at all, save for the sons and brothers of existing urban workers. The number of apprentices in printing declined dramatically. Once 55 percent of the total in Germany, they formed only 26.5 percent of all printers by 1906, and less than that in the largest cities; the union-enforced scale of apprentices thus had a dramatic effect. And in Germany legislation supporting formal apprenticeship carried this process still further; the 1908 'proof of capability' law allowed artisan masters to test and judge apprentices, and only when these latter had reached 24 years of age, in any local profession in which a compulsory Innung had been formed.18
Artisans did not adopt limitation measures without some regret, for they could threaten other aspects of the defense of the profession. While most French journeymen resisted apprentices because of the competition they provided, a few expressed fears that their craft would
die out for want of proper training. The sense that good workers were declining because of changes in apprenticeship was widespread, and it could add to the anxieties older artisans felt about their whole way of work.19 But there is no doubt about what was actually happening. Entry to the most dynamic crafts was increasingly confined to the urban-born, leaving out the masses of rural aspirants. In Berlin printing, for example, 50 percent of all workers were born in the city itself, far above the overall population ratio; while in all of Germany only 29 percent of all printers had been born outside large cities, again a proportion well below the ratios even within the big-city population. In the early 1890s 81 percent of London bookbinders and 66 percent of all London printers had been born in the city, in contrast to 53 percent of factory laborers and 22 percent of all railway laborers.2 ° And within the urban group, an increasing number of journeymen simply followed their fathers into the profession. Mobility was not cut off, but it was definitely restricted. Again in German printing, a union survey revealed that only 18 percent of the grandfathers of existing printers had been printers, whereas 50 percent of their fathers had been in this trade.21 There is little doubt that, were similar data on other crafts available, they would suggest the same pattern of increasing concentration within existing craft families.
Yet even this does not exhaust the complicated behavior of the urban artisanry. From a number of crafts came reports of sons' increasing reluctance to follow their fathers' career choice. In Grenoble glove manufacturers had to give special subsidies to induce entry into apprenticeship, for new, higher-paying industries lured youths away and made their parents loath to pay out the 200-300 francs that traditional apprenticeship would cost.22 In Dijon and elsewhere, children of furniture-makers were drawn into the iron industry. Some were encouraged by their parents, who were disheartened by the prospects of their own trade and convinced that apprenticeship had deteriorated anyway; they wanted their children to better themselves by earning more money. But others went against the wishes of their fathers, who thought that their ability to obtain jobs for their sons and provide them with tools at low cost should override any strivings for independence.23 Here, and even in better-paying trades such as printing, the sense that sons were impatient with a training period and eager to earn right away was widespread. It is not far-fetched to suggest a considerable erosion of parental authority in these cases, a desire to choose work not because of tradition or the intrinsic nature of the work itself but because of its instrumental value in providing higher pay. The confusion
caused among older journeymen by the many changes in the techniques and organization of the crafts could only have furthered this partial rebellion. Even in Germany where, as we will see, the instrumental view of work was less fully developed than in France and Britain, there were indications that a growing number of families in the most prestigeous crafts sought to send their children into higher professions; one survey in Berlin and Leipzig found over 40 percent of the sons of all printers who were of working age serving as booksellers, technicians, teachers, lawyers, and bureaucrats. Less definitively, the same survey reported the impression that this kind of mobility had become newly-important.24
We can, then, suggest a twofold movement in the urban crafts. Fathers and sons, or sons alone, were in many cases concluding that craft work had lost its validity. This impelled a career choice based on earning power and/or status in the community at large. The impression was — though it can only be an impression — that this kind of choice was spreading. It was naturally more widespread in countries in which artisanal traditions had been more thoroughly eroded, as in France in contrast to Germany. But everywhere a still larger number of fathers and sons worked with great success to preserve a career choice in which a young man would count himself lucky to follow his father's footsteps, for a greater percentage of the ranks of urban craftsmen were filled through this kind of choice than at any point since industrialization had begun.
And this in turn meant that more aspirants for craft jobs were disappointed than ever before. Even many of the young men who opted for the high wages of factory work probably were influenced by their fear that the crafts would be closed to them. Still more ended up in the factories simply because the jobs they really wanted were unavailable. Carl Severing described a distressingly common pattern. His father, a cigar maker, hoped that his son would become a preacher, while Severing himself wanted to be a musician. Relevant training was too expensive, to the family's great distress. So the father decided on a career as a tailor, then as printer; but printing proved impossible because of the number of candidates. So Severing became a locksmith, and after apprenticeship in a small shop (where he also learned his socialism) he ultimately found work in a sewing machine factory.25 This kind of frustration was recounted by many German workers, who were most vulnerable because of the rapidity of industrialization and the sudden decline of the small town crafts, but it operated in all the industrial countries to some extent. In a period of increasing change,
the most logical job choice involved following one's father, where the paternal profession offered any kind of security and status. Where this choice was impossible, as in the many stagnating crafts, it was then most logical to seek a job in another, but economically more viable, craft. Yet this was more difficult than ever before. So many young men took work which was at best their third choice, and found it difficult if not impossible to shake off the frustration, the sense of declining status, which this kind of imposed choice placed upon them.
We find the frustrated journeymen in the factories above all, though not a few, hampered by some family disaster or their own ill health, tumbled into unskilled casual labor; the ranks of London dockers, for example, were swelled by refugees from decaying crafts in the East End.26 In the factories the craftsmen tried to recreate much of the ambiance of the crafts themselves. German locksmiths prided themselves as being from the best families, using the familiar form of address only among friends, rather than with their workmates generally.27 Limoges porcelain painters similarly insisted on being called 'Monsieur' by the ovenmen.28 Certainly there was a widespread effort to limit access to the factory skill. British iron founders pressed for limitation of apprenticeship agreements, succeeding in Sheffield (where they cut the number of apprentices to one per three workers). British engineers In one dispute declared that 'we were determined that we would not in any way assist, instruct, or help those whom [employers] selected other than skilled turners.'29 Much of the familiar history of internecine rivalries within a factory labor force stems from the kind of compensations workers sought for a career that was not their first choice. Some of course found genuine interest in their work, like the most highly skilled workers in precision manufacturing in Berlin; many of these further hoped to earn or learn enough to rise to independent status or into the company bureaucracy. But others, trained in a more traditional craft, could only feel that their profession had deteriorated as they found themselves locked into factory work.30 The metal trades, particularly in Germany, provide a host of examples of this kind of anxiety. The workers characteristically had fathers who were journeymen and who had warned them against factory labor. They had been taught that factory workers were idle people, 'Bummler' or louts, who took no joy in their work, and as children some of them had seen the workers dragging home, dirty and tired, after a day in the factory.31 Then, for want of craft jobs, they found themselves in the factories. High wages might compensate to some extent, but these were not workers who found high wages appropriate as the principal basis for a
job choice; the instrumental view of work was forced upon them, not freely adopted, and the work itself was all the harder to value as it had been reviled in their own upbringing.
And everywhere the effort to maintain craft traditions in the factories came under increasing attack at the turn of the century. German furniture-makers, citing their long apprenticeship and their purchase of their own tools, resented other workers in the new factories who rivaled their earnings even though 'their technical ability was less.' In contrast to the crafts, few factory groups were able to limit training; the British Amalgamated Society of Engineers lost a bitter battle on this subject in 1898. Here is where -formal apprenticeship really declined, for where factories needed traditional skills they had only to recruit from the small town craftsmen.32 This was the approach taken by the rising furniture factories in Brussels and in German metal production, where former locksmiths were used so extensively.33 Erosion of skills and job controls meant erosion of personal status within the factory. The skilled worker, often frustrated in his actual job choice, could easily sense a deterioration in the evolution of factory labor after about 1890, because it departed still further from the criteria he sought in a job in the first place. An exhaustive study of German textile and metal workers produced overwhelming evidence that the vast majority of these workers had had higher goals in their youth than they were able to realize in their actual jobs.34
We can suggest, then, that the workers who felt most completely masters of their destiny were still to be found in the urban crafts, save where these were under direct attack by factory competition. These workers chose their jobs with a sense of their fathers' example before them, according to values promoted by an artisanal community that remained quite real. They had to fight to maintain their sense of control, particularly by limiting entry to their ranks, and they were by no means immune from changes in the nature of their work. But they were generally successful in preserving their status and their ability to base family continuity on continued access to the craft. Though a minority from this group would opt for more substantial social mobility or the lure of higher wages, most chose a job which would provide a combination of relatively high status, relatively high earnings, and considerable intrinsic satisfaction. This was the only large group of workers capable of this kind of choice, but far more wanted nothing better than to emulate it. Hence the theme of frustration echoed so often in individual statements by workers and in general, typically abortive movements to reproduce the same combination of values in
other settings.
Most groups of factory and transport workers had a considerable element drawn from the craft orbit, often (particularly in Germany) with direct craft training and even more widely with important elements of the craft mentality. Most German studies of worker origins revealed a far higher percentage of artisanal (including, almost certainly, domestic manufacturing) than of peasant ancestry, for factory labor; in a leather plant 40 percent of workers reported grandfathers who had been Handwerker compared to only a third from peasant stock, while in a textile factory in Eastern Germany workers with artisan fathers outnumbered peasants about three to one.35 The fact that many of these workers clustered at the top of the factory labor force in terms of skill and earnings makes their potential disappointment all the more significant, for they were often in a position to translate it into active protest.
Against the artisanal background we can measure the other large group of relatively new entrants to factory life, clustered mainly in the lower skill levels. These were people from a traditionalist environment also, but a much more static one. Where would-be artisans customarily made a conscious decision to enter a trade, in close consultation with fathers and even community leaders, many of the unskilled had no pattern of choice before them. They might dream of an artisanal life, but their dreams would be quickly dashed. Were they better off for their relative freedom from expectations that they could control their lot? Was purposelessness — from the standpoint of occupational choice — better than frustration? The goals of many new workers were not really wrapped up in the job at all, for they expected no joy from work. Ironically, many of the unskilled were closer to an instrumental view of the job than were the workers with artisanal values. But we must look at their apparent motivations before we can even conjecture about the relative satisfactions they might derive, in comparison with the artisans, from a factory setting.
A study of textile labor in a Mônchen-Gladbach factory gives a precise, if statistically limited, framework for the type of workers who seemed, by their own admission, to drift through their lives of work. Only 38 percent of his workers could give a precise reason for their choice of industry. Almost 13 percent assigned need, rather vague in itself. Another 13 percent said they were following their fathers' profession, though in fact in a full 31 percent of cases the fathers had been textile workers, suggesting that following the parental example was less compelling in some factories than in the crafts. Only 12
percent said they chose textiles because it offered a good job. Thirty-five percent specifically said they could not account for why they took the job they did. This uncertainty was confirmed by the fact that 59 percent of all workers under 21 had already had two jobs and 41 percent more than two, while 23 percent of all workers between 22 and 30 had had five jobs.36 Less precise data suggest that many other workers would have had similar difficulties explaining why they did what they did. Many German miners, brought in by company recruiters, were so disappointed at what they found that they embarked on a life of constant job-changing. One young worker at 17 years of age left a Ruhr company to go to Holland; he evinced no sign of making a conscious choice of profession, simply hoping to see the ocean. He never made it, for he was arrested by the police as a tramp before he crossed the border; ultimately he ended up back in the mines.37 In Ruhr mining generally, a full 40 percent of the sons of miners left the mines; this does not mean they necessarily lacked a job choice but it suggests at the least the weakness of traditional paternal example.38 And if the evidence on aimlessness is most substantial in Germany, again because industry was newest there, the phenomenon was widespread. General unions in Britain were based in part on the fact that semi-skilled engineering workers, for example, had no sense of choosing a job and thus felt kinship with building laborers; there was in fact some drifting from one job to another, while in both cases laborers could rarely hope to rise into skilled categories.39 The growth of semi-and unskilled factory labor everywhere, associated with the more sophisticated new machines, denotes the rise of a group at least unaccustomed to the notion of selecting a job. Without pretending to assign a percentage to the group overall, we can agree with contemporary social scientists who noted that many workers seemed to do whatever came along.40
Three types of workers were most likely to be unable to assign a reason for their holding the job they did; for most members of each category the whole notion of explaining job choice was really foreign. The unskilled form the largest group. Their lack of choice was not new, but evidence available at the end of the nineteenth century allows some new insights into motivation; and in certain respects their situation had changed dramatically from that of the early industrial revolution. Within the unskilled category large numbers of older workers were more directly deprived of choice. And the growing number of female manufacturing workers probably fell within the 'choiceless' group, though for rather special reasons. Each of these categories deserves
some exploration before we return to the question of job choice more generally.
Let us begin again with an extreme, albeit a statistically significant one. Into France, Germany, and Belgium poured a host of foreign workers who were bent on making as little choice as possible.41 This is ironic, given the fact that in retrospect the decision to move to the city and to industry seems so monumental. And unskilled migrants now moved farther in search of work than skilled workers did, a railway-based reversal of early industrial trends.42 In the Daimler plant in Stuttgart, for example, a third of all day workers came from some distance, compared to only a fifth of the locksmiths.43 The movement of foreign workers simply heightened this general trend. We cannot of course pretend to fathom what prompted particular migrants to move, as compared to their contemporaries who remained in the village. Once arrived in the industrial labor force, however, what stands out is the sense that extensive geographic movement was cushioned by the lack of emotional abandonment of the past: work in industry was meant to fulfill traditional goals. Thus many unskilled workers, like the Polish miners employed in the Ruhr, were bent on earning a nest egg to buy land back home. Of course they had some desire to earn more money — hence a decision to go to mines in the Ruhr rather than stay in Silesia where wages were lower — but their acquisitive instinct was limited. They had no intention of remaining workers permanently, even though many did precisely that. They did not move into industry to better themselves — a number of observers noted that Flemish miners were devoid of ambition, in what was really an extreme of a typical pattern — but to restore something that had been lost or was imagined to have been lost. The purpose was to go back, to endure the present in order to restore a position back home. A few extra enjoyments resulting from relatively high monetary pay, such as the ability to buy cigarettes, did not lead to quick conversion to an acquisitive standard of living or to a really instrumental view of work.
The need to avoid choice and the desire to preserve a traditional pace of work was illustrated by frequent returns to the home setting. Among 4105 Italian workers in the Longwy steel industry in 1903, for example, there were 1618 departures for home; the next year, 1589 departures from among 4148 workers. Most of these workers deliberately left their families at home, because of the firm intention to return. Their intermittent work was the product of earnings higher than traditional expectations and their revulsion at factory labor — both instances of the fact that no choice had been made, in terms of
commitment to a new job, but that poverty alone had pushed these workers to a new setting, supplemented in some cases by a recruitment agency and rather formless expectations of easy earnings.44 And they were able regularly to send significant savings home, affirming their moderate personal expectations and their ties to the past; 500,000 francs were annually sent to Italy from the Villerupt post office alone.45
The situation of foreigners simply exaggerated the characteristics of native unskilled migrants. German shipbuilding, traditionally the province of local craftsmen, was supplemented during the 1890s by masses of unstable rural workers, many of whom regularly left to do agricultural work. The fact that this migration heightened, if massively, a traditional seasonal influx of workers from the Weser confirmed the minimal amount of choice involved in the process.46 Breton workers, sometimes recruited as strikebreakers, entered the Parisian transport and construction fields and the mines of the Nord. Some remained, though keeping contacts with the home village from which they continued to receive food (thus enabling them to accept low wages and avoid any sense of class consciousness). But where the nature of the work was really novel, as in the mines of the Nord as opposed to the casual labor of construction or hauling, upwards of three-quarters of the recruits left within four months.47
Of course there were casual laborers whose situation was less clear-cut. The German merchant marine was flooded by immigrants from many areas, and we cannot presume to determine the motivations involved at this point. Big cities, particularly in Britain, spawned a variety of unskilled workers from products of broken homes, the ill, and the retarded, and while these people had little choice of job they lacked the continuity with tradition that many unskilled migrants still tried to maintain.48 And other migrants, even though without skills, had newer motives in mind; British agricultural laborers, attuned to market incentives, moved to the docks and the mines quite frankly because of a desire for steadier or higher earnings and showed no disposition to leave.49 But, particularly in the factories where the need for conscious choice of job would seem most obvious, little career decision was really involved. There was strong motive to leave the village, little knowledge of what work was in store, and a great desire to use the work to restore a pre-crisis village life. Because the work was so strange few migrants could persist to achieve their original goal, but their durable adaptation to industrial labor — if they stayed in manufacturing at all - was a protracted process that had little to do
with original motives.
As we have seen, the massive influx of women into manufacturing was a phenomenon common to almost all the industrial countries. In Britain between 1891 and 1911 the number of women in manufacturing and transport work rose by 40 percent, while the increase of women in the overall population was barely half that rate (at 24 percent). Between 1895 and 1907 the increase of women in German manufacturing was 51 percent, with the bulk of the gain coming after 1900. By 1910 there were 33 percent more women workers than in 1905, and their expansion in manufacturing jobs was double the rate for men.50 This was a development of tremendous importance in working-class life, for it involved an unprecedented commitment to women's working outside the home. It is increasingly recognized that despite the horrors of female labor in the early factories - indeed perhaps because of them — most working-class women did not work outside the home during the initial stages of industrialization. Their earning activities were much more commonly devoted to servanthood, domestic manufacturing, or caring for lodgers. The breakthrough to factory and office work that occurred toward the turn of the century was thus genuinely novel; for the first time the majority of working-class women spent at least a portion of their lives working outside a domestic environment.51 Here, even more than with the long distance migration of many unskilled workers, we must ask about the choice involved.
Some women in the textile industry could undoubtedly have explained why they held the jobs they did. They could look back to a long tradition of work and they feared the boredom they would face if they were confined to the home; as a Lancashire spinner said, when asked why she did not devote herself to household and children: 'It 'ud give me the bloomin' 'ump.'52 Some women who had worked as servants had a definite sense of alternatives. Workers who came to Bristol confectionery from domestic service found 'more life' in the factory. German women who made a similar switch noted that, 'the foremen were not nearly so coarse as the gracious ladies.' Other German women who claimed that industrial jobs conveyed higher status than servanthood, in part because of some opportunity to rise to supervisor level, were making an even clearer career choice in the factories.53 But none of these constituted a normal pattern. The women in textiles who kept on after marriage were a rarity among working women; overall, only 10 percent of all married women worked in Britain, and many of these did so only because their husbands were dead or ailing. The
percentage was rising slowly, but in all the industrial countries it remained true that the typical working-class wife did not hold a job outside the home and that the typical female factory worker was an unmarried young woman.54 Nor did many women come over to industry from servanthood. The number of female servants declined (in France after 1895), stagnated (in Britain), or grew less rapidly than before (in Germany), but this resulted mainly from women not entering the occupation in the first place. It is safe to assume that they had some awareness of the alternatives before them, and chose factory work because they anticipated greater freedom and higher pay.55 But they were not, in most instances, actively choosing jobs.
For women still worked to supplement family income and usually on a transitory basis. Not a few came from the ranks of artisans and even professional people; in several German factories the social origins of women workers were higher than those of men, though in sweated industries the daughters of dockers and construction laborers predominated.56 Certainly in the former case, parents did not expect massive earnings from their daughters, allowing them to avoid the most arduous jobs; many young women thus preferred weaving to spinning, despite lower pay, because the work was less demanding.57 Even in the sweated trades of London most girls were working for pocket money and, perhaps, to escape their parents' domination during the day.58 None of this minimizes the significance of this change in the lives of young working-class women, or the fact that they made an important decision in going to work. And of course male opinion was normally hostile to women in industrial jobs. Ardent socialists, despite a theoretical commitment to women's rights (or perhaps in part because of it) could urge women workers to return to the home and take care of their children, thus fulfilling their proper role and allowing men's wages to go up.59 A French typographer expressed the same view in talking of his female colleagues: 'They're too impulsive. One day they're enthusiastic for our work, the next day they've changed their minds. The only way to resolve this problem would perhaps be by absorption. Each male typographer would marry a female typographer. That would be a solution.'60 This climate, combined with the newness of the industrial work experience and the tradition of temporary jobs before marriage explains the lack of job choice, but the fact remains that few women had much sense of selecting a career in industry.
Thus the departure from industry into marriage was a logical, completely expected pattern, for the job had been endurable in large measure because it was known to be temporary. The same mentality
prompted British girls, when asked about problems on their jobs, to talk more about tensions at home, with their parents.61 In Britain and elsewhere women changed jobs more frequently than men, and as with the male migrants this was both symptom and cause of a lack of commitment to a clear job choice. Even low levels of unionization among women, although owing much to male resistance, were related to this absence of professional commitment on the part of this rapidly growing segment of the labor force.
If, then, we focus on an industry with large numbers of women (aside from some traditional female industrial occupations such as cotton textiles — but even then perhaps only in Lancashire) or large numbers of unskilled migrants (like German mining, or construction labor generally) we have gone some considerable way to explaining, in admittedly gross terms, the large minority of workers who could not express a sense of choice in discussing their jobs. Both groups had made important decisions: to move a long distance, or to work outside the home, but where they found themselves in industry was almost irrelevant to this decision. In fact what they experienced on the job differed greatly from their expectations precisely because they had lacked the basis for a definite career choice. So many of them drifted. Or, unable to move readily - one wonders about the single women who were unable to marry — they lived what must have been confused, unhappy lives at work. But there is a final category of choiceless workers, less readily identified by contemporaries or in retrospect, that lacked even the luxury of making an initial decision to quit a traditional environment. Large numbers of older workers could have explained their position in the work-force only by the necessity of survival; their range of alternatives had narrowed to virtually nothing.
For many workers, old age, from an occupational standpoint, began in the mid-'thirties, certainly by forty. British railway companies, in a fairly typical example, rarely hired anyone over thirty. Unskilled workers could get jobs after they reached forty only with difficulty though they had to keep trying.62 British metal workers, claiming that work speed-ups caused premature aging, lamented that too many of their employers judged them 'too old at forty.'63 By no means all older workers found themselves in serious trouble. Some died before reaching even a young old age — deaths helped account for the low percentage of older workers in mining — and as usual in history it is difficult to count the dead against the living. Others flourished reasonably well in industry, a point to which we will return. In terms of our present concern, essentially choiceless older workers can be found in several situations. Many
were buried in the countryside, clinging to domestic manufacturing jobs or even entering such jobs afresh because they could find no other work. Ignored by all but some meticulous government investigators, they were assumed to be contented because they were incapable of protest and rural, but in fact they were often barely surviving and quite aware of their choiceless plight. We have noted already that departures of young workers plus accretions of the old left sectors like rural clothing manufacture, in Belgium, or ribbon manufacture, around Saint-Etienne, in the hands of workers over forty, who were normally underemployed. 64 This recourse had little value for workers in the big cities or for British workers generally; and the number of older workers increased dramatically with improvements in longevity and the increase in population growth through mid-century. Hence a variety of unskilled occupations developed or expanded to provide some casual employment to older urban workers, many displaced from decaying crafts. Taxi-driving was one, and the field rapidly became overpopulated. Parisian drivers included former valets, artisans, and mechanics, while in both Paris and London there were about 50 percent more drivers than cars by World War I.65 Displaced older workers also headed for the docks. Here too their lack of real choice in a final job was matched and fed by the casual, irregular nature of the work.66
Within the factories older workers were threatened by two related forces: the possible irrelevance of their initial skill and the pressure of work speed-up (both enhanced by diminished physical vigor). The latter provoked the loudest complaints around the turn of the century, particularly in Britain. Alfred Williams, in a locomotive factory, wrote vaguely of the employers' tendency to fire older workers. British railroad workers complained that senior workers were passed over in a desire to promote young hotshots, and special anger was directed against eye tests that could result in dismissal of older engineers. The cotton spinners' union criticized a tendency to fire older workers to make room for the promotion of piecers — the product of increased longevity as well as the speed-up drive.67 Piecework hit many older workers hard. In Parisian masonry it increased production enough that some older workers could be fired, while the stronger, young workers responsible for the increase simply enjoyed their higher earnings. The older workers who kept their jobs found their pay reduced, as employers insisted on tying wages to product. Similarly, older German workers complained that their earnings were below those of a rank beginner, again the fruit of the confrontation between piecework and diminished strength and skill.68 And there were more general
complaints that large companies were less loyal to older workers than small, constituting another ominous trend.69
These pressures were exceedingly important, and while not entirely new they were undoubtedly on the rise. Many older factory workers suffered declining earnings (though some family expenses might be down as well) and severe blows to their self-esteem. And there was some outright unemployment even among healthy workers. Yet in terms of the question of job choice it would be inaccurate to generalize too glibly about older factory workers. They were not dismissed en masse. Only 25 percent of the unemployed in a York study were over forty — a percentage lower than the size of this age group in the working population. Among British iron workers, unemployment did rise for men after their thirty-eighth year, but it was highest for those in their early twenties.70 In fact, as we shall see, British labor had developed protection for older workers that speed-up could dent but not overturn; the vigor of the complaints reflected expectations that age should be defended in factory jobs. Older workers were undoubtedly conscious of the need to watch their step, because of the difficulty of finding new work, but they were not under constant threat.
The situation was rather different among older Belgian, French and German factory workers. There is some evidence that older workers formed a larger percentage of the unemployed than in Britain; in France in 1906 they were twice as likely to be without a job.71 Certainly those who kept jobs tried to work steadily; it was noted that their production stayed even or rose a bit in the spring, whereas younger workers, distracted by the season, let it drop notably.72 They were less likely to change jobs: in one textile factory, where 23 percent of all workers between 22 and 30 held over five jobs, only 16 percent of the workers over 40 claimed the same.73 Above all, large numbers of older factory workers found themselves demoted to the ranks of the unskilled. This was of course endemic in mining, where workers were brought to surface jobs at age 40. But Belgian and German mine-owners exacerbated the problem by using older pit workers for hauling, whenever they could hire strong young replacements.74 Even more significantly, report after report on German metal and engineering factories suggested that the bulk of the unskilled labor force was composed of workers over thirty-six, who had lost their original skill rating and had given up all hope of improvement, and who formed an unusually stable element because their occupational survival was so tenuous. In France in 1911 29 percent of all male workers over 65
were listed as general laborers.75
There can be no pretense at measuring the overall size of this group of older workers or at comparing it, save impressionistically, with its British counterpart. But what was going on was fairly clear. Against the general backdrop of speed-up, workers who lacked strong union protection and who came into factories with artisanal skills, often learned in the village and initially useful, found themselves displaced by younger workers with more up-to-date techniques. Lower nutritional levels played a role as well, sapping the strength of many German, French or Belgian workers earlier than their British analogues.76
In sum, older workers were forced to change jobs without real choice, or more rarely to suffer outright unemployment, in two general settings. Declining crafts released a number of workers to the ranks of casual labor. Older factory workers might be pressed - and in some industries and areas regularly were — into the unskilled category, where, unlike many other unskilled workers, they could not even risk the luxury of switching jobs or taking time off. As with women and migrants, industries with unusually large numbers of older workers contained an unusually large number of workers incapable of explaining any choice, of job. Such would undoubtedly have been the case on the docks, had any pollster ventured there. Such was definitely the case in textiles in comparison with metallurgy, for a considerably larger proportion of the textile labor force was composed of older workers,77 some displaced elsewhere and drawn by the lighter demands of the industry and others demoted within the industry itself.
Describing the situation of the choiceless workers gets us only part of the way to an understanding of their relationship to their job, but because most of these workers were truly inarticulate it is difficult to penetrate much further. They rarely protested because they lacked the job expectations to form the appropriate basis; and it is no easy matter to judge whether lack of protest reflects satisfaction or the most profound alienation. The older workers just described, locked into mediocre jobs in German factories, would not have claimed choice in their work, but this does not necessarily indicate intense dissatisfaction. For they might have expected old age to be a time of deterioration - even today workers rate the early twenties as the peak period of life — and have been grateful for surviving as they did. Locksmiths in the Daimler plant commonly talked of staying at their job 'as long as I can' — a fairly clear reference to anticipated problems in the later years of work.78 Immigrant workers could derive pleasure from helping their families at home and relieve tension by changing jobs
and areas. Women, who were given some chance to speak about their jobs, manifested relatively little discontent, and in this case often talked of positive enjoyment at the social contacts possible in factory work; but this reflects the fact that, of all the 'choiceless' groups assessed, women had the greatest sense of alternatives in entering factory work and were more probably pulled rather than pushed into their jobs. But none of the groups expected much durable, intrinsic satisfaction in the job itself. If they were contented - and it will remain difficult to determine this basic point — it was because the job was n ot troublesome, in terms of expectations of workload, not because it brought pleasure and even more because of compensations peripheral to the work itself — social contacts, earnings, or sheer survival.
It would be possible, combining the two large groups thus far described, to paint an exceedingly bleak picture of workers' ability to choose a job, outside of the increasingly restrictive crafts. Frustrated at one end because of artisanal expectations, choiceless at the other, could factory workers feel they had a role in selecting their job? In fact, while both mentalities are exceedingly important, they do not describe the bulk of the factory population. A final venture into contemporary polling can introduce us to the mainstream of attitudes toward job selection.
The Daimler automobile plant near Stuttgart drew most of its workers from nearby towns and villages (again, only among the unskilled did significant numbers travel long distances); 44 percent of its workers were from villages under 2000, though among the top skilled workers (the locksmiths) the urban element was much larger. The average worker was 32 years of age and had been with the company four years; the skilled element was noticeably younger than the average, at twenty-nine years, but it had the same longevity. Artisanal backgrounds loomed large. This was, in sum, not a completely atypical factory setting, in terms of the elements we have already described, and though it had a greater home town atmosphere than the big factory cities of the north this might merely have heightened the frustration at factory life. Indeed some skilled workers did express a desire for the kind of training that would allow them to enter an independent trade, while admitting that they lacked the money they would need for this. But the vast majority of all workers — and particularly of the skilled group — said that they chose their profession according to their own free wish or the recommendations of their parents; the largest single response was that the profession was enjoyable. In contrast to the textile factory cited earlier, most of these
workers had always been in their current profession and most said they intended to stay in it.79
Even among relatively new industries in Germany, there was thus considerable diversity in the willingness of workers to express job choice. If we cast our net wider, admitting the lack of precise polling data, to more settled industrial countries the sense of diversity can only increase. Two problems, then: to account for the reasons workers might have for believing they had chosen their jobs, despite the considerable potential for randomness or frustration, and to provide greater precision on the differences in choice within the working class.
To begin with, it is easy to exaggerate the frustration element. There is no doubt that far more German workers wanted to become artisans than were able to do so and could thus tell an investigator that their factory job was not their first choice. But three qualifications to this pattern, apart from the obvious fact that the dilemma was greater in Germany, as a newly-industrial country with a rapidly growing labor force, than in Britain or probably even France. First, we must not exaggerate the universality of acceptance of artisanal life. Apprenticeship could be exploitative at worst, dull and confined at best. Many were glad to escape it. One German metal worker was trained by his father, a master baker, from the age of ten; he hated the life. At 16 he began to wander, taking various unskilled jobs and often begging; finally he gained a permanent factory job at 28.80 Second, workers who expressed a sense of disappointment at not having followed their first choice may have been developing a kind of ambivalent culture that has taken firm root in the working class. Recent surveys81 of the English working class suggest the ability to express career aspirations for selves or children that are almost explicitly admitted as unrealistic. German workers at the turn of the century could similarly talk of their desire to be a bureaucrat or an independent master and then note that they had no real control over their lives, that they would go 'where the wind blows us.'82 The larger aspirations were not insignificant, but they did not preclude a sense of positive choice, even of quiet satisfaction, in the job that had been acquired. And finally, in many factory industries the artisan mentality, as we can understand its survival, could find considerable expression. There was the need to grit one's teeth and accept a large workplace and considerable direction from above; some former artisans and peasants would always find this distasteful. But if this could be done, the criteria for job choice did not have to undergo total change.
There was, first of all, a widespread program of training. Formal
apprenticeship was under increasing attack and promotions of the unskilled posed a growing problem in many industries, particularly engineering and shipbuilding, and this trend must not be neglected.83 But even in 1914 a considerable majority of all manufacturing workers were rated, and doubtless would have rated themselves, as skilled. The sense of choice already discussed in the Daimler plant was obviously related to the fact that skilled workers outnumbered unskilled and semi-skilled by almost two to one. British engineering, hard pressed by new methods, had a labor force that was 60 percent skilled by 1914 (the remainder evenly divided between unskilled and semi-skilled). And in many areas threat to skills in one company might be compensated by the development of new demands elsewhere; French Lorraine, for example, cried out for skilled metal workers throughout the pre-war years.84 The threat to skills was real. It could be projected for the future even when not yet operative. Yet it was still possible for many workers to choose a factory job confident that it would involv e training and skill. And we should not minimize the inventiveness of individual workers in protecting this sense of training, even when union efforts at defending apprenticeship programs failed. Many German machine workers, for example, changed jobs explicitly to learn more; turners wanted experience in building steam engines, saying that this would not only increase their earning power but improve their satisfaction with their careers.85
After training came promotion possibilities. Considerable attention has been given to the traditional mobility within the artisanry, from apprentice to journeyman to master, and how this was increasingly blocked in the early stages of industrialization. American investigators have devoted great effort to the study of more modern kinds of mobility, defined occupationally in terms of movement from one major job category to another, as from unskilled to skilled.86 But what has been missed is a process somewhat in-between, that could be a normal life experience for a given factory worker, sometimes susceptible of being passed on to children, and quite possibly a very sensible pattern for workers who remembered the artisanal process which was now closed to them. What follows does not, of course, involve the nominal tracing of individuals that is essential to establish mobility definitely, and we will return to the problem of mobility more generally in a later section. For now, what can be established is that many workers could choose a factory job because it provided a fairly well-organized ladder of promotion covering a considerable portion of one's working life. Workers at Krupp, predominantly from artisanal backgrounds in the
1860s, saw a clear ladder of advancement established from one skill level to the next. And their descendants could rise higher still; only about a third of the children of second-generation unskilled were in the same category, whereas a full half were skilled and the remainder were in the company bureaucracy. And while this does not account for the workers who left the company, job stability was sufficient to give the sample significance. Metal-working and metallurgy everywhere involved advancement after the training period, even if, as with traditional artisans, this sometimes required explicit defense. A similar pattern was found at Daimler, where all the children of skilled workers old enough to hold jobs had risen higher than their fathers, either in the company or outside.87 Carmaux metallurgists struck to protect the advancement of rollers by seniority. British smelters complained — successfully — that the customary promotion of the oldest changewheelers to furnace work had been ignored by one company.88 This kind of training and promotion system in metal work could produce tensions quite similar to those discernible among artisans. Assistants in British iron manufacture (and in cotton) were reluctant to agitate lest this damage their chances for promotion by seniority; their concern was directed not only at employers but also at the skilled workers who supervised them, many of them their own fathers, and who therefore were free to dominate the union. Sons of Belgian metallurgists were reported avoiding their fathers' profession in favor of taking training as turners, where they could earn money faster, a job-choice dilemma that again tends to confirm the assimilability of factory and artisanal skills.89
It is obviously impossible to suggest how many workers chose an industrial job with promotion in mind, or how many benefited from it, aside from citing the general figures on skill levels. And it must be remembered that only certain workers could hope to get on the ladder at all. Just as construction laborers were doomed to unskilled work, so railway maintenance men were apart from the careful seniority system used for the operating crews.90 And not all of the major industries had clear systems at all, to compare with those in many kinds of metal work and on the railroads. But British and French mining had a definite ladder, from assistant or boy through hauler to miner, with the latter graded at five levels or more. The German system here was more confused, because of massive new entries of workers, except for the possibility of rising to master miner at the top; no matter at what age they were hired most workers moved after ten years as a hauler to an apprentice miner, and then on to miner when they were capable of
digging coal on their own — a ladder that may not have given much sense of movement, but which avoided complete stagnation.91 Textiles allowed movement from piecer to spinner or apprentice to weaver, and again there is evidence of a firm sense of movement within a given factory; workers in a rug factory in Neuville, in the Nord, struck against the hiring of an adult rug weaver who was not in the weaving 'corporation,' noting that this would prevent apprentices from rising. They ultimately beat up the worker involved, which seemed to settle the matter. Individual workers might choose jobs explicitly for the opportunity to rise. Contrasting his trade with coal mining, a German metallurgist proclaimed: 'If I work hard and remain with the company I can be foreman and perhaps even later even supervisor.'92 Many kinds of industrial jobs, then, could provide not only training but a sense of subsequent advancement, which in certain instances — railroads being the clearest case — gave seniority advantages and possibilities for supervision of assistants even late in the working career.
Finally, as has been obvious from the discussion of promotion itself, factories would quickly develop systems of favoring the children of existing workers, providing another kind of advantage that artisans sought. This is one of the reasons that a substantial minority of factory workers would explain their jobs in terms of parental choice; and there is no question that parents actively sought the possibility of assuring work for their children. In many Belgian metal factories, the children of existing workers were almost the only new workers hired. Not only metal workers but also tram and railroad workers often agitated for confirmation of the rights of children over outsiders, and a similar system was clearly at work in many textile centers.9 3 In Arrnentières linen weaving 78 percent of all workers were related to another textile worker in the city in 1901, 42 percent in the same factory; few children (3 percent) went into other industries. Where fathers had a son at work, 70 percent of the sons were weavers, most of them having started as their fathers' assistants. Parental guidance had its ambiguities for both parties. In an isolated textile area, and even more in the mines, parental example might operate only because there was no other work ready to hand, and we cannot be sure that it provided many workers with an active sense of job choice. In the Rhondda valley, 95 percent of all workers depended on the mines. Some children, hearing their parents complain about their labor, wanted an alternative but could find none. Others, who also had no sense of choosing among jobs, were nevertheless drawn to the mines by the possibility of earning relatively good wages early and by the mystique of work, the challenge to
manhood, that they developed as boys.94 Lacking direct inquiries into miners' choice, it is impossible to sort those who felt a positive commitment from those who could have explained their job only by the absence of anything else. But the probability is that the group who could explain why they were in the mines increased with time. This is surely one reason that a growing percentage of sons followed their fathers into the Ruhr mines after 1900 despite an earlier tradition of seeking other work and the availability of factory jobs in the general area.95 After the World War, it would also be a factor in the reluctance of miners' families to turn to other work even as the mines declined.
Overall, the ability to choose a job or at least explain why one had a particular job increased with the maturation of industry. The sense of frustrated choice did not disappear, but it is no coincidence that around 1900 it was far stronger in Germany than in Britain. Many workers, particularly with craft backgrounds, came to the cities with a desire to reproduce the best features of artisanal life, and without question not all of these could be found in the factories. Independence, in the artisanal sense, was impossible; it could only be ironically echoed by frequent job-changing. Other elements of artisanal job choice could be reproduced, but it took some time either to realize or to develop this. Promotion systems, particularly ones that would protect older workers, were even by 1914 less clearly established in Germany than in Britain. But as workers settled down they could develop a system of job choice which included parental guidance and example, a sense of training and some hope for a lifetime career.96 Not all workers settled in this way, of course; and those who did undoubtedly narrowed their horizons somewhat. But within this framework many industrial workers could claim some understanding of why they were what they were.
Because many workers did seek to choose a job, but with somewhat varied criteria and important differences in their ability to make a selection, certain industries tended to attract distinctive types of workers. This process would be most apparent in a country like Germany, which was rapidly expanding its manufacturing labor force, but its results were still apparent in England, because an important minority of workers did move from one industry to another and because parental example could perpetuate certain attitudes and physical characteristics. Information is inadequate to cover the whole industrial roster, but a few key examples can illustrate how the process of job choice, blending with the technical requirements of various industries, produced a variegated working class.
Railroad service was consciously selected by a large number of
workers — as with many artisan jobs, its popularity greatly exceeded the number of jobs it could provide. In France there were 30,000 applicants for approximately 1300 vacancies each year, and these were carefully screened to select the most 'stable' types. As noted, pension systems were general as well, attracting workers with foresight for their old age. Many families sent several members into railroad work, which encouraged pride in the calling. It is not far-fetched to suggest that many applicants were rather stolid types in the first place, for the big attraction of railroad work was the steadiness and security of work, along perhaps with fringe benefits such as uniforms and, in Belgium and Germany, the prestige of being in state service. Promotions played a role, as we have noted, attracting workers with foresight for their old age ; pension systems were general as well. High pay might come at the end of a cureer, once one became an engineer, but it was not an obvious draw. Railroad work, and to a lesser extent employment on tram lines, where job tenure was also a realistic goal, tended thus to recruit a cautious, security-minded work-force, and in so far as the work was passed from father to son some of the same qualities were transmitted as well.97
Metal work also drew workers who felt they had a job choice, but their interests were somewhat different. Early high pay was more important, concern for the long run rather less so; hence the average age of entry was low, compared to metallurgy or even mining, and young workers changed jobs so often. Cliques around particular skills divided the category still further, for if metal workers did not have the obvious trappings of prestige, recognizable to the larger society, that railroad workers might boast, they had a vigorous sense of place within their own community. They distinguished themselves by residence — the better-paid often shunning company housing to avoid bad associations — and by conversational groups in the factory. But status concerns aside, this was a more flamboyant work-force than the railroads employed, proud of their skills and their physical strength, touchier in their relations on the job.98
Textiles provide a different picture still. There were good reasons to choose textile work, especially in places like Lancashire where parental example was obvious. But the percentage of textile workers who sensed a job choice was lower than in metallurgy. There were more women, more elderly, and skill levels were not as high even for young males. Textiles thus drew a labor force that was less literate than that in the crafts or metallurgy, and above all one that was physically weaker. In Germany only 29 percent of the textile workers did military service, most of the remainder excused because of physical ailments. Textile
workers were thus more likely to be disappointed by a failure to succeed in initial job choices or incapable of articulating a conscious choice at all. Even in Lancashire the physical health of the cotton workers was inferior to the working-class norm, if only through inherited characteristics exacerbated by relatively poor care for children and a tradition of relatively early child labor."
Obviously, distinctions of this sort are extremely general; they do. not predict the characteristics of any given worker. But the tendency for certain kinds of workers to gravitate to certain kinds of work deserves serious attention, for it helped shape the nature of each particular work-force. The characteristics involved expectations and the very ability to account for one's presence on a job, but also, in an age of uncertain nutrition and medical care, important physical traits as well. Differences might be enhanced by the actual work experience; for example, the reasons the artisans and metal workers chose their jobs were quite similar, but the subsequent behavior of the two groups divided by the organization of work imposed on the metal workers. But the initial job choice would continue to color the work experience itself, affecting job stability, protest, even family patterns to a degree. By the same token differences in job choice, among factory industries as well as between artisans and the unskilled, constituted serious divisions within the working class.
For the simple fact was that workers could readily perceive those of their workmates who were on the job for different reasons than they were. In the mines workers who were drawn to the peculiar excitement of mine work or following their parents' lead encountered unskilled newcomers whose presence had nothing to do with the work itself. Ethnic hostilities owed much to this kind of distinction; the Walloon miners who railed against 'Flemish cowherds' perceived the newcomers' strange motivations as well as their language and religiosity.100 Tension was equally obvious in the Ruhr mines. Silesian newcomers thought that more experienced local workers were odd, if not reprehensible, because they seemed to be seeking something more than a daily grind, while the locals ridiculed the Silesians for their willingness to drag through every day so long as they were able to earn little treats like cigarettes.101 Neither judgement was fully accurate; Silesian workers, for example, might drag through many days but they were more likely to quit their jobs frequently. And judgements of this sort reflected more than differences in job choice. But what was sought in a job would affect ongoing experiences, so differences had lasting impact.
In stressing the range of job choice available we are not trying to
suggest some illusory degree of freedom. Direct evidence o>f opinions comes from only a few cases in Germany, itself not the most typical mature industrial setting by the turn of the century. Opinion and reality might differ; what workers told a bourgeois investigator might, whether deliberately or not, be intended to appeal to his sense of appropriate rationality, not to what really happened; though even the calculation of what was an acceptable reason for holding a job has considerable interest. After grappling with the workers who admitted they could not articulate on this subject, one must be wary of accepting the more communicative workers at face value. And many of these workers did not explain their job in terms of a choice among alternatives. Some who did weigh alternatives were doomed to disappointment, for the risk was great for the worker who thought beyond his parents' station. And even those who did think in terms of alternatives — the boys who were placed as printers rather than carpenters or the young men who became turners, in an engineering plant, instead of ovenmen in a smelting factory — operated under severe constrictions. Apart from the limitations on any human choice, workers had to select a career with obvious disadvantages in placement contacts, interregional mobility, funds available for training, and in many instances physical stamina.
Yet the sense of choice was by no means idle. Even a decision to enter industry could contrast favorably with traditional pursuits, as in the case of many women; or it could be taken amid the compulsions that induced a lonely migration. Choice of specific job could frustrate. It could fulfill a parent's dream. It could lead to an anticipation of satisfaction, the result depending on individual personality but also some broad categories of background and industrial setting. The reasons for taking a job were strong enough to distort a labor market, for within a range of economic compulsion — the need to survive — workers were not simple economic men. The desire to remain artisans retarded the formation of a large, skilled factory labor force in Germany or in the newer industrial areas of France. It kept printing skills alive that were no longer technically necessary. Related motivations made railroad recruitment so easy that wages stayed low despite a growing work load.
For on balance the criteria of workers who could explain their choices were rather conservative. We must not take the purely artisanal yearnings too seriously. Many workers had to choose the factories and could do so with a sense of positive commitment. But whether from artisanal background, as was so often the case in Germany, or the
product of several generations of factory experience in which independent criteria could be established, workers were rarely in a position to strike out too far. The increased ability to explain why one had a particular job, which we have asserted for the more mature industrial period, was not the fruit of an obvious modernization of working-class outlook. It was not the expression of great individual venturesomeness or the desire to maximize individual opportunity.102 Rather it reflected a desire to regain some job values that had been threatened during the earlier stages of industrialization.
This appears most obviously in the role taken by parents. Just as artisans continued to guide their sons, so factory workers could begin to think in terms of placing their boys. Correspondingly the workers most likely to lack specific job commitment were those in which parental referents were missing: the migrants, the older workers displaced from their chosen job, and women, for whom parents had not yet developed occupational (as opposed to marital) criteria. The working-class family was an economic unit still, and the activity of parents not only in advising but in placing their children followed from this.103
Closely related to parental guidance were other criteria expressed in job choice: social status, at least within a working-class community, and a hierarchy through which some advancement was conceivable, even normal. Regularity of work was an important factor, though some kinds of workers would stress it more than others; artisans, for example, were less concerned than railroad workers. Provision for employment in old age might have been a logical consideration for security-conscious workers, but traditional guidelines were shakier here and the expectation of survival did not keep pace with the fact. Workers developed a concern for what would happen in their later years after some time on the job, more than in their initial decisions.
But this in a way merely confirms the desire to seek in a job many of the satisfactions traditionally associated with successful work: status, parental approval, and — as the Daimler workers noted so often — some intrinsic pleasure in the work itself. This was not, in so far as we can determine, an instrumental view of work. The view that a job should be taken not for its own sake but for extrinsic benefits was most common, in however inchoate a form, among new, unskilled workers, who saw their work as a means of returning to the countryside or escaping parents/finding a mate. Of course wages were part of the satisfactions that articulate workers said they sought in taking a job. And the absence of explicit mention of wage levels as a reason for job choice in
the German polling materials - it is virtually complete, despite an appropriate spot in the questionnaire — may relate to the recency of German industrialization, which tied the workers to an unusually traditional set of justifications. We have seen important signs of a tension between the parentally-approved reasons for taking a job and a youthful desire to earn money quickly. This was surely one reason that certain skilled trades, such as construction work in London, had constantly to be replenished by small-town trainees. Complaints by French artisans and metallurgical workers that the younger generation pursued the quick franc more directly express the potential clash among job criteria, as does the significant variation in the percentage of young people in the prosperous trades and industries. But the wage-based choice was nowhere yet predominant. Even where the absence of job alternatives was deplored, as among some Welsh miners, few young workers were sufficiently venturesome to seek their fortunes elsewhere. This was still the product of unusual necessity, as with the foreign migrants. Correspondingly the pecking order of occupations, for big-city workers who had the clearest range of alternatives, was not completely correlated with earnings. Jobs that offered other satisfactions, such as many crafts and railroad service, could rate above those with much higher average wages. High wages might in fact have to be offered precisely because the job was unpopular according to the general criteria workers used, and even then they might not suffice to eliminate a serious labour shortage.
Hence this stage of industrialization can be associated most clearly with a widening of a sense of job choice according to sensible but rather conservative criteria. This pattern was threatened less by youthful rebellions — which were by no means necessarily new -— than by disruptions of skill levels within the factories. The rapid influx of semi-skilled workers into engineering, metal work, and even crafts such as printing raised a host of problems about the future course of job choice. Could the semi-skilled themselves develop a sense of selecting one job over another, particularly given the hostility of those more experienced, skilled workers who might have served as logical models? Would the threat to established skills be sufficient to force even the most settled sector of the labor force to reconsider its reasons for selecting a manufacturing job? These problems were not yet predominant by 1914, but they were clearly visible and their significance was all the greater for the challenge they posed to the carefully-reconstructed framework within which most manufacturing workers had learned to operate in selecting a job.
And this raises the final question: if most workers by 1914 had not yet explicitly switched to a new system of job choice or to a belief that there was no reason for one job as opposed to another, how would their criteria coincide with their actual work experience? The relationship was frankly complicated. There was almost surely à correlation between those workers who could express reasons for job choice and those who felt satisfaction with their job. German metalworkers, for example, were much happier with their work than their colleagues in textiles, just as they more commonly believed they had chosen their jobs.104 The same would surely have applied to artisans as opposed to the unskilled. But there was a massive gap between the figures for job choice and those for job satisfaction, in both metals and textiles. It would be ridiculous to play with precise statistics, and the biases of the pollsters — conservative/social-scientific in the one case, socialist in the other — explain part of the gap. But the gap had reality in the workers' experience as well.
For the very fact that many workers had developed or retained criteria for choosing a job gave them bases for protest when the job did not turn out as expected. Their protest could relate to the job itself, in an effort tp convert it into a more satisfactory experience, or it could assume more instrumental lines, when workers essentially gave up on their initial expectations and decided that their only hope was to pry more earnings out of an unpleasant situation. On the whole, therefore, a relationship developed between workers capable of job choice, and the industries in which they were most concentrated, and rates of protest.105 In this sense, as in its relation to the work experience itself, the growing ability to decide on a job was a vital, if complicated, part of the maturation of the working class.
Notes
1. In Belgium it became virtually impossible to find apprentices in domestic industries such as clothing, for workers rarely urged their children to continue in the profession. Ministère de l'industrie et du travail, Les Industries à domicile (Brussels, 1908), IX, 89. With an aging labor force, natural attrition tended to reduce the number of workers. Friedrich Behr, Die Wirkung der fortschreitenden Technik auf die Schuhindustrie (Leipzig, 1909).
2. On the contrast between the irregularity of agricultural work and the relative stability of jobs in industry, Fritz Darmstàdter, Die Lage der Arbeiter im Kalisatzbergbau (Munich, 1911), passim.
3. In Germany former agricultural workers complained that farmer-employers insisted on being called Herr, abandoning formerly friendly behavior at joint meals. C. Moszeck, éd., Aus der Gedankenwelt einer Arbeitsfrau (Berlin, 19Q9), 22.
4. Bruno H. Bûrgel, Vont Arbeiter zum Astronomer (Beilin, 1927).
5. Ministère du travail et de la prévoyance sociale: office du travail, Enquête sur le travails à domicile dans l'industrie de la chaussure (Paris, 1914).
6. Bernhard Adeling, Sein und Werden (Offenbach, 1952).
7. Robert Tressell, The Ragged-Trousered Philanthropists (London, 1955), 471.
8. Le'on de Seilhac, Syndicats ouvriers, fédérations, Bourses du travail (Paris, 1902), 57.
9. A. E. Musson, The Typographical Association (London, 1954), 231.
10. Ibid., 253.
11. Commission syndicale du parti ouvrier et des syndicats indépendants, Rapport présenté au XlVe Congrès syndical extraordinaire du 28 Avril 1912 (Brussels, 1912), 83 ff.
12. Musson, Typographical, 258; Archives départmentales du Rhône, Series M, General strike by Lyons dyers, 1903.
13. Ministère de l'industrie et du travail, Industries, IX, 89.
14. B. Seebohm Rowntree, Land and Labour: Lessons from Belgium (London, 1911), 85 ff.
15. Ministère du commerce; office du travail, Rapport sur l'apprentissage dans l'imprimerie (Paris, 1902), lxviii.
16. Charles Booth, Life and Labour of the People in London (London, 1895), VI, passim.
17. Amedée Dunois, 'Le Lockout de la maçonnerie,' Pages libres (1908), 52.
18. A. Sartorius von Walternhausen, Deutsche Wirtschaftjgeschichte 1815-1914 (Jena 1923); Raymond Joran, L'Organisation syndicale dans l'industrie des bâtiments (Paris, 1914), 94 ff.; Max Morgenstern, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft (Leipzig, 1912), passim; P. Cousteix, 'Le Mouvement ouvrier limousin de 1870 à 1939,' L'Actualité de l'histoire (1957), 74 ff.; Fanny Imle, Die Tarifvertràge zwischen Arbeitgebern und Arbeitnehmern in Deutschland (Jena, 1907), passim.
19. Ministère du travail, Chaussure, 105, 307.
20. Walter Abelsdorff, Beitrage zur Sozialstatistik der deutschen Buchdrucker (Tubingen, 1900). In 1907 40% of the population of Germany's big cities had been born there. Wolfgang Kôllman, 'Industrialisierung, Binnenwanderung, und "Soziale Frage" ', Vier-teljahrschrift fur Sozial-und Wirtschaftsgeschichte (1959), 53; Booth, Life, X, passim.
21. Hans Hinke, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiter im Btichdrucke-rgewerbe (Berlin, 1910), 35 ff.
22. Grenoble et sa région, 1900-1925 (Grenoble, 1925), 464 ff.
23. Ministère du Commerce, office du travail, Rapport sur l'apprentissage dans les industries de l'ammeublement (Paris, 1905), 525,531 ff., 634.
24. Abelsdorff, Beitrdge.
25. Carl Severing, Mein Lebensweg (Berlin, 1950), I, 13 ff. Even unskilled workers could briefly harbor craft aspirations. An East German laborer described his desire to be a locksmith, though this was completely beyond any realistic attainment. After a stint as an agricultural worker he ended in construction labor, hating his job at every stage. Luth Franz, Aus der Jugendzeit eines Tageslohners (Berlin, n.d.), 19.
26. Paul de Rousiers, The Labour Question in Britain (London, 1898), 336 ff. In Germany many unskilled workers were former shoemakers, bakers and the like who felt their status loss heavily. Heinrich Reichelt, Die Arbeitsverhàltnisse in einem Berliner Grossbetrieb der Maschinen-industrie (Berlin, 1906). For an individual case in Germany see Wendel Holek, Lebensgang eines deutsch-tschechischen Handarbeiters (Jena, 1909).
27. Paul Gohre, Drei Monate Fabrikarbeiter (Leipzig, 1913), passim.
28. Maurice Kahn, 'Les Evénements de Limoges,' Pages libres (1905), 9-10.
29. H. A. Clegg et al., A History of British Trade Unionism since 1889 (Oxford, 1964), I, 430; Sidney Pollard, A History of Labour in Sheffield (Liverpool, 1959), 239 ff.; A. L. Levine, Industrial Retardation in Britain (London, 1967), 477.
30. Clemens Heiss, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiter in der Berliner Feinmechanik (Leipzig, 1910), 111.
31. R. J., 'Erlebnisse eines Metalldrehers,' Thunen-Archiv (1909), 218 ff.
32. Pollard, Sheffield, 211 ; Darmstâdter, Lage, passim.
33. Archives de la ville de Bruxelles 197—2, report on cabinet-makers' strike, 1912.
34. Marie Bernays, 'Berufswahl und Berufsschicksal des modernen Industriearbeiters,' Archiv fur Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik (1912), 123 ff.
35. Max Morgenstern, Auslese und Anpassung der industrieller Arbeiterschaft betrachtet bei den Offenbacher Lederarbeitern (Freiburg i. Br., 1911); Elise Hermann, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Wollhutsindustrie (Munich, 1912).
36. Marie Bernays, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft der geschlosene Grossindustrie (Leipzig, 1910). German textile employers correspondingly could not count on children 'naturally' entering the industry: Schulz-Gaevernitz, The Cotton Trade in England and on the Continent (London, 1895).
37. Adolf Levenstein, Aus der Tiefe, Arbeiterbriefe (Berlin, 1905).
38. Max Metzner, Die soziale Fursorge im Bergbau (Jena, 1911). Part of this stemmed also from restrictions on child labor in the mines; some of the 40% may have returned later.
39. E. J. Hobsbawm, 'General Labour Unions in Britain, 1889-1914,' Economic History Review (1949), 138. A building laborer by age 24 could expect to remain a laborer all his life. Booth, Life, VI.
40. Pollard, Sheffield, 230 ff.; Heinrich Herkner, Problème der Arbeiterpsychologie (Leipzig, 1912).
41. In France in 1911 14% of all transport laborers, 13% of all construction laborers, 9% of miners, and 5% of metal and woodworkers were foreign. Georges Mauco, Les Etrangers en France (Paris, 1932), 49.
42. On early industrial patterns, Arthur Redford, Labour Migration in England (London, 1926); John Modell, 'The Peopling of a Working-Class Ward: Reading, Pennsylvania, 1850', Journal of Social History (1971), 71-96.
43. Fritz Schuman, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Automobilindustrie (Leipzig, 1911). There were, to be sure, some isolated factories in which the unskilled were recruited locally, living at home and trying to preserve as much as possible of their traditional peasant life; but this was now uncommon in manufacturing. The main exceptions occurred in Belgium, where the extensive commuting network allowed many industrial workers to spend evening or weekends by their customary patch of earth. H. Demain, Migrations ouvrières à travers la Belgique (Louvain, 1919), 70 and passim. For more limited German examples: in one Magdeburg factory in 1898, 97% of all workers lived in their native villages, up to 23 kilometers away from the job. Hermann Beck, Lohn- und Arbeitersverhàltnisse in der deutschen Maschinenindustrie (Dresden, 1902). In Offenbach 78% of the leather workers were from the area, almost 50% of them rural and continuing to live in the countryside: Morgenstern, Lederarbeiter, 24 ff.
45. Léon de Seilhac, 'Les Grèves du bassin de Longwy,' Musée social (1906), 390 ff.
46. Josef Neumann, Die deutsche Schiffbauer (Leipzig, 191 0).
47. de Peyerimhoff, 'Les Charbonnages français,' Musée social (1913), 148; H. Leduc, 'A Villeneuve-Saint-Georges,' Voix ouvrière (1910), 658 ff.;AftMéejocw/(1908), 291.
48. E. Fitzer, Die wirtschaftliche und technische Entwzcklung der Seeschiffsfahrt (Leipzig, 1902). A study of the unemployed in York noted that over a tenth were locals under 19 years of age, who had entered a blind alley job, serving for example as delivery boy, and lacked the strength or wit to seek alternatives once their exploitable boyhood was over. B. Seebohm Rowntree and Bruce Lasker, Unemployment; A Social Study (London, 1911) 49.
49. Royal Commission on L&boxxx,Minutes of the Evidence, Group 'B' (Transport by Water and Transport by Land (London, 1892, C 6708), I, 392.
50. Abstract of Labour Statistics (London, 1915, Cd. 7733), 293—319; Franz Hitze, Geburtenruckgang und Sozialreform
(Mônchen-Gladbach, 1917); Arthur Feiler, Die Konjunktur-
Periode 1907-1913 in Deutschland (Jena, 1914). 51. 77% of all unmarried women over 15 were employed in Britain
by 1911: Peter N. Stearns, 'Working-Class Women in Britain
1890-1914,' in M. Vicinus, éd., Suffer and Be Still (Bloomington
"1972), 110. 52 Mrs. J.R. MacDonald et al., Wage Earning Mothers (London, n.d.),
14.
53. Royal Commission on Labour, The Employment of Women (London, 1893, C. 6894), 36; Heinrich Herkner, Problème der Arbeiterpsychologie (Leipzieg, 1912); Bernays, Auslese, 171.
54. Steams, 'Women;' Hitze, Geburtenruckgang, passim. In Germany the massive increase in women working in industry was accompanied by an- actual decline in the percentage of married women in the manufacturing labor force, from 6% to 5%.
55. Theresa McBride, Rural Tradition and the Process of Modernization: Domestic Servants in Nineteenth-Century France (Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Rutgers University, 1973) demonstrates that a strict economic calculation before the late nineteenth century would have sent women into servanthood, where earning possibilities were greater than in the factories; but after the 1870s the balance shifted. Former German servants reported a similar finding by 1900.
56. Booth, Life, passim; Hermann, Auslese.
57. F. Hecht et al., Die Stôrungen in deutschen Wirtschaftsleben (Leipzig, 1903), II, 77 ff. and passim.
58. Stearns, 'Women,' passim.
59. Léon de Seilhac, Les Mariniers du Nord et leur dernière grève (Paris, 1905), 151.
60. Archives départmentales du Nord M621/31; see also A. and Z., 'Pour la Réduction des heures du travail,' La Revue socialiste (1906), 131 ; Fédération française des travailleurs du livre, Dixième Congrès national (Paris, 1910), 53.
61. Royal Commission on Labour, Women, passim.
62. W. T. Stephenson, 'The Railway Conciliation Scheme, 1907,' The Economie Journal (1911), 505; Rowntree and Lasker, Unemployment, passim.
63. Friendly Society of Iron Moulders, Monthly Journal, 1907.
64. Ministère de l'industrie et du travail, Industries, IX, passim; Pierre Clerget, Les Industries de la Soie en France (Paris, 1925).
65. Public Record Office HO 55943, report of 1890; L. Bonneff and M. Bonneff, 'La Grève des taxi-autos,' La Grande Revue (1912), 353 ff.
66. Edward G. Howarth and Mona Wilson, West Ham (London, 1907).
67. J. E. Williams. The Derbyshire Miner (London, 1962), 304; Amalgamated Society of Railway Servants, The Railwaymen's Charter (London, 1907), 8—17; General Railway Union, Executive Council Meetings (1905), 111; S. J. Chapman, 'Some Policies of
the Cotton Spinners' Trade Unions,' The Economic Journal (1900), 467.
68. J. Lapierre, 'Les Grèves des platrières du bassin de Paris,' La Vie ouvrière (1912), 129; Cari Fischer, Denkwùrdigkeiten und Errinerungen eines Arbeiters (Leipzig, 1904); A. Picart, 'La Grève de la maçonnerie parisienne,' Musée social (1909), 381.
69. Dora Lande, 'Arbeits-und Lohnverhàltnisse in der Berliner Maschinenindustrie zu Beginn des 20. Jahrhunderts (Leipzig, 1910).
70. Rowntree and Lasker, Unemployment; Friendly Society of Iron-founders, Investigation into the Mortality, Sickness and Unemployment Experienced among Members (London, 1913).
71. Louis Variez, Recensement des chômeurs gantois (Glient, n.d.).
72. Ernst Bernhard, 'Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft,' Jahrbuch fur Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung, und Volkswirtschaft im Deutschen Reich (1911), 1426. It may be more than a random contrast to note that many older skilled British workers took a day or two off during the week to rest: Arthur L. Bowley and A.R. Burnett-Hurst, Livelihood and Poverty (London, 1915), 111.
73. Bernays, Auslese.
1 A. L'Ouvrier mineur (1907), 17; N. Dethier, Centrale syndicale des travailleurs des mines de la Belgique (Brussels, 1950), 127.
75. Bernhard, 'Auslese,' 1405.
76. On nutrition levels, a detailed and reasonably exact comparison is provided by the several studies of the British Board of Trade: Report on an Enquiry into Working Class Rents, Housing and Retail Prices . . . in the Principal Industrial Towns of Belgium (London, 1910, Cd.5065), of France (London, 1909}, Cd.4512); of Germany (London, 1908, Cd.4032. Whether so many workers were demoted within factories in France as in Germany is not clear; as many workers crop up, after age 65; in metals, textiles, and construction as the overall manufacturing average; Slightly lower percentages in metallurgy as mining relate to formal pension plans as well as wearing work. But from most industries some older workers flowed into the casual labor force. See Chapter VIII; estimates based on the 1901, 1906, and 1911 censuses.
77. 8.8% over 55 years of age in French textiles, compared to 6.2% in metallurgy and 6.1% in mining in 1901; Charles Benoist, 'Le Travail dans la grande industrie,' Revue des Deux Mondes (1902), 853.
78. Fritz Schumann, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Automobilindustrie (Leipzig, 1911), 111.
79. Ibid., Ill and passim.
80. Richard Ehrenberg, 'Schwàche und Starkung neuzeitlicher Arbeitsgemeinschaften,' Thunen-Archiv (1911), 415 ff.
81. John H. Goldthorpe et al., The Affluent Worker in the Class Structure (Cambridge, 1969).
82. Peter N. Stearns, 'Adaptation to Industrialization: German
Workers as a Test Case,' Central European History (1970), 303 if.
83. Lande, Arbeitsverhaltnisse; A. L. Levine, Industrial Retardation in Britain (London, 1967); E. Backert, Geschichte der Brauarbeiterbewegung (Berlin, 1916).
84. Levine, Retardation; Schumann, Auslese; Lucien Brocard, 'La Grosse métallurgie française et le mouvement des prix de 1890 à 1913,'.Revue d'histoire économique et sociale (1922), 394.
85. Ehrenberg, 'Schwâche,' 517 ff.
86. Theodore Hamerow, Restoration, Revolution, Reaction (Princeton, 1956); Stephan Thernstrom, Poverty and Progress: Social Mobility in a Nineteenth Century City (Cambridge, Mass., 1964); Clyde Griff en, 'Occupational Mobility in Nineteenth-Century America,' Journal of Social History (1972), 310-30.
87. Richard Ehrenberg and Hugo Racine, Krupp'sche Arbeiter-Familien (Jena, 1912); Schumann, Auslese.
88. Adrien Veber, 'Le Mouvement social,' La Revue socialiste (1900), 367; British Steel Smelters, Mill, Iron and Tinplate Workers Association, Monthly Reports, 1913.
89. H. A. Clegg, General Unions in a Changing Society (Oxford, 1964), 3—6; Jules Lekeu, A Travers le Centre; Croquis et moeurs; enquête ouvrière et industrielle (Brussels, 1907), 32. J. R. Clynes described how often agitation among cotton piecers was dampened by the criticism of the spinners, who were typically their fathers or uncles: Memoirs (London, 1937), I, 57.
90. Amalgamated Society of Railway Servants, General Secretary's Report (1905), 11. On the British railways one normally moved from a training period to fireman, where one served for eight years or so before expecting to rise to engineer; cleaners could ultimately hope to rise to foreman's positions, while brakemen and signalmen had their own hierarchies.
91. H. Stanley Jevons, The British Coal Trade (London, 1915), 335; Adolf Levenstein, Aus der Tiefe, Arbeiterbriefe (Berlin, 1908), 21—2; David Crew, 'Definitions of Modernity: Social Mobility in a German Town, 1880-1901,' Journal of Social History (1973), 51-74.
92. Adolf Zimmermann, Von Haspe biz Duisburg. Industrielle Reisebriefe (Berlin 1912); see also Archives départementales du Nord M625/111, report of September 1904; John Jewkes and E. M. Gray, Wages and Labour in the Lancashire Cotton Spinning Industry (Manchester, 1935), 93.
93. Lekeu, Centre, 32 ff.; Edward J. O'B. Croker, Retrospective Lessons on Railway Strikes (London, 1 898), 11.
94. Wil Jon Edwards, From the Valley I Came (London, 1958), 142 ff.; Jevons, Coal, 596 ff.; William Reddy, 'Family and Factory: French Linen Weavers in the Belle Epoque,' Journal of Social History (197'4).
95. Die Bergarbeiterzeitung, 1899 ff.; Heinrich Mvinz, Die Lage der
Bergarbeiter im Ruhrrevier (Essen, 1909).
96. Joan Scott has described the settling process for Carmaux glass workers, where the percentage of workers born locally rose dramatically in the 1880s and 1890s. 'The Glassworkers of Germany 1850—1900,' in Stephan Thernstrom and Richard Sennett, Nineteenth Century Cities (New Haven 1969), 3-42. The contrast between British and German mining, in teims of the stabilization process, is equally striking, though German miners were picking up the same trend. Up to 70% of all new Scottish and up to 85% of all new Welsh miners were sons of miners, and a large portion of the older workers had been many years with the same company; only 40% of the Ruhr miners were sons of miners even by 1914, and in representative companies only 19% of the miners had 10 years or more experience. B. McCormick and J. W. Williams, 'The Miners and the Eight-Hour Day,' The Economic History Review (1959), 239 ff.; Gerhard Adelmann, Quellensammlung zur Geschichte der sozialen Betriebsverfassung: Ruhrindustrie unter besonderer Berùcksichtigung des Industrie-und Handelskammerbezirks Essen (Bonn, 1965), II, 103.
97. R. Godfernaux, Aperçu de l'évolution des chemins de fer français de 1878 à 1928 (Paris, 1928), 32: Charlotte Leubu-scher, Der Arbeitskampf der englischen Eisenbahner im Jahre 1911 (Munich, 1913), 21 ff.; Archives nationales (France) F 713826.
98. Paul Gôhre, Drei Monate Fabrikarbeiter (Leipzig,- 1913); Otto Jeidels, Die Methoden der Arbeiterentlôhnung in der rheinisch-westfàlischen Eisenindustrie (Berlin, 1907).
99. Max Morgenstern et al., Auslese und Anpassung der Arheiterschaft (Leipzig, 191-2); The illiteracy rate in French textiles in 1901 was 15%; in metallurgy 6%; in printing, 2%: Ministère du commerce, Résultats statistique du recensement général de la population (Paris, 1904); Jewkes and Gray, Wages.
100. Eugène Rousseau, La Grève générale dans le Centre en 1913 (Ghent, 1913), 6.
.01. Stearns, 'Adaptation,' passim.
.02. This point needs some possible qualification for workers who strove to escape manual labor altogether, a topic tak&n up in the Conclusion; but their number was not vast.
.03. On the economic roles of the stabilized working-class family, see Michael Anderson, Family Structure in Nineteenth-Century Lancashire (Cambridge, 1971).
.04. Levenstein, Tiefe, passim.
05. The one possible exception, and a massive one, is mining, in which direct-action protest occurred at the highest rate of all. There i_s too little information available about miners' job choice to determine if it had anything at all to do with protest. German miners undoubtedly chose their jobs less often than British, and their protest rate was much lower — though still high compared to protest rates of other German industrial categories. British miners
may have chosen their jobs, if only through parental example, and then rebelled because they failed to find what they were seeking, or they may have entered without alternatives and protested steadily as a result. There are, of course, many other factors involved in the massive strike rate of miners in all the industrial countries. Clark Kerr and Abraham Siegel, 'Interindustry Propensity to Strike — An International Comparison,' in A. Kornhaus, R. Dubin, and A. M. Ross, eds., Patterns of Industrial Conflict (New York, 1954).
CHAPTER 3 UNEMPLOYMENT
Unemployment, like the choice of a job, touched almost every aspect of the work experience. The vast majority of manufacturing and transport workers — except those with jobs in the mines and metallurgy — could expect to undergo some unemployment during their work career, and many would be frequently unemployed and for long periods of time. This stark fact requires a careful assessment of the nature of unemployment, despite its relationship to topics that will be discussed subsequently such as technological change. The subject is exceedingly complex, which is doubtless why it has been avoided by most students of the working class heretofore. No simple set of factors explains unemployment during this period; direct displacement by machines, for example, played only a small role, despite many workers' impressions that they were the principal villains. Complexity is compounded when we treat differences from one industrial category to the next; we must again deal with artisans in quite different terms, dividing them between small-town and urban, various groups of factory workers and the unskilled: the rates of unemployment varied widely. Within this framework we must try to determine what unemployment meant. For a few workers it was deliberate, for most a great burden. But some of those most severely burdened in a material sense were not surprised by unemployment, while others learned to fight it vigorously, some with considerable success. And, as with the choice of jobs, there was a certain evolution at work as industry itself matured, in which many types of workers learned to bring unemployment under some controls save in years of outright crisis. Fatalism most assuredly declined, although everywhere the fact or fear of unemployment cut severely into the stability of working-class life.
It is distressingly difficult to establish the incidence of unemployment with any precision. Given the difficulty with present-day unemployment figures we could expect many problems in the interpretation of unemployment statistics, in terms of seasonal, sex, and age adjustments. In fact, for this period, the figures themselves are often close to useless. Their existence is tantalizing, and we will utilize the outline they provide for several purposes. But we must turn quickly to more limited examples and impressions that provide no more general
statistical precision than the materials on job choice. A word, first, about the sources themselves.
All the industrial countries provided annual and monthly unemployment figures by 1900. The series sometimes changed categories, but at least numbers are available. They derive, unhappily, from trade union records; only in France, during this period, was unemployment checked as part of the census process. But the trade union figures covered only a minority of the working class. They were heavily biased toward the skilled. Unskilled unions were small and normally composed of unusually stable workers. This could lead some government statisticians, as in Germany, to claim that skilled workers were unemployed more often than unskilled, which overall was nonsense.1 Even among the skilled there are serious questions about the representativeness of the membership sample. Did unemployables flock to unions to receive benefits? Or as was more probable, were union members among the healthier, diligent workers and therefore less likely to be unemployed than the average in their trade? Union figures undoubtedly minimized unemployment overall and possibly even in highly unionized trades. Furthermore, apart from the limitations of their staff work, unions had different motives in reporting unemployment figures. German unions tended to minimize rates because of the responsibilities they had in the social security system. French unions may, for doctrinal reasons, have exaggerated their rates. All told, the British unemployment figures are most reliable because of the size and experience of the unions and the fact that they had little to gain from exaggeration in either direction. Belgian and German figures are ludicrously low and deserve attention only for their indications of orders of magnitude over time and among industries; they cannot be seriously compared with the British. French figures seem more reasonable, despite the small size of unions, and the census check supports their utilization.
One final problem, with any of the sources on unemployment, relates to the reaction to unemployment itself. Many workers were desperately eager to avoid being called unemployed. The anxiety comes out strongly among Belgian workers, who were in so many cases close to the countryside and conscious of their neighbors' scorn for failure. A study of the unemployed in Ghent noted how few of the jobless registered at the Fonds du Chômage, because they felt they had 'dropped out of humanity' if they admitted their situation.2 The workers who were still rural residents could often conceal unemployment by working in the fields. Some were claimed to welcome
the chance to catch up on home chores. But unfortunately for those observers who noted the dignity of workers who stayed home instead of pacing the streets, peak unemployment rarely coincided with the chance even to putter in one's garden; the observer who in December 1910 explained away a 7 percent unemployment rate in two of the backward provinces (Louvain and Nivelle) that supplied commuting workers for heavy industry, although far more accurate statistically than the government sources, simply ignored the seasonal factor. He was misled not only by the myth that things can't be too b ad if they're rural but by the workers' own sense of dignity.3 A similar desire to refuse to admit unemployment, plus the sheer necessities of survival, prompted many unskilled or even skilled workers to change jobs when unemployment struck. Hence in East Germany many textile workers did building trades work during the summer, at considerable cost to their professional skill; their own work was slack in this pe riod, and by leaving machines unmanned they believed they reduced the chance of overproduction later. These workers, too, would rarely report unemployment, for alternatives in rough work were preferable to a confession of failure.4
One can only suggest the kind of culture that produced this reaction, to which we must return in discussing the fears of even more sophisticated workers. A long tradition of underemployment in the countryside combined with village scorn for idleness and th difficulty of appealing to communal resources produced the culture, which may then have been enhanced by bourgeois promptings about the virtues of self-reliance. There is no question that it distorted the description of effective unemployment in many areas and industries. At the same time, the culture was declining around the turn of the century. Many artisans had long been loath to take work outside their skill, preferring unemployment instead; hence many engineering worker in Berlin factories cited the lack of 'suitable' work, not of work itself, in explaining their frequent unemployment.5 This mood spread in the factories. Alfred Williams described the unwillingness of fitters and boilermakers in his locomotive plant to take work outside their trade ; they preferred wandering, even begging.6 More and more workers came to see unemployment not as a personal failure but as a fault in the system, and their anger mounted as a result. Demonstrations by building trades workers in London, between 1901 and 1906, occurred amid unemployment that was undeniably uncomfortable, but relatively mild by traditional standards; what was new was the reaction.7
All of this means that unemployment figures were most accurate in
countries like Britain, and industries like machine building or printing, where workers defined their dignity in terms of their skill, and not the mere fact of holding a job. It means that the accuracy of the figures probably improved with time, not only because union membership became more widespread, which increased the reporting sample, but because more and more workers stopped seeing unemployment as a matter of shame and began to press for solutions. But the new mood could tend less to correct than to reverse the statistical problem: from underreporting workers might turn to exaggeration. Certainly the fears of unemployment stressed by the most articulate workers did not correspond to the discernible statistical trends; they mounted much more quickly. The repeated laments of skilled British workers - much more widespread than those in Germany — did not reflect a comparative difference in actual unemployment of comparable magnitude. It stemmed instead from a consciousness of unemployment as a social problem that was only beginning to spread in Germany or Belgium. This, too, complicates the task of the historian forced to go beyond the general statistics to more impressionistic sources.
National unemployment figures produce two unsurprising, if significant, conclusions, and one of high probability which is less expected. Unemployment oscillated greatly from year to year, by as much as 300 percent. It varied far more from one industry to the next, and this gives even yearly national figures quite limited utility in measuring the human fact of unemployment. But if we can attribute any value to the national figures they suggest that unemployment was undergoing an interesting decline during the years before World War I, most marked in France and Belgium while somewhat debatable in Britain where stability rather than decline is a more probable conclusion. This differential trend coincides with the thesis that can be offered concerning the overall relationship between maturing industrialization and unemployment: that the advance of industry could be compatible with apparently low rates of unemployment, where the economy of the countryside was not massively disturbed — the possible case in Germany; that more normally it ate into the rural bases of employment, swelling joblessness among the unskilled particularly — the Belgian and even more the French case early in our period; but that further advance would reduce unemployment levels, not only because of abstract processes of the economy but also because of actions by workers themselves, including new kinds of job choices, while leaving workers still highly vulnerable to economic crises — the British case and increasingly the French and Belgian.
Before dealing with differentials and trends, however, it is vital to establish the range of unemployment during the period as a whole, and this is precisely where the national figures are least helpful. Between 1891 and 1913, official statistics8 revealed an average unemployment rate of 4.3 percent in Britain (excluding the sick, and superannuated, and strikers), 2.2 percent in Germany, 2.9 percent in Belgium, and 7.0 percent in France (none of these last figures distinguishing so carefully among types of joblessness). The role of economic crises is rather clearly delineated by the national figures. Unemployment rose massively (by 80 percent) between 1891 and 1892 in Britain.9 The effects of the 1902—3 slump, so widely discussed at the time, were more muted; unemployment rose 21 percent in Britain, 23 percent in France, and scarcely at all in Germany in the first year of the crisis. The unskilled were hit harder than this, of course, and even unionized workers were much more seriously affected in many centers; for many, the employment effects of the crisis were felt more seriously later, in 1904-5— this was particularly true in the building trades, which influenced the national figures substantially and help account for their otherwise surprising pattern. The recession of 1908—9 was more sharply felt, partly because union reporting had improved but also because unionized workers were more vulnerable than before. The increase between 1907 and 1908 was only 25 percent in France, but 81 percent in Germany, 111 percent in Britain, and 156 percent in Belgium. In all these cases — and particularly in the slumps of the mid-nineties and 1902—3 — official figures were only the tip of an immeasurable iceberg. In Germany in 1901, for example, metal workers in Berlin reported up to 25 percent unemployment, plus vast amounts of short time, while the official figures showed the most modest national rate. In 1908, similarly, German unions on their own spoke of jobless rates of over 15 percent; and here as in the other countries the unskilled were scarcely counted.10 Thus, at a conservative estimate, between one in ten and one in five workers was out of work at any point of a crisis year, and between 1891 and 1914 there were at least eight crisis years.
Within a single year of normal prosperity, seasonal fluctuations were severe. They were endemic in the building trades. While about 5 percent of French construction workers lacked a job during the summers, the rate rose to ten percent or above during the winters. Seasonal variation was a bit less in Britain, at 6.3 percent between January and May. But fluctuations in Germany were still more radical, in part because of more severe winters but in part because of the poor organization of
small-town construction work. Hence in 1909 — admittedly a recession year — unemployment of unionized workers was 2.9 percent in small towns and 5.6 percent in large during the summer, but rose to 38 percent and 22 percent respectively by December.11 Winter unemployment was also high in quarry work.12 Obviously winter unemployment could be palliated by taking other jobs; many German masons learned to serve as brewery workers during the winter. But increasing rationalization made this particular interchange less feasible, and more and more masons were reduced to small repair jobs periodically during the winter.13 Of more lasting utility, in some areas, was the fact that dock employment peaked in the winter, but this could draw workers to these jobs who would find themselves on the streets again come spring. Seasonal factors in other crafts were different, but only a bit less severe. Employment among furniture workers varied 169 percent during an average year in Britain. Printers encountered greatest joblessness in the summer; their employment rates varied as much as 90 percent during a normal year (the range in Britain was from 3.3 to 6.3 percent during the years from 1900 through 1914).14 Jewelry and precious metal workers were victims of seasonal irregularities in the popularity of their products, as were the semi-skilled workers in the sweated clothing trades.
Seasonal factors were much less significant in the factories than in the crafts or among unskilled workers, but they were far from negligible. Shipbuilders reported long waits between jobs after a ship was completed, though overall metal and engineering work was relatively stable, ranging in Britain by 24 percent from a low in May to a peak in December. Workers in the light industries, such as textiles and shoe-making, suffered more seriously from seasonal variations in demand. These were reflected more commonly in short time than in outright unemployment, but the impact could be serious even so. The production of bicycles in Saint-Etienne dropped radically every autumn. A Belgian weaving factory reported a gap of five to six weeks between pieces on each loom, so that workers in theory responsible for four looms actually worked only three, with a corresponding loss of income, except during the autumn clothing boom. The percentage of workers on full time could fall to a low of 57 percent in British shoe-making during a slack season.15 Oscillations in heavy industry were far less significant, and again took the form of short time rather than unemployment; between 1900 and 1914 the average monthly variation of total shifts worked per coal miner in Britain was 10 percent (the peak occurring during the winter months), while that of iron and
Table I Annual Unemployment Rates
Britain |
France |
Belgium |
Germany |
|
1891 |
3.5 |
|||
1892 |
6.3 |
|||
1893 |
7.5 |
|||
1894 |
6.9 |
|||
1895 |
5.8 |
|||
1896 |
3.3 |
|||
1897 |
3.3 |
|||
1898 |
2.8 |
|||
1899 |
2.0 |
6.6 |
1.5 |
|
1900 |
2.5 |
6.8 |
2.5 |
|
1901 |
3.3 |
7.8 |
2.3 |
|
1902 |
4.0 |
9.9 |
4.0 |
2.4 |
1903 |
4.7 |
9.4 |
5.3 |
2.1 |
1904 |
6.0 |
10.2 |
3.3 |
2.1 |
1905 |
5.0 |
9.0 |
2.8 |
1.6 |
1906 |
3.6 |
8.0 |
1.8 |
1.2 |
1907 |
3.7 |
7.0 |
2.3 |
1.6 |
1908 |
7.8 |
8.6 |
5.9 |
2.9 |
1909 |
7.7 |
7.3 |
3.4 |
2.8 |
1910 |
4.7 |
5.8 |
2.1 |
1.9 |
1911 |
3.0 |
5.7 |
1.9 |
1.9 |
1912 |
3.2 |
5.4 |
1.1 |
2.0 |
1913 |
2.1 |
4.2 |
2.0 |
2.9 |
steel workers was only 2 percent.16 But these important exceptions only place the instability of employment for most workers into sharper relief.
In virtually all the unstable trades, furthermore, a minority of workers were favored with unusually regular employment, as employers sought to content a nucleus of particularly adept or docile workers. A few privileged workers regularly worked four looms in the Belgian textile factory described above. An elite of leather workers in Offenbach was exempted from seasonal short time.17 Even miners consistently complained of favoritism in the allocation of above-average numbers of shifts. And on the docks and in the building trades, inequality in the access to work was endemic. Variations among workers who had daily contact with each other could produce
self-satisfaction among the fortunate and apathetic despair among those condemned to instability. Increasingly, it caused resentment.
Unpredictability, within a year as well as from year to year, obviously colored workers' reactions to their jobs, particularly when it was concluded that part of the instability was due to human agency. And the massive oscillations in employment levels, along with great variations among industries and among groups of workers within a single trade, limit the desirability of positing an 'average' unemployment experience. Yet the effort to establish a composite picture has some merit in getting at the human experience which unemployment involved.
We can assume that at any point during a given year (lumping crisis and prosperity together) an average of at least 4 percent of all workers were unemployed in Britain and France. In fact this is surely a minimum figure, typical in fact of prosperous years, because of the underreporting of the unskilled, as the French statistics, which took more account of dockers and builders' laborers, already suggest. Actual rates in Germany, as we shall see from local reports, were probably comparable if not a bit higher. What did this mean, in terms of a worker's experience? Simple mathematics reveals that an annual unemployment rate of 4 percent, if spread equally over the entire labor force during 313 working days each year, would produce the loss of twelve and a half days for each worker. A series of local studies suggests that this calculation accurately conveys the days lost to unemployment among the kinds of workers included in trade union figures, but that a minority of workers bore the brunt in any single year. Available British statistics confirm the pattern closely. London compositors, for example, reporting an average of 5 percent unemployment, saw this spread among 20 percent of all workers during the year — suggesting that each unemployed worker was out nearly three months. More typically Scottish blacksmiths, with an average rate of 13 percent unemployment during 1894, spread it among 45 percent of all workers at some point, for a typical unemployment period of about a month.18 In 1892 60 percent of all members of the Amalgamated Society of Engineers were unemployed less than three days; 17 percent three days to four weeks; 7 percent four to eight weeks; 4.5 percent eight to twelve weeks; and 11 percent twelve weeks or more. In a better year, in 1895, a larger percentage were unemployed a few days or not at all (76 percent). The amount of moderate-term unemployment, up to four weeks, dropped 7.2 percent, but the other figures varied more modestly: 5 percent were unemployed four to eight weeks, 3 percent
eight to twelve weeks, and over 8 percent more than twelve weeks.19 The engineers' and compositors' figures reveal that in industries relatively stable in terms of seasonal factors, unemployment rates of 2 up to 5 percent annually involved over a fifth of the entire labor force at some point, for an average term of several weeks.
A study of the 1278 unemployed workers in York in June 1910 suggests a similar pattern in which most British unemployment was relatively long-term; the study occurred when union unemployment in the city was listed at 3.7 percent, but did not depend on union documentation. Of the unemployed only 1.1 percent had been jobless less than a week. Figures for other intervals reflected a large hard-core group; thus whereas 7.8 percent had been jobless between two and four weeks and 14 percent between eight and twelve, 11.5 percent had been out of work between seven and nine months and 5.6 percent over two years.20
German materials display a different and in some ways more distressing pattern, for in addition to a hard-core group — visible in part because the German union statistics did not distinguish clearly between those lacking work and those incapacitated by illness, accident or old age21 — there was also a sizeable minority affected by several weeks of joblessness each year. The result was more general if possibly less intense suffering than in England. Among unskilled Berlin machine workers in 1906, for example, 41 percent suffered prolonged. unemployment during a good year because of illness, lack of work, or old age. The average skilled worker was less vulnerable, though more so than official union figures reflected, but still over a third suffered unemployment of two weeks to a month each year.22 In the crafts the situation was at least as bad. In 1907 17 percent of all unionized printers were unemployed at some point each quarter, over 40 percent at some point each year. Partly because of the poor economic situation 25 percent of all woodworkers lost time to illness alone in 1902; but even in 1897, a good year, 23 percent had done so. In 1902 unemployment and illness combined caused 52 percent of all skilled woodworkers to lose time from their jobs. German building trades workers suffered at least as severely. In 1900 32 percent of all roofers were unemployed at some point, while 27 percent of all masons were out of work in December alone.23 And the length of unemployment among German union members was extraordinary. Of the masons identified in December, 1900, as unemployed, 22 percent had lacked work for at least thirteen weeks. The woodworkers in 1902 averaged, if unemployed, 34 days each; if sick or injured, 29 days. Unemployed
Berlin printers in 1910 were out 18.4 days, on the average, and in 1912, 23 days: some were unemployed three or four different times during the year to reach this figure.24 In 1907 the average unemployed miner was out 27 days; the printer, 23 days; the woodworker, 15 days; the metal worker, 14 days; the baker, 11 days; the leather worker, 17 days; and the ship's carpenter 61 days. Interestingly in this case heightened unemployment in 1908 did not increase the average duration of unemployment overall; considerable duration seemed endemic to German unemployment. This same pattern prevailed in France. In 1896 only 12 percent of all unemployed males had been out only a week or less; 14 percent had been jobless for 26 weeks or more. Only a few trades such as printing had commonly brief stints, and by 1906, when only five percent of all unemployed suffered for a week, and a full 35 percent for over 26 weeks, even these privileged pockets had disappeared.25
None of this adds up to a complete statistical picture of unemployment, and to some the figures may already have become excessive. Yet a few general conclusions are obvious. Most important, a listed rate of four or five per cent unemployment was no idle figure to large segments
of the labor force; it cannot be dismissed as the sad lot of a small minority. In Britain it was compatible, in prosperous years, with long-term unemployment of up to a fifth of a skilled labor force,26 while in crisis years another group of up to 20 percent might be hit with up to four weeks of unemployment. In Germany prosperous years saw a higher percentage of workers affected by unemployment than in Britain, with up to a third of all skilled workers involved, for often substantial periods of time - a pattern not too dissimilar from British crisis years save that the hard-core group must have been smaller, for average duration was less. And during a year of recession, over half the labor force might be touched with unemployment at some point. In a situation such as this few workers would be immune from a fear of losing work and most would endure the experience several times during their working life.27
Who were the unemployed? Several approaches might be revealing here. Women were less likely to be unemployed than men in a given industry - 50 percent less likely in Saxony in 1910—11.28 This reflected some employer preference to keep cheaper workers on, perhaps, but more the withdrawal of unemployed women from the labor force. More significant is the apparent urban-rural pattern. The very biggest cities drew in so many unskilled workers, plus excessive skilled workers in trades like printing, that their rates would be higher
than those of other cities. In 1901, for example, the Parisian unemployment rate was more than twice as high as that in the industrial Nord.29 Berlin and to a lesser extent London were also pockets of massive unemployment; so was Brussels, where unemployment could hit 19 percent while in other Belgian cities it ranged between 4 percent and 10 percent.30 But city unemployment generally was lower than that in small towns, except the outright factory center. In 1910 a small-town construction worker in Germany was 60 percent more likely to be unemployed than his big-city counterpart. Similar patterns prevailed in printing and other crafts.31 These urban patterns relate in turn to the distribution of unemployment among key industries, which is the most important single way to break the phenomenon down.
Relatively few groups of workers enjoyed unemployment rates markedly below the average, but they included a large minority of the labor force. We have seen that railroad workers (not including maintenance men) chose their profession in part because of the regularity of employment. Miners and metallurgical workers were the oilier large categories among whom unemployment was normally not a problem.32 Scattered returns from Germany suggest a normal unemployment rate among miners of about .2 percent; only in the crisis year of 1901, when the rate was 4.1 percent, were over one percent of all miners unemployed. French miners suffered briefly in 1905-6, when rates in some months soared past 5 percent, but normally they too were under one percent, even in the recession of 1908—9. The French censuses of 1901 and 1905 recorded .05 and .5 percent unemployment in the mines, respectively. Unemployment among British miners may have run slightly higher, and between 1907 and 1909 it topped 5 percent; but again the normal rate was so low that it undoubtedly included only voluntary job-changes plus some incapacitated workers. Thus short time was a greater problem in the mines than unemployment, but even here workers were rarely deprived of at least live days of work per week. Metallurgical workers were even better off. The French census caught them with .03 and .17 percent unemployment in 1901 and 1906; German rates were a bit higher, averaging something over 1 percent between 1901 and 1905 and thea pulling up to 2.1 percent and 3.9 percent in 1912 and 1913. No rates are available for Britain, but short time was less significant than in the mines. Given the normal unemployment experience, the distinctive situation in heavy Industry was a tremendous boon for the workers involved. Metallurgical workers, who often lived near other categories that suffered much more
seriously, could particularly appreciate their advantages; one may hear echoes of their foresight in their efforts to keep their sons out of the more remunerative but chancier jobs in metal work. Miners, with no comparative base immediately visible, were less likely to reflect a sense of satisfaction with their job security.
Most factory workers endured unemployment rates close to the national averages, though there are some areas of uncertainty. Reported rates in the textile factories were usually rather low, though we have noted considerable seasonal underemployment. German textile unions reported an average of 1.4 percent unemployment; the French censuses recorded .04 and 1.7 percent unemployment in the textile factories. British rates were usually between 2 and 3 percent. Unemployment in Ghent textiles was a bit over 3.5 percent in 1910. But French unions recorded an average of 6.9 percent unemployment between 1901 and 1914, and there were complaints about massive joblessness in Roubaix and Rheims at various points.33 So textiles present some uncertainties, beneath the official rates. Shoe manufacture was distinctly chancier. Germany reported rates of over 6 percent on several occasions, while in France the unions claimed an average of almost 8 percent; there were unusually wide fluctuations in the industry. Metals and engineering provide more ample information. Generally unemployment in these industries was close to the national average or a bit higher, placing them at the risky edge of the factory group. Thus the French censuses, listing 2.6 and 3.7 percent rates in 1901 and 1906, reported no higher rates in a predominantly factory industry. German recorded rates ranged between 1 and 3 percent, but we have seen that these should probably be doubled. French unions averaged 7.0 percent between 1901 and 1914, British unions 5.9 percent between 1891 and 1914 (a rate pulled up by shipbuilding, whose average was 8.9 percent); engineering specifically was 4.3 percent. Thus 5 percent unemployment was a very common pattern in the industry. These rates, plus the skill involved in much machine work, understandably produced important efforts at job defense. Hence a high rate of demarcation disputes, particularly in Britain; ship's carpenters, for example, seemed almost permanently at war with the riveters. Other workers tried to refuse to train new workers, to protect their jobs. And throughout the industry there was a widespread sense of threat, for machines and unskilled labor seemed to combine to menace the whole future of the industry.34
But in general factory workers were less afflicted by unemployment and the fears it produced than other workers who laid claim to special skills. The urban crafts were significantly less stable, a distinction that
was not new but could be seriously troubling. Printers approached a 5 percent unemployment level: British typographers averaged 4.6 percent between 1891 and 1913, London compositors 5.3 percent. The French census found printers hovering under a 4 percent rate (3.8 and 3.6 percent in 1901 and 1906 respectively) — reflecting an interestingly low level in France which union figures confirm — while unionized printers in Germany averaged 4.6 percent. Printers, then, suffered about the same unemployment rates as metal workers. Both groups were highly skilled and divided between large shops and small. Woodworkers, also mixed in factories and shops, had comparable unemployment rates: 4.0 percent in Britain, but higher in France (at 10 percent according to union figures) and probably in Germany (at 2.5 percent even "by official statistics) where factories were less widely developed. The more artisanal the situation in this industry, the higher the unemployment rates: hence furniture makers in most countries (except Britain, where factories were well established) had extremely high unemployment rates. In France furniture workers often refused to train apprentices because of the threat to jobs, while Belgian furniture workers often suffered over 10 percent unemployment even in prosperous years.35 Artisans in all these trades, caught between the traditional attractions of their craft and new machine competition, could easily echo the fears of their colleagues in the engineering plants: a French printer lamented, 'Unemployment, one of the greatest wounds of present-day society, has installed itself as master in all the shops, where previously there was security for the morrow.'36
But the crafts more remote from the factory orbit were worse off still. Artisans in jewelry and precious metals suffered from unemployment averages bordering on 10 percent. Bakers fared just as badly. German bakers averaged almost 12 percent unemployment, never falling below 6 percent. In contrast to factory textiles, workers manufacturing hats and gloves suffered massive unemployment, again ranging over 10 percent in theoretically prosperous years. As could be predicted from their severe seasonal problems, skilled construction workers were often without work. British carpenters and joiners averaged 4.6 percent unemployment, all English builders 4.5 percent (5.3 percent in London); their Continental counterparts were far worse off. As we have seen, German unemployment rates surpassed 12 percent when averaged through the year. Here too complaints multiplied. British workers claimed, in the winter of 1905—6, that they could 'never recollect being so badly off since we have been in the trade.37 French workers sought an explanation in new machinery: 'A
building which, fifty years ago, took two years to build, is now done in six months.'38 And at one point Parisian builders resisted the imposition of a weekly day off, saying that they were already forced to miss more work than they wanted.39
The professions that contributed to the reports on unemployment thus displayed a range of almost 1000 percent, with articulated fears varying accordingly. Three groups of workers, reflected rarely in the official evidence, operated in quite a different climate. Workers in domestic industry, workers in the sweated trades, and male laborers were often employed at best half the year. Many of them could thus not think of work as a normal experience, and their whole culture was profoundly conditioned by uncertainty.
We have touched on domestic industry already. High unemployment rates in shoe manufacture or woodworking reflected a division between factory or urban shop workers and manufacturers in a putting-out system. The latter rarely appeared in trade union reports, and their unemployment was much more common than that of the unionized workers, but they put pressure on the whole employment situation. In French shoe manufacture only 36 percent of all domestic workers reported little unemployment; the remainder were out two to six months a year - a full third missing half a year's work.4 ° Many saw-makers working at home in Sheffield were almost permanently unemployed.41
Workers in the sweated trades showed up in some general rates, such as those for food processing and clothing. German clothing workers in 1912—13 suffered almost 29 percent average unemployment, those in Brussels often recorded at over 26 percent unemployed. Leather workers in France - here divided between largely unmechanized factories and outwork — were unemployed at a 20 percent rate. Thirteen per cent of French food workers were unemployed during an average year, again according to trade union figures. The French censuses, taken in the spring during a peak period of employment, nonetheless found clothing and leather workers second only to ditch-diggers in their unemployment rate (4-4.5 percent), with over 3 percent of all food processers out of work.
Finally there were the unskilled males, dependent on their ability to lift and haul. Here we return mainly to local evidence, but it is compelling. France provides the only general rates that can be taken seriously: in the summer of 1901, when their jobs were usually at a peak, 6 percent of all ditch-diggers were unemployed; five years later the rate was 7.1 percent. Unions of building trades workers (here
mixing skilled and unskilled) reported over 15 percent unemployment between 1901 and 1914, while unionized dockers averaged 26.9 percent annually from 1904 onward. The notion of average unemployment ranging above 20 percent per year is confirmed in other cases. A British Select Committee in 1896 described the hordes of workers seeking low-paying navvies' jobs in Wales. Over a third of the York unemployed were casual workers, serving as builders' laborers, porters, cab drivers, even agricultural laborers; while in London a mass of irregularly employed men shifted among small jobs in construction, printing, and engineering, as well as going to the docks.42 Thus big cities produced a host of sickly, slow, or misguided young people condemned to a life of casual labor; and their numbers were swelled by older workers displaced from other industries and by newcomers from the countryside, to whom the wages of a laborer's job could initially seem quite attractive.43 The result was chronically high unemployment.
Dock workers provided the best documentation of the appalling pressure because, far more than other laborers, they could hark back to more stable conditions in the past.44 A few ports provided havens of regularity even around the turn of the century. Belgian dock workers were organized in nations, each consisting of up to sixty chiefs or bazen, who served essentially as subcontractors, and about three hundred workers. The nations imposed stiff rules on absenteeism, drinking, and the like and in return could assure quite regular jobs in small ports like Bruges.45 Vestiges of similar arrangements existed in small ports in Germany, such as Flensburg; and new trade unions here could replace the older corporations in assuring stable jobs. In no case, given the haphazard arrival of ships, did such arrangements prevent significant unemployment, but they could keep it within certain limits and provide a fair distribution of the work that was available. But in ail the larger ports such arrangements were a thing of the past. Nations existed at Antwerp, for example, but they were powerless to prevent massive unemployment; the pattern of thirty-six hours of steady work followed by days without a job, so common to dock workers everywhere, held full sway.46 Rates, again, are hard to determine, but 50 percent unemployment was common in Liverpool and Bristol during the 1890s. In London in 1901 there were 7000 more dockexs than were used at maximum, and 9000 more than were used on the average — which assured that on a typical day 36 percent of all dockers would lack work.47 Rising unemployment was also reported in Marseilles and to a lesser extent Le Havre.48 In Hamburg in 1895, only
9 percent of all dockers worked over 210 days a year; 7 percent worked 106 to 210 days, while 83 percent had between a single day and 106 days. Obviously here and elsewhere figures could be swollen by occasional job-seekers from other fields. In Hamburg 59 percent of all dockers were in this category. Even so, only 22 percent of the permanent dockers approached regular employment (over 210 days), while 46 percent worked less than 106 days.49 And for their part many dockers did not move easily to other work, like the unskilled construction workers. Some observers claimed that this reflected a lack of knowledge and experience; it may also have mirrored an attachment to a profession that, in its odd way, had something of a craft background without the attendant skills.50 In any event, the lot of the docker would be truly pitiable. Statistically he could count himself lucky to work half the time, which meant that survival was always precarious. A London docker described a normal situation: 'I had three days' work last week, but three days doesn't go far with many mouths to feed at home.'51
Work among dockers, and to a slightly lesser degree among ordinary merchant seamen, was a constant battle. 'I daresay none of you know what it is to be out of work,' one man noted to a British Royal Commission. 'I wish that some of you had that experience. There are always crowds at the dock gates and wharf gates, even at the best of times, who are fighting and struggling for employments.'52 Periods of intense work alternated with anxious, usually fruitless waiting, in makeshift sheds and according to rather random periods of call.53 Unemployment rates among the unskilled encouraged favoritism and toadying beyond anything known in the factories or mines. Most employers tried to keep a cadre of steady workers, while periodically distributing work among enough others to maintain a labor force adequate to any sudden boom. A minority of dockers thus had relatively steady jobs. In Hamburg workers were divided into three classes, as the annual days of work rate reflected, with the 'steady workers' given first crack at every job.54 In all the big ports employers responded to labor unrest after the 1890s by extending the discriminatory system. 'Mixed' unions were everywhere successful in defusing agitation by assuring preferential hiring to a quarter to a third of the dockers.55 In Marseilles, for example, a quarter of the labor force was in a mixed union which promised that if one employer fired them they would be sent to another company immediately; a mixed union in Antwerp was similarly organized, with two workers on an executive board of twelve men. This system quashed agitation in
Marseilles for more than five years after 1904, in Antwerp for virtually a decade. For the majority of casual workers, whatever the theoretical interest in spreading work, jobs came through foremen or hiring bosses. In the German ports innkeepers served as hiring agents for dockers and especially seamen, taking healthy bribes in the process; British dock foremen were often bribed.56 Unskilled work, then, was degrading as well as unpredictable for masses of workers.
The typology of unemployment, even if it cannot be completely filled in, goes some way toward explaining both probable comparative differences among mature industrial countries, and trends in the two decades before World War I. Comparison is of course chancy, given the quality of the statistics, and the main point in all countries is the relatively high incidence of unemployment plus the similarity of patterns among key groups of workers. All the national figures, based on crafts and a few skilled factory sectors, do not adequately take miners into account, though there was some reporting, and they certainly do not embrace the bulk of the unskilled. Most, then, are probably understated for the working class as a whole. But it does seem likely that a country where industrialization was less advanced but where agriculture could no longer sustain a mass of underemployed labor suffered an unusually acute unemployment problem. Add a larger mass of vulnerable domestic manufacturing workers and the probability is enhanced still further. This might, along with admitted differences in the reporting base, explain the significant disparity between France and Britain. For Germany and Belgium, comparison is lost in conjecture because of the underreporting of factory and craft unemployment and the absence of any general information about the unskilled. Possibly the latter were still content to cling to the countryside, so that urban unemployment was really lower than in France. But Germany as well as France could produce the kind of angry rioting by otherwise inarticulate, young unskilled workers that reflects the presence of an excessive casual labor force in the cities. Several strikes called by factory or craft workers in Dusseldorf and Hannover, as in Saint-Etienne and Armentières, turned into violent action by this quite different group of workers.57 This was not the case in Britain, where periodic but calm marches by the unemployed reflected greater consciousness of the problem but also, possibly, a somewhat smaller degree of pressure. In any event, it is quite likely that overall unemployment was comparatively severe in Germany as well as in France. In Britain half a century earlier massive movement of the rural poor into the cities had created an unassimilable casual labor force,
Table II Trends in Unemployment
A. National Rates (annual averages per period)
Britain: |
1891-95, 6.0%; 1896-1900, 2.9%; 1901-05, 4.6%; 1906-10, 5.1%; 1911-13,2.8% |
Belgium: |
1902-05, 3.9%; 1906-10, 3.1%; 1911-13,1.7% |
France: |
1899-1905, 8.5%; 1906-10, 7.3%; 1911-13, 5.1% |
Germany: |
1899-1905, 2.1%; 1906-10, 2.1%; 1911-13, 2.3% |
B. Industrial Rates
Britain: |
1891-95 |
1896-1900 |
1901-05 |
1906-10 |
1911-13 |
Engineering, Metal, Shipbuilding |
8.5% |
3.6% |
6.2% |
8.3% |
3.1% |
Amalgamated Engineers alone |
6.4 |
2.4 |
4.5 |
6.0 |
2.4 |
Boilermakers & Shipbuilders |
12.6 |
5.4 |
9.8 |
14.2 |
2.5 |
Carpenters, Joiners |
3.4 |
1.4 |
5.5 |
9.2 |
3.7 |
Woodworkers, furniture |
3.6 |
2.3 |
5.0 |
6.1 |
2.9 |
Printers, Bookbinders |
4.6 |
4.0 |
4.6 |
5.0 |
4.8 |
London Compositors |
4.5 |
3.7 |
4.9 |
5.6 |
8.0 |
Typographical Association |
4.0 |
5.1 |
5.1 |
4.8 |
4.1 |
English Builders |
3.4 |
1.4 |
5.5 |
8.1 |
4.5 |
London Builders |
3.9 |
1.4 |
6.5 |
_ |
_ |
France: |
1901-06 |
1907-13 |
Mines |
3.7% |
.5% |
Chemicals |
3.4 |
5.2 |
Printing |
3.9 |
1.8 |
Leather |
17.1 |
22.5 |
Textiles |
7.5 |
6.3 |
Metals |
5.7 |
8.4 |
Building |
20.5 |
11.8 |
1904-06 |
1907-13 |
|
Shoes |
9.8% |
6.1% |
Wood |
12.1 |
8.7 |
Ports |
30.2 |
23.7 |
Germany:* |
1901-08 |
1909-13 |
Wood |
3.1% |
4.1% |
Leather |
1.9 |
2.5 |
Textiles |
1.5 |
1.3 |
Printing |
5.4 |
4.7 |
Building |
8.7 |
9.4 |
Transport |
2.0 |
2.1 |
Machines, Metals |
2.0 |
2.4 |
*based on scattered returns |
while unemployment on the Continent remained buried in the countryside; so now changes in agriculture plus, possibly, new yearnings by the rural unskilled imposed a heavy burden on the Continental cities.
And this in turn sets the framework for overall trends during the pre-war decades. A period of fifteen to twenty-five years provides a limited basis for generalization, to be sure, but it is long enough to stake out some conclusions. Despite tempting characterizations of the displacement caused by new levels of mechanization, and the intense and understandable belief in such characterizations on the part of many workers, overall unemployment rates went down in most cases, even as the reporting base improved, making it more likely that unemployment would be detected. Measurement by five-year periods in Britain reveals no upward trend; the three periods in which recessions occurred can be easily compared, while rates in the immediate pre-war years were slightly lower than those in the crisis-free late 1890s. French rates went steadily down, with the final three years reaching unprecedented lows; Belgian rates followed the same patterns. Only German rates rose slightly, but almost certainly because reporting improved right before the war. Where measurement is possible unemployment declined in almost every key industry in France and in many in Britain.(See Table II.)
To be sure, mechanization was felt in some general rates. In machine building and metals there was a secular trend towards increase in most countries. In other industries mechanization may have heightened rates more briefly, only to yield to an adjustment in the labor force or collective efforts to defend jobs. Thus problems in British typography were particularly acute for ten years after 1896, when the introduction of new machines was at its peak. Mechanization could also have shaped rising rates in the construction trades, which began to yield, and incompletely when they are controlled for the absence of recession, after 1911 in Britain. On the other hand, although the process defies exact tracing at this point, increasing mechanization, in opening up jobs to the unskilled, probably cut into rates in this vulnerable group; and overall, as the French and British figures both suggest, growing mechanization was compatible with stable or declining unemployment rates in such trades as printing, food processing, shoe manufacture, and even textiles. Furthermore, despite their persistent suffering, many dockers and other unskilled workers seem to have benefited by some regularization of their work as the period wore on. British docks by the 1890s, in entrusting hiring to employers' agents, were for all their
problems ahead of Continental ports, where hiring agents were under fewer controls. Everywhere the influx of rural workers began to dwindle, while labor agitation, even when abortive, prompted attention to better organization out of capitalist self-interest.58 The development of new kinds of work for untrained personnel could only have aided this process. Certainly the trends in French construction and dock work reveal a significant evolution. There is one obvious caveat here: unskilled workers were still pouring in from abroad, as the many complaints of seamen and builders' laborers about foreign competitors attest. The rates of joblessness among the immigrants were rarely measured, because the victims departed when they lacked work. In German Lorraine, for example, up to 25 percent of Italian workers left during the crisis of 1901.59
But at least for native workers advancing industrialization reduced irregular employment in normally prosperous years, showing some noticeable effects even within a two-decade span. Recessions were still severe, of course, and aside from this the improvement in average levels was cold comfort to workers in industries where mechanization did cut into jobs or to the masses of workers even in statistically improving situations who faced long stretches of unemployment each year. Even in a prospterous year right before the war, outright unemployment or the fear of it was a major factor in the job experience of all but a few segments of the working class. But the tendency toward some improvement was an important part of workers' experience. It related closely, if ironically, to the workers' own consciousness of their situation.
For beyond the obvious if important statement that workers hated and feared unemployment, the key point in assessing its impact on their consciousness is in terms of the sense of ineluctability. Workers who found the unemployment experience new would most obviously try to react against it. Dockers, as distinguished from the usually more quiescent builders' laborers, may have been roused to their sporadic, massive protests around the turn of the century by their realization that stability had been lost to a horde of new workers. Railroad employees could certainly be spurred by the fear of unemployment, for this challenged one of their main goals in work. In 1909-10 the Prussian railways fired seventy-three workers — a small number, but in context enough to drive masses of their colleagues into the union.60 On the other hand, when unemployment was regarded as normal it could sap any desire to seek improvements. Many older workers in Germany and elsewhere were profoundly affected by the searing experience of the
1870s, when they had lacked work themselves or suffered hunger as children because of their parents' unemployment; new recessions in the 1890s and after merely enhanced the desire to cling to whatever work was available. Similarly, high unemployment rates could produce great satisfaction among the minority of workers who were proud to be able to support their families; this was common on the docks, where it reduced ability to take collective action against arbitrary hiring practices.61 And quite apart from the impact of unemployment as seen in past crises or among one's fellows, many workers brought to their jobs a recollection, if only passed on from father to son, of the long period of underemployment that was part of agricultural life even before industrialization began. This, surely, must explain the mentality found in the Daimler automobile factory, where workers were so ready to claim that they chose their own jobs. There was virtually no unemployment here, yet most workers said they expected to lose their jobs sometime in the future. Yet beyond a sense of concern, even of dread, few could suggest what they would do if this happened. They said they had 'no information' or 'God only knows'; some talked of 'hoping to die first,' even of suicide, while others, less concerned, counted on fate or the divinity. But none had any plans or sense of alternatives, save in a few remarks that the state should increase benefits under existing old age and sickness insurance laws. Most, if pushed beyond general laments, talked only of begging or doing anything that came along.62
This kind of attitude had never characterized the urban crafts, with a tradition of organization against unemployment, and it would decline, with experience, in the factories. This is not to claim that workers had substantial control over the employment situation. Metal workers in Berlin or Britain were extremely conscious of the unemployment problem and consistently tried to remedy it. But direct efforts to limit apprentices had to give way, as we have seen, to attempts to defend job boundaries through demarcation disputes or to pious agreements, such as one reached by the Amalgamated Society of Engineers in 1907, that the employers' federation would urge its members to retain any worker displaced by machines.63 Unemployment mounted anyway, and the growing resentment of its toll simply produced a rising tide of angry protest. But where competitive pressure was less intense, workers' efforts could contribute to the stabilization or reduction of the unemployment rate. Apprentice agreements in printing obviously had an effect; German brewers were also successful in limiting the access of unskilled workers.64 On occasion, attacks on competing workers might
help. Unionized workers in many industries divided between factories and domestic production sought to eliminate the latter because of the threat to jobs and pay, most typically through bargaining agreements or organization of the domestic workers, but sometimes through physical assault. Hence after growing periods of unemployment bands of two to three hundred Fougères shoe workers in 1905 attacked the houses of domestic producers and threw their work away.65 Countless workers sought to limit production in order to preserve jobs. Parisian masons worked to rule as part of their period of intense unrest, following massive unemployment through 1905. South Wales tinplate workers traditionally responded to overproduction by limiting their effort per shift; in 1913 they even discussed a 'stop week' with employers. Limitation by agreement was actually achieved briefly in some crafts; it was tried in Birmingham brass manufacture in the 1890s, to the detriment of the industry, while precious metal workers set production quotas with their employers in 1903 and 1905.66
In no sense were devices or concerns of this sort new, but they were spreading more widely. And at the same time some traditional remedies declined in importance. British engineers, for example, reduced their traveling to seek jobs. Between 1890 and 1910 the use of travel cards from the Amalgamated Society of Engineers declined despite rising unemployment.6 7 Here was another sign of the settling-down process which so powerfully affected initial job choice. Traveling was a much more common remedy for workers whose commitment to a profession was limited or who could not really think of unemployment as anything but an act of God; hence its popularity among new miners or metallurgical workers in France and Germany. Increasingly workers strove for collective remedies. In addition to the customary arsenal they sought union shops, which obviously could serve to control job access, and they worked with growing vigor to reduce the hours of work as a means of protecting jobs. Stone cutters in Rouen who struck in 1910 for a ten-hour day and weekly rest defended their goals in terms of their desire 'to avoid too frequent unemployment,' and their thought could be echoed by countless workers throughout the period.6 8
And the growing concern about unemployment was responsible for the repeated claims that the problem was worsening even when this was not in fact true. If engineers had a good case to make in their laments that things had never been so bad, printers did not; there is every indication that printing unemployment had been higher in the 1880s and early 1890s than it was in the two decades before the war, yet complaints of unprecedented difficulty were regularly repeated in
many areas. There is no need to quibble about a lack of historical consciousness or statistical precision, for what was claimed was reality to vast numbers of workers. Growing unwillingness to accept unemployment combined with a sense of precise enemies — machines, in printing, or Jewish workers in British shoe-making or tailoring, or Chinese or Africans in the seaports — to create growing anger.70 The anger could lead to significant political or direct action protest; it could also lead to a sense that work had lost its value.
Yet though there was a trend in the consciousness about unemployment, workers were profoundly divided in this matter as in the experience of unemployment itself. Quite apart from the fact that attacks on unemployment often meant attacks on other workers, the gulf between those workers who saw no alternative but to accept unemployment as inevitable, and therefore jobs as a gift, and those who fought for their jobs remained great. Patterns of unemployment in Britain suggested in some ways that the gulf was widening, even aside from the rural workers who could still be found to take casual employment with a sense that any job was a boon. For many workers a few years' experience on the docks produced only a sorrowful apathy; an inquiry among unemployed workers in 1909 revealed a single dominant idea — to get a few days' work. Some workers even abandoned the notion of work itself: almost 10 percent of the York unemployed in 1910 no longer actively tried to get jobs.71 The very success of many skilled workers in defending their work, save during recession years, expanded the group of long-term unemployed, as we have seen. Their morale sagged and their physical constitution deteriorated. Hopelessness among the unemployed in every country owed much to their inevitable deficiency in diet. Many of the York workers, for example, ate only bread and achieved less than half of their minimum caloric needs.72
But if we must not forget the divisions within the working class concerning unemployment — including, at the other extreme, those industries where unemployment was not a problem — it is important to stress the division that unemployment or its threat created within the typical worker himself. Here was an experience beyond his immediate control. A few—14 percent, in one study — might be voluntarily unemployed, as they sought a better job or merely some leisure time; but the vast majority were under the severest compulsion.73 The damage to their income was immense. A Berlin lock-maker, if unemployed at all during the year, lost on the average a third of the income a full-time worker could earn during a year.74 Added to this
was a sense of failure that was hard to shake off. And the experience was profoundly lonely. Unions might offer brief assistance, but it was the worker himself who had to seek another job. Placement agencies existed, of course, and a bitter battles in France by workers such as bakers whose unemployment forced them to request new jobs frequently attested to how important an unbiased job service could be.75 But, in part because it was hard to free placement efforts from employer control and the resultant fear of favoritism, few workers actually found their jobs through them; and with rare exceptions trade union efforts to establish competitive services foundered on employer unwillingness to co-operate. Hence, in Germany, less than five percent of all workers found their jobs through the organized placement agencies.76 Even collective efforts to protest unemployment had to be indirect. Unemployed workers might vent their anger in violence or in encouraging their fellows to hold out in a strike; they might march. But while they were unemployed there was little they could do to get at the cause of their problem.
Hence the growing resentment of unemployment could be extremely frustrating. Of course it fed the rising tide of labor protest, for with the exception of mining the greatest agitation came from workers in industries with significant but not incapacitating unemployment problems, workers who could articulate the desirability of a different organization of labor. But these were the same workers who felt a sense of choice in their jobs and were increasingly reluctant to change professions. Consciousness of choice and consciousness of unemployment as something other than the hand of God were part of the same mentality, in which each element could feed the other. Here was a tension that embraced one's daily life at work, in which pride and fear regularly battled. In such ambiguity the actual experience of work took place.
Notes
1. Reichsarbeitsblatt, 1903. A claim that a higher percentage of skilled than unskilled workers was unemployed was based on a comparison of reports from the tramworkers' union (unemployment 1%) with printers (8%). Historians, including those most sympathetic to workers' hardships, have not been immune to similar errors. Jurgen Kuczynski, accepting union figures at even more than face value, says they describe the unemployment of the
'mass' of workers, even though they reach a peak of only 7.5% between 1900 and 1914. Die Geschichte der Lage der Arbeiter in England von 1640 bis in die Gegenwart (Berlin, 195 5), 134. In Britain, Norman B. Dearie, Problems of Unemployment in the London Building Trades (London, 1908) contrasts the low jobless rates among unionized (skilled) workers with the much higher but unreported rates of the casual laborers.
2. Louis Variez, Recensement des chômeurs gantois (Ghent, n.d.), 37.
3. H. Demain, Les Migrations ouvrières à travers la Belgique (Louvair, 1919), 161. See also B. Seebohm Rowntree, Land and Labour: Lessons from Belgium (London, 1911), who clearly found this one of the things Britain could profitably learn from the Belgians.
4. F. Hecht, Die Stôrungen in deutschen Wirtschaftsleben (Leipzig, 1903), I.
5. Dora Lande, Die Arbeits- und Lohnverhàltnisse in der Berliner Maschinenindustrie zu Beginn des 20. Jahrhunderts (Leipzig, 1910).
6. Alfred Williams, Life in a Railway Factory (London, 1915), 115.
7. E. H. Phelps Brown, The Growth of British Industrial Relations (London, 1959), 16ff.
8. The general unemployment rates have been derived from:
Statistisches Jahrbuch fur das deutsche Reich, Bulletin de l'Office du travail (France); Labour Gazette; and the Revue du travail (Belgium).
9. The Continental figures are simply not good enough even to report for the 1890s. (They are comparable in this regard to the ludicrous material available for the 1870s in Britain; in both cases unions were simply not large enough to report anything useful.) Official German statistics indicated only a 3% unemployment rate during the crisis of the mid-90s, which is absurd. Franz Hitze, Die Arbeiterfrage (Mônchen-Gladbach, 1905). In fact, unemployment in centers like Berlin ranged up to 19% in 1895, reflecting the impact on the unskilled as well as high rates among skilled workers. Alfred Zinn, Die Entwicklung der Industriestandortes Berlin (Berlin, 1955).
10. André Sayous, La Crise allemande de 1900-1902 (Paris, 1903); Korrespondent fur Deutschlands Buchdrucker und Schriftgiesser, 1908.
11. Zentralverband der Maurer Deutschlands, Jahrbuch, 19"09. In Paris only 25% of all building workers were reported as working all year round; Amédée Dunois, 'Le Lockout de la maçonnerie,' Pages libres (1908), 54.
12. Ernest Martel, La Vérité sur le Lock-out des carrières d'Ecausonne (Brussels, 1910).
13. Franz Habersbrunner, Die Lohn-, Arbeits-, und Organisations- Verhàltnisse im deutschen Baugewerbe (Leipzig, 1903).
14. Board of Trade, Abstract of Labour Statistics (London, 1915, Cd. 7733), 9.
15. Journal des Correspondances (Belgium), 1909, 51; Labour Gazette, 1904; M. Devin, 'L'Industrie du cycle à Saint-Etienne,' Revue de géographie alpine (1949), 12.
16. Board of Trade, Abstract, 10-12.
17. Ludwig Hagen, Die Lederwaren-Industrie in Offenbach am Main und Umgebung (Karlsruhe, 1905), 33 ff.
18. Phelps Brown, Growth, 75 ff.
19. William H. Beveridge, Unemployment, a Problem of Industry (London, 1931), 69.
20. B. Seebohm Rowntree and Bruce Lasker, Unemployment, a Social Study (London, 1911), 62.
21. A study in 1895 showed that 40% of all German unemployed were incapable of work, which might help explain the higher incidence of unemployment in Germany than in Britain, though logically it should produce far longer average duration as well. In the York study only 7% were physically handicapped, though another 42% of the unemployed might be described as disadvantaged in terms of age (25% were over 40) or bad character (mainly drunkenness). But the German crafts, where disparity with Britain is marked, were less affected by incapacity (printing 36%, wood 33%) than machines (41%), mining (68%), and textiles (55%). So the explanation cannot be pushed too far; it would not, for example, account1 for the difference in percentage unemployed at some point annually that stands out so clearly as between German and British printing, Hitze, Arbeiterfrage, passim.
22. Lande, Arbeitsverhaltnisse. 37% of all locksmiths, 29% of all turners, and 42% of all smiths were thus involved, the latter especially because of illness.
23. Theodor Leipert, Zur Lage der Arbeiter in Stuttgart (Stuttgart, 1900); Fanny Imle, Kritisches und Positives zur Frage der Arbeitslosenfursorge (Jena, 1907).
24. Imle, Kritisches; Der Arbeitsnachweiss in Deutschland, December 1913.
25. Korrespondent fur Deutschlands Buchdrucker und Schriftgiesser, 1908, passim.
26. 20% of a labor force averaging 12 weeks of joblessness would produce an overall unemployment rate of 3.2%.
27. Without meaning to flog a dead statistician, the German trade union studies, together with other investigations such as Lande, Arbeitsverhaltnisse, make something of a mockery of the officially listed rate during this period, even for skilled, unionized workers alone. The national rate simply cannot be derived from the union reports as published by the government. Thus in 1912, when the national rate was 2%, listed union rates in the government tables were: mines .1%, metals 5.7%, food 3.8%, printing 4.8%, transport 6.5%, textiles 2.7%, leather 7.2%, shoes 7.5%, wood 3.7%, and
bakers 16.5%. If these figures were weighted according to the size of the trade union group in each case, one might produce something like the official pattern, but it would be statistically valueless. There is no question that the official rate is up to 50% too low even in normal years. It would nonetheless remain below the British rate for skilled workers, because of the lower average duration of unemployment. Figures in printing were almost surely correct; in 1907 the 5.3% listed rate coincided with the percentage of union members listed as unemployed at some point, adjusted for average duration. But in 1906 evidence on skilled metal workers (33% unemployment at some point, of 2—4 weeks in Berlin) suggests unemployment of at least 2.2% when the state figure is .9%. Again, the suggestion would be to multiply most figures by two, for comparative purposes. The same probably holds for Belgium; while less information is available, urban rates ranging from 4% to 19% in years when the official rate was under 3.5% suggest some strange manipulations. Variez, Recensement; Statistisches Jahrbuch, 1899-1913.
28. Richard Calwer, Handel und Wandel in Deutschland, 1910.
29. Ministère du commerce, Résultats statistiques du recensement général de la population (1901) (Paris, 1904).
30. Variez, Recensement, passim.
31. Calwer, Handel, 1910.
32. The chemicals industry was apparently another haven, though information is scanty. The French censuses listed rated well under 1%, though later trade union returns suggest an increase after 1906.
33. L. Guérin, 'Les Industries textiles,' Musée social (1912), 179; Variez, Recensement, 13.
34. Amalgamated Society of Engineers, Monthly Reports, 1906; James B. Jefferys, The Story of the Engineers (London, 1946), passim.
35. Ministère du commerce, Office du Travail, Rapport sur l'Apprentissage dans les industries de l'ameublement (Paris, 1905), 531 ff.
36. Fédération française des travailleurs du livre, Compte-rendu du neuvième congrès nationalisons, 1905), 208.
37. Dearie, Problems, 36.
38. Fédération nationale du bâtiment, Les 9 heures dans le bâtiment (Paris, 1910), 3.
39. Archives de la Préfecture de police de la Seine, B/a 13 80. Report of 1905.
40. Sidney Pollard, A History of Labour in Sheffield (Liverpool, 1959), 202.
41. Dearie, Problems; Rowntree and Lasker, Unemployment, 62 ff.; Select Committee on Distress from Want of Employment, Report (London, 1896, HC 321), IV, 27.
42. Royal Commission on Labour, Minutes of the Evidence, Group 'B' (Transport by Water, Transport by Land) (London, 1892, C 6708), I, 292.
43. William Sewell, 'La classe ouvrière de Marseilles sous la Seconde République,' Mouvement social (1971), 27 ff., describes the exclusivism by which Marseilles dockers defended their jobs.
44. J. Izart, La Belgique au travail (Paris, 1910), passim.
45. G. Vaes, 'La Grève du port d'Anvers,' Revue sociale catholique (1907-8), 52.
46. Select Committee, Report, 27; Beveridge, Unemployment, 93.
47. André Sayous, Les Grèves de Marseilles en 1904 (Paris, 1904), 62.
48. Paul de Rousiers, Hambourg et l'Allemagne contemporaine (Paris, 1902), 249 ff.
49. William H. Beveridge, 'The Problem of the Unemployed,' Sociological Papers (1906), 323-45.
50. Society of Amalgamated Toolmakers, Monthly Journal, 1913.
51. Royal Commission, Minutes, I, 75.
52. London dockers in the 1911 transport strike reflected this problem in asking for three set times of call, at recognized places. Ben Tillett, History of the London Transport Workers' Strike (London, 1911), 14.
53. Carl Legien, Der Streik der Hafenarbeiter und Seeleute in Hamburg-Altona (Hamburg, 1897); see also Eleanor Rathbone, Report on the Results of the Special Inquiry into the Condition of LabouY at the Liverpool Docks (Liverpool, 1904), 20.
54. Léon de Seilhac, Les Unions mixtes des patrons et ouvriers (Paris, 1908), 51 ff.
55. Rathbone, Report, passim.
56. Niedersàchsiches Staatsarchiv (Hannover). Polizeiakten des Oberprâsidenten der Provinz Hannover (Hann. 122a XI), 70—72, rioting by workers, 1887—1908; Hauptstaatsarchiv Dùsseldorf, Zweigarchiv Kalkum, Regierung Dùsseldorf (Politische Akten), 15919, strikes by non-mining workers, 1899—1921.
57. German ports, for example, eliminated hiring for short stretches — as little as a half-hour — in favor of a half-day minimum, during the 1890s. Rousiers, Hambourg, 249 ff.
58. Hecht, Stûrungen, II, passim.
59. Ludwig Radloff, 'Die Lage der preussischer Eisenbahner,' Socialistische Monatshefte (1909), 1500 ff.
60. Adolf Levenstein, Proletariers Jugendjahre (Berlin, 1909), passim.
61. Rousiers, Hambourg, 249 ff.
62. Fritz Schuman, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Automobilindustrie (Leipzig, 1911), 118 ff.
63. Jefferys, Engineers, 156.
64. Martin Weigert, Arbeitsnachweis, Einigungsamt und Tarifgemeinschaft in Berliner Braugewerbe (Leipzig, 1907). A 1903 agreement set the percentage of unskilled workers who could be hired at 15—20%, and this was scaled down in a renegotiation
four years later.
65. Léon de Seilhac, Le Lock-out de Fougères (Paris, 1907), 104—5.
66. Albert Hùglin, Der Tarifvertrag zwischen Arbeitgeber und Arbeitnehmer (Stuttgart, 1906); A. Picart, 'Le Lock-out de la maçonnerie parisienne,' Musée social (1908), 70; Arthur Pugh, Men of Steel (London, 1951), 166 ff.
67. Jefferys, Engineers, passim.
68. Archives départmen tales, Seine-Maritime, Series M, Commerce et Industrie, report of 22 April 1910.
69. Korrespondent fur Deutschlands Buchdrucker und Schriftsgiesser, 29 December 1908, for a typical complaint; but 1880s unemployment rates had averaged 9%; Emanuel Baensch, Die Neuerungen in der Tarifgemeinschaft der deutschen Buchdrucker (Karlsruhe, 1908), 17.
70. National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives, Monthly Reports, 1892; Scottish Tinplate and Sheet Metal Workers' Friendly and Protective Society, Annual Report and Financial Statement, 1896-7.
71. Rowntree and Lasker, Unemployment, 62 ff.; Royal Commission on the Poor Laws, Minutes of Evidence (London, 1909, Cd. 4835), IV, 260.
72. Rowntree and Lasker, Unemployment, 224.
73. Der Arbeitsmarkt, February 1912; the study dealt with the unemployed in Munich.
74. Lande, Arbeitsverhaltnisse.
75. Peter N. Stearns, Revolutionary Syndicalism and French Labor (New Brunswick, 1971), 40.
76. Heinrich Reichelt, Die Arbeitsverhàltnisse in einem Berliner Gross-be trieb der Maschinenindustrie (Berlin, 1906), 51 ff.
CONCLUSION
Changes in the occupational structure, job choice, and the perception as well as the fact of unemployment constituted vital elements of the framework within which work took place. All suggest important distinctions in the working class, often but not always related. Occupational differences were crucial. Major industries displayed quite different levels of economic vitality. Most of the expanding sectors included many workers who evidenced some sense of job choice; opportunity and choice were obviously related. But expanding industries also drew in many lesser-skilled workers, including growing numbers of women, whose occupational commitment was often vague. And some of the stagnant industries, where a craft background was involved, could positively attract workers still. Obviously, sectors that were declining or barely holding their own normally evidenced high levels of unemployment; this was particularly true of the rural and small-town crafts. But some of the expanding industries were unstable as well. Construction was traditionally notorious in this regard, and it was difficult to see any noticeable improvement. Trades such as engineering and to an extent printing encountered unemployment difficulties for various reasons, but in part because of their attractiveness to new workers. They were vigorous, expanding industries still, but job choice could push more workers toward them than could be readily accommodated.
Occupational differences thus involve, even before we approach the work experience itself, a complicated set of factors. Craft-vs.-factory-vs.-unskilled remains an important tripartite division, but in the cities the craft-skilled factory lines had muddied somewhat as factory workers strove to take on some of the attributes of the artisans, as in the matter of job choice. The unskilled were more clearly discrete, but we have suggested that there was some increase in their job-specificity and even training (in terms of both on-the-job guidance and general educational background). Some halting limitations in their unemployment rates and some opportunities to rise to a definite semi-skilled level brought them more clearly within the basic framework of the working class. Within the tripartite division, other differentiations become obvious: high-unemployment vs. low-unemployment industrial settings
(metallurgy, for example, vs. metals or engineering); rapidly rising industrial populations vs. essentially stagnant (engineering vs. textiles); stable or rising artisanal vs. declining (printing vs. woodwork or leather). Similar distinctions probably existed among the unskilled, as dockers seem to have had more sense of choice, and possibly more clearly declining unemployment, than builders' laborers. Certainly in the crafts and in factory industry, at least a two-fold distinction between sectors with relatively rapid expansion and relatively high levels of job choice is essential.
Partially cutting across this analytical structure are other distinctions. In the crafts and to an extent in the factories, rural-small town vs. big city background and concentration prove consistently important. Sex differences are obviously vital, for the experience of men and women in a given industry differed widely, and certainly the working population as a whole was divided by sex. Age distinctions must also be borne in mind, though they remain difficult to trace precisely. Aging may have been undergoing a twofold process, from the occupational standpoint. Traditional havens such as domestic manufacturing, where workers were somewhat free to set their own pace, were either declining or becoming less palatable. This was clearly of overwhelming importance in countries like Germany and France where industrialization was just becoming fully established, though the virtues of domestic manufacturing should not be exaggerated. Within a more modern or simply more urban setting, the position of older workers may have been improving, at least so long as they could remain on the job. Work hierarchies settled in and could involve some attention to seniority.
In any event, a composite sense of the framework for work should combine the occupational distinctions based on factors of background, age, sex, and residence — a complicated combination but one that can to an extent be charted and, even for those accustomed to finding or wanting their social history relatively simple, not necessarily more cumbersome than the pattern of political factions farther up in society during the same period.
But the temptation to generalization will remain, and a few impressions do stand out from a consideration of the environment for labor. A maturation of the working class is obvious. Fewer outright newcomers were entering the class, an attachment of family to work had developed even in factory settings, and a sense of choosing a job — which meant to some extent orienting oneself within an industrial environment — had spread reasonably widely. Yet maturation
contained some important ambiguities. We have seen that job choice, industrial growth, and employment stability could conflict. Workers could want jobs that were decreasing in economic viability. They could want jobs that were growing rapidly in number but still exposed to massive fluctuations in employment. Both of these clashes could severely reduce the sense of satisfaction enjoyed once on the job.
More generally, the working-class culture that had matured was in important senses conservative. This followed from the continuing ties that segments of the class retained with the countryside, and even more from the contributions of artisanal origins and values. The kind of links that developed between family and work enhanced a conservative approach as well, for a job increasingly was something to be passed along. Conservatism made sense as well when the expansion of opportunities was beginning to shrink. Artisans and textile workers could perceive the slowing of industrial growth directly. So could women in the traditional concentrations, and older workers generally; and these groups were vital in passing job values along to the newer generations. In the expanding industries a defensive mentality could also be produced from the advent both of new numbers and of new kinds of workers — new nationalities, new youth, and possibly more women. Of course some workers, particularly the younger ones, were open to new goals; we have seen signs of this in the periodic defiance of parental direction, when young people entered better-paying industries instead of, waiting for traditional training. But, increasingly, one wonders if many of the most venturesome young workers might more likely have left the class altogether, to enter more rapidly-growing middle-class ranks. To the extent to which this occurred, the conservatism of the working class would only be heightened.
Conservatism may seem too loaded or rigid a term. It is not meant to cover the whole of working-class values; its relationship with obviously radical politics will be explored subsequently. It is certainly not meant in a patronizing sense; most people are in some sense conservative about their jobs or prospective jobs. Nor, finally, should rigidity be over-stressed. The diversity already noted qualifies any sense of a general job conservatism. Workers would still respond differentially to change, and certain kinds of innovation could have obvious appeal. Nevertheless, the contrast with the middle class, when also taken as a whole, was becoming clearer. In the early stages of the industrial revolution the middle class, in its numerical majority, had massive ties to the older order; only the minority was eagerly innovative. Workers, except for the craft elite, were subjected willy-nilly to novelty. Now it
was the working class that was expanding only slowly, open to fewer newcomers than the middle class. Key sectors of the class, beyond the rural-artisanal remnants, which themselves still loomed large, were beginning to close their ranks, some sensing the curtailment of opportunities that would soon lead to absolute decline in several of the leading industries of the early industrial revolution. And the working class had painfully constructed a culture that, reflecting their inability to control their own lot, would protect them against undue change and perhaps provide greater respectability in the relevant society. Defense of job traditions was a major part of this culture, but it increasingly extended to sexual behavior and other matters as well.
The potential clash between working-class culture and its economic setting is already obvious in the contrast between the motivations for job choice, where these could be articulated, and the actual growth patterns of the occupational structure. Change was essential. Parental guidance had to be flexible or to be partially ignored. The sense of job values would be even more severely challenged by changes in the work-place itself, particularly of course in those industries that were expanding most rapidly. For technological and organizational developments were advancing at a rising pace. Workers who had chosen their jobs because of traditional prestige or parental guidance could easily be disappointed. Those who were increasingly conscious that job instability could and should be avoided might feel newly threatened. This does not mean that an anticipation of clash should dominate the consideration of the juxtaposition of actual work situations with working-class values. The values had already proved adaptable. And the class, precisely because it had a work culture, could influence if not deflect the new forces impinging upon it. Obviously, its culture could provide the basis for protest as well.
Part II FORCES FOR CHANGE
CHAPTER 4 TECHNOLOGY
To the extent that workers assigned clear values to work, their culture would be severely tested in the decades immediately before World War I. Three factors demand special attention: technological developments, the new scale of business organization, and the drive for a higher pace of work. All were interrelated, so that in final analysis the assess ment of work must be made against a varied background of change. But each factor can be considered in some isolation, and each illuminates certain aspects of the work experience. For we are concerned, not with the details of inventions or corporate structure, but with the impact on work and on workers' thinking about their jobs.
With an approach to work that was in essential respects conservative, the labor force might be expected to react harshly to what was unquestionably an important new round of technological change. In fact the reactions were subtle, often indirect. They varied with some of the simplest divisions within the working class. Artisans whose skills were threatened lamented loudly, but where their industries were in decline they were powerless to react directly. Perhaps they had been expecting the blow for too long, and were disillusioned by the failure of earlier efforts to confront the industrial wave directly. In some cases, at least, they found refuge in political movements that, in their eyes, seemed to promise a return to an older order. Direct conflict was rare. This was not the case with important groups of unskilled workers, whose growing numbers gave them a sense of strength and who were lacing technological change for the first time. Significant if scattered clashes resulted, for machines were part of the process forcing unskilled workers to rethink their jobs. In the factories, finally, reaction to machines varied with the vitality of the industry and the system under which technological changes were introduced. But on the whole factory workers were least upset by change in this area, if only because of their long experience with the process. Previous exposure to machines, rather than the scale of technology, seemed to determine response. Hence sweeping generalizations on the dehumanizing effect of advancing mechanization would be out of place. Some workers even found new interest in the jobs produced by technological change. Yet there was human cost involved, and one must wonder if acquiescence was not
mainly the product of a sense of helplessness, a belief that this aspect of the job was out of control.
The outlines of technological change can be quickly sketched, for they are familiar in many respects. We have already suggested that the process of change took on some distinctive contours towards the 1890s, for innovation was more spurt-like than continuous and, on the whole, one can view the turn-of-the-century period as the second peaking of a new technology, less radical certainly than the first, early industrial incursion but a significant break with the pace of change in the 1870s and 1880s. Of course this periodization is not equally valid for all industries. The process of speed-up in British textiles, for example, began in the 1870s with the introduction of multiple looms; we pick up only the tail end of the process in the 1890s, and this will prove significant in assessing workers' reactions. Relatedly, the pace of change was greater in the less completely industrialized areas than in established leaders such as Britain. French use of steam engines, for example, doubled in the 1890s and then doubled again between 1900 and 1913; in 1902, 58,700 establishments had steam power, averaging 34.00 horsepower per firm, while in 1912, 63,000 companies averaged 51.3 horsepower. Innovation in Britain or Belgium was much more modest. But there is nevertheless an air of novelty to the 1890s overall, even in Britain. Two main developments can be discerned: the spread of new equipment to branches of manufacturing and goods handling previously untouched by this aspect of the industrial revolution; and the introduction of a new generation of equipment, far more automatic than its early industrial ancestors, to factory production.
The spread of gasoline motors literally revolutionized any work involving the lifting and hauling of materials. Cranes were introduced to all major docks. New stoking machines affected gas workers. Loading devices also gained ground in metallurgy. Hundreds of thousands of workers, who had only their backs and arms to sell, were touched by equipment of this sort.1
The construction industry was naturally affected by the advent of cranes. Stones and to a lesser extent bricks were no longer lifted by hand. This was an industry that also exemplified the spread of machines into traditional artisanal preserves. Masons and stone-cutters now had machines to cut stones; simultaneously, in that odd accommodation of taste to equipment that has long characterized industrial society, the use of highly ornamented facades receded, so that many types of stone cutting were abandoned outright. French masons complained that even funeral monuments were being turned out in preformed concrete. But
actually carpenters and joiners were more seriously affected by new machines and materials. Some mechanical saws were introduced in woodwork, though mainly in lumbering rather than construction per se. More serious was the growing use of prefabricated wood units and, especially, iron and concrete for buildings. Here was an opportunity for new specialists, and iron carpenters became an important segment of the industry; but many traditional craftsmen could only feel that their trade was declining. The use of asphalt instead of lead and tile affected roofers, and plumbers had new methods to learn as earthware replaced lead piping in sewers. Obviously changes in materials were unlikely to have as radical an effect on skill levels as new equipment, and the construction industry was disrupted rather than transformed. It is also true that changes occurred differentially by area. German and Belgian construction yielded to new methods far more slowly then French or British. And while French masonry and carpentry were touched, roofing, in contrast to Britain, was not.2
Artisanal manufacturing was another story, for here a radical transformation did take place. Throughout industrial Europe the 1890s was a decade of displacement for one rural craft after another. Button machinery spread in France after 1895, while machines to manufacture hats gained ground even earlier. Glass bottling was revolutionized, as new equipment allowed four workers to do the work of 75. In Germany, these devices spread after 1900, though there were only seventeen in the whole country by 1910. Here the slowness of change limited outright disruption, but a traditional trade was being slowly wiped out nevertheless. In leather new equipment was developed, again after 1900, to shave the hair and flesh from skins. The list of trades affected could be expanded almost indefinitely. It was true that the small size of initial units in these craft industries delayed the widespread adoption of new equipment in many cases.3 Power-driven saws and lathes could transform woodwork, for example, and new furniture factories sprang up to apply these devices on a large scale. But still, in Germany in 1904, 82 percent of all companies employing workers in this industry had no power equipment at all, and only 6 percent of these had even hand-foot devices. In Berlin lock manufacture the German lag in artisanal technology was notable even in the cities — the number of companies with motors more than doubled between 1895 and 1907, but from 8 percent to only 17 percent of the total. Even where new machines were employed, the advent of internal combustion and electrical motors could give a new lease of life to otherwise traditional forms of manufacture. The tenacity of home
production in the French clothing industry and the rapid rise of companies employing less than five workers after 1896 was due to the possibility of disseminating new sources of power to operate sewing machines. But where machines existed factories were rarely far behind; in lingerie, for example, home production was almost dead by 1900. And while the gradual character of technological change in several industries must be emphasized, their employees could hardly fail to realize that they were under the gun; in some cases a swift death might have been preferable to the agony of most of the traditional rural crafts.4
On the Continent and to an extent in England (where the process had begun earlier) the 1890s saw displacement of most hand manufacture of shoes. The number of hand workers in the German shoe industry, for example, over half the total in 1895, had declined by over 40 percent a decade later. Heeling and finishing machinery spread in the 1890s, while lasting equipment, to nail the parts of the shoe automatically, came in around 1900. And in this industry workers barely had time to adjust to the advent of factories and powered equipment when larger, more fully automated equipment was introduced in the leading plants, most of it imported or copied from the United States.5
Textiles, though of course a factory industry for many decades, also found itself opened to new equipment, again often of American origin. Here a distinction must be made between British cotton and the Continental textile industry, with British wool following the patterns of the latter. British cotton was substantially more mechanized then French and especially German. The German spinner operated fewer spindles, the weaver fewer looms; many French and German weavers in fact ran only a single loom, and few operated more than two; while in Britain the norm was four. German equipment ran at least ten percent more slowly than British as well and, in far worse repair, it operated only 80 percent of the working day in contrast to Britain's 92—95 percent.6 Hence the most advanced techniques possible in the industry were not the main issue except in Britain. New looms such as the Northropp, which greatly increased the automation of the weaving process by recharging the shuttle with weft if the thread broken ran out and allowed a given worker to run twenty or more looms simultaneously — for a given loom could run untended for two hours — spread in British cotton to a limited extent and, by 1910, they were beginning to receive some attention in France. Even in England the Northropp was more talked about and feared than actually
introduced. In Germany, France, and in the British wool industry the kind of technological change that affected most workers was the steady pressure to adopt two looms instead of one, or three instead of two. Simple multiplication suggests that, if this did not constitute a dramatic improvement in technique, the potential impact on work and on output could be considerable. Concomitantly the amount of new horsepower being applied to the industry rose steadily, in France more than doubling the resources of the industry between 1899 and 1908 (when the process began to slow).7
Heavy industry was subjected to less change. Electrical equipment spread in German metallurgy after 1900, and this helped allow a 50 percent expansion in the size of blast furnaces between 1895 and 1913. Everywhere new machinery plus the increased use of Bessemer or open hearth methods displaced traditional metallurgical skills such as puddling.8 Coal-cutting machines were introduced first in the 1890s, but they made surprisingly slow headway. By 1913 8 percent of British coal, 10 percent of Belgian, but only 2 percent of German was cut by machines. In Germany the spread of steam engines and even horses for hauling coal affected production more seriously.9 Finally, on the railroads the development of larger engines and freight cars seriously affected the nature of work, for the capacity of train engines doubled in the decade after 1895.10
Of all the traditional factory industries, the manufacture of machinery was most seriously transformed by the new generation of equipment. More specialized lathes accomplished a number of cuts at once, making this process more automatic. Milling machines displaced the chisel-and-file work of the fitters, while grinding machines relieved turners of hand labor with emery tools. Mechanical drills and borers created new skills, or semi-skills, while in shipbuilding the spread of iron ships was accompanied, thanks to new machines, by the creation of teams of riveters and platers. By no means were all traditional skills threatened; fitters, for example, lost some types of work but gained new jobs manufacturing special tools. But the way was clearly open to semi-skilled workers, as both 'handymen' and women gained increasing ground in the industry. Furthermore, for all workers, the use of new steel in machines and the growing application of electric power (by 1914 commanding 14 percent of British machine production) allowed a massive increase in the speed of the equipment generally, in old processes as well as new. For many workers, this industry, like printing where the automatic composing machine massively heightened per worker productivity, became almost unrecognizable within a twenty-
year span.11
The initial introduction of powered equipment in many industries, the growing conversion to automatic processes in others where, after the initial introduction of power, the technical base had remained rather low added up to a substantial increase in the potential productivity of the manufacturing sector and a significant transformation of the conditions of work. And, as suggested for several major industries, the knowledge that processes still more advanced than those actually in use were available heightened the fears and uncertainties of many workers. Hence, if often with some exaggeration, workers themselves voiced the sense that they lived in a new technological age; the refrain, 'never before,' was re-echoed in many industries.
For unskilled workers the whole machine experience was new, yet unlike earlier factory workers few of them operated machinery directly. They lifted and hauled still, but for shorter distances and more rarely up and down stairs and ladders. Some few were trained as crane operators, but for most the nature of work itself seemed to change little. Small wonder, then, that many saw machines primarily as a threat, a real or potential creator of unemployment. A few might add that machines made work more intense, by making workers responsible for stacking, loading and handling more goods arriving at more regular intervals; this was a complaint of British warehousemen in 1896. The spread of steam ships angered many sailors, who felt that the ship had become less their own and who specifically noted that their rise to officer levels was now blocked by a new class of heaters, who came from various backgrounds instead of the traditional sources of the merchant marine.12 But generally the fear for jobs was overwhelming, in a period when the ranks of the unskilled continued to increase rapidly. Rouen dockworkers, for example, noted that employers drastically reduced work crews whenever a crane was introduced. Small wonder that refusals to work with the new equipment or outright Luddism were reported widely among the unskilled; this was in fact the only group likely to attack machinery directly during a labor dispute. In 1912 dockers in Swansea refused to work on an electric-magnetic loader, until prevailed upon in lengthy negotiations by their own union organizer.13 Construction workers in Dortmund threw sand in a crane in a 1900 dispute; Le Havre dockers pushed cranes into the ocean on at least two occasions; unskilled loaders in Lorraine metallurgy destroyed machinery in the 1906 strike. Belgian grain loaders, threatened by the spread of grain elevators, burned one of the structures in 1907.14
Scattered incidents, to be sure; this was not a characteristic response and the fear of displacement could inhibit violent action as much as it encouraged it. But violence was undoubtedly the tip of an iceberg, for machines caused or enhanced a massive sense of job insecurity among the unskilled. Sardine sorters in Britanny, many of them women and few formally trained, fought sorting equipment for ten years, at one point proclaiming, 'There is nothing left for us except the General Strike if they try to impose the machine on us.' And here we get one of the rare insights into the sense of commitment that even workers we must rate as unskilled could develop for their jobs. Fear of unemployment loomed large in Britanny, and it was certainly realistic, but the machine was resented also because it reduced the human element of work: 'The machine will never manage to do as well as we do.'15
Objectively, many unskilled workers stood to benefit by new equipment. Physical strain was reduced for many, and on the docks, if not so regularly in construction work, the increase in work to be done — the massive regular growth in tonnage handled, for example - limited the threat of greater unemployment. In fact, we have suggested that unemployment probably declined among this group. Machinery did not cause the decline, but it could promote a regularity of work that was a logical concomitant. German dockers, for example, found the work adjustments induced by investment in capital equipment helped the development of a more stable work-force, limiting the oscillation between short bouts of intense work followed by unemployment. Some also benefited from the substitution of daily pay for the piece rate which had characterized hand work, for they had often been cheated by sub-contractors when paid by the task. Yet all of this is a view from the outside. The unskilled were not normally articulate as yet. They could fear displacement even when it did not occur; they could resent changes in work habits that might otherwise be judged an element of stability. The unskilled did not rise in massive protest against machinery, and since they did express other grievances more vigorously we might assume that most decided they could live with the new equipment, once the fears accompanying the actual introduction of a powered machine died down. All we can be sure of is that they were given little choice; like the more massive Luddite protests of an earlier day, efforts by the unskilled to impede mechanization came to naught. The Breton sardine workers who refused to operate new equipment were simply replaced, sometimes by children. It was no more difficult to find dockers or construction laborers to work alongside the cranes, whatever their views on the
subject.16
Artisans who saw not only their own jobs but their whole profession being lost were more consistent in their complaints, but of course no more effective. British cabinet-makers proclaimed the downfall of their trade: with machines, apprenticeship was abandoned and boys and Jews were brought in to do the work of Englishmen. Bricklayers correctly noted that the use of steel and concrete threatened their livelihood — buildings were going up in 'half the time' with a third of the traditional number of bricklayers — and so they constantly talked about the need to 'sustain customs' on the job. British construction workers generally blamed their unemployment on the competition of machine-made building materials.17 But here, far more clearly than with the unskilled, more was involved than the threat to jobs. A French carpenter put it this way: 'With the development of industry, the worker is becoming more and more the complement of a machine. No one wants a "good artisan" any more, no one needs one.'18 And many French builders used strikes to point out the shoddy materials and sloppy methods their employers had adopted. A glass worker who refused to work on new machinery whose expense forced the establishment of a night shift noted: 'I see no need, for £4 a month, for me or my children to give up our sleep at night or our liberty.'19 Lock-workers from the Black Country to Berlin fought factory-made locks. A German blasted machine work as the death of art and creativity, claiming that only unskilled workers were stupid enough to endure the machines at all — and even they would find no joy in them, for independent hand work alone offered satisfaction.20
Shoe and leather workers had obvious verbal battles to fight. Introduction of leather-cutting equipment, and unskilled workers to man it, caused craftsmen in Germany to complain of the monotony and tension of machine labor; they particularly lamented the noise, for they could no longer talk to each other: 'When there's good talk along with it, then the work flows gaily along.'21 Birmingham shoe workers in 1893 tried, like so many artisans, to point out that machines did not do as good work as hand labor, and 'a class of the workers are dispensed with in consequence.'22 A Parisian worker was more direct, claiming that 'the machine had killed the trade.' 'If I want the revolution, it's not to do any harm to people but to be able to destroy all these machines.'23
Only one type of artisan was prepared positively to praise the new technology, and this rarely. Home workers might rejoice in the ability sewing machines gave them to stay out of the factories for another
generation. A German rug weaver welcomed the advent of electricity: 'As opposed to work in a velvet factory in Crefeld it's a good exchange.'24
Otherwise the fear of losing one's job or the actual experience of having to transfer to machine labor soured the working lives of countless artisans. Yet, in industries like shoe manufacture, the advance of machinery was inexorable. Wages for hand work fell and periods of unemployment became unconscionably long; many workers had to give up.25 Neither respectful complaints nor revolutionary appeals dented the process. And where this occurred the workers' resentment could be tragically counter-productive. A German union leader noted that the accident rate in the wood industry was almost twice as high on machine as in hand work, a differential he claimed was due as much to the feeling of stress as to actual physical danger.26 Quite possibly many unskilled workers were better adapted to machinery in the newly-converted industries than were trained artisans; certainly it is small wonder that many older craftsmen held out in non-mechanized work, even as their wages fell. How many workers were forced, in mid-career, to shift to a machine we do not know; nor can we do more than speculate about possible resentments which even a teenager fro m a craft background might bring to the machine. There is no question that, in all the industries faced with rapid conversion, the attitude of the established workers was suspicious if not positively hostile — and because of the new scope of technological change this involved a large minority of the whole labor force.
Yet in trades where skills were not actually being extinguished and where growth still occurred, so that a lesser-skilled element could be accommodated without outright displacement, despair was not predominant and some adaptation was possible. Most construction workers did not find their work profoundly altered, and they could fight for their jobs. In Britain the incessant demarcation disputes that developed in the industry represented an attempt to fight on traditional lines; union leaders found it difficult to deal with new processes, insisting that their men should do the work they had always done. The result was the stagnation of union membership and, possibly, an unnecessary shrinkage of the traditional skilled groups as a percentage of the whole. On the Continent, where construction unions were newer and their leaders more radical, the intrusion of new technology less severely limited the growth of skilled categories; French carpenters, for example, might complain about the development of iron work but they organized with their fellow specialists. And, by including unskilled
labor, Continental builders reduced the sense of threat from that direction. We have noted also that in Germany and Belgium, at least, they were not faced with such rapid technological change in the first place.27
Crafts that were more fully mechanized could adapt as well. Grumbling undoubtedly persisted, but if the threat of unemployment was not too great signs of adjustment soon developed. Bakers in Marseilles struck in 1907 when the number of mechanical kneaders spread, not against the machines themselves (which after all lightened their work) but over the rates they were to be paid on them, British glassblowers sometimes talked as if they were ready to resist machines root and branch, but in fact they strove to apply craft procedures to the machines, by limiting access to mechanical training to their own sons; in one case they refused even to let their employer's son learn the trade. Dyers in Saint-Etienne, deciding against frontal resistance to new machines, insisted instead on specifying a large work crew for each machine. The result was a violent strike in which workers who had consented to serve on small crews were attacked; but ultimately an accommodation was reached which minimized the chance of-displacement. German brewers admitted that new machines improved their lot somewhat, for refrigeration permitted production the year round whereas traditionally no malt work could be done during the summer. So they worked for agreements to limit the number of unskilled workers who could be trained on the new machines while seeking reductions in the hours of work and annual vacations — the latter a clear effort to retain, in new guise, something of a traditional break.
In other words few artisans in fields like food processing or construction even thought about acting on a rooted hostility to machines. How much the experience of machines actually bothered them we cannot pretend to determine, but at the worst they were so intimidated by decades of advancing industrialization that they lacked the will to stand their ground. Quite possibly the five hundred Saint-Etienne dyers who threw stones at their colleagues' houses would really have preferred to break the machines directly. But in many job categories the actual displacement of workers - as opposed to intergenerational change — was sufficiently slight and the preservation of a recognizable skill level sufficiently great to make adjustment something more than a pis aller.
This phenomenon can be traced in unusual detail for printers, whose trade encouraged written records. The advent of the composing machine was a severe threat to traditional skills. The number of women
and other semi-skilled workers in the industry actually advanced more rapidly than in many other crafts. It is true that printing had already been partially transformed toward mechanization and large-shop, if not factory, organization. Furthermore the composing machine did not eliminate the need for skills, and one historian has suggeste d that this makes the printers' case unique.29 But the great possibility of using unskilled workers and the obvious preservation of recognizable skills elsewhere indicate that this is not an unusual case. Printers were frightened by the new machines. Their unions discussed them at every congress. But everywhere they opted for adaptation, and in so doing they were able to influence, if not control, the course of mechanization. Their example cannot be generalized too far, but it serves some purpose in illustrating the position of the modernized artisanry generally.
Despite their relatively privileged position as a high-paying, expanding trade, printers were seriously tempted to resist machines directly. Unquestionably their antagonism was greater before the fact; anticipation was worse than reality. Some claimed massive unemployment was inevitable. The British typographers' union noted in 1901 that its members had initially feared the disappearance of compositors, but came to realize that conditions actually improved.30 From France: 'Mechanization pitilessly increases the amount of unemployment, and engenders misery.'31 There were claims that mechanization increased nervous exhaustion at work: 'fast-running machinery .. . caused greater mental and physical strain;'32 but it was admitted that this statement, offered in British negotiations over conditions on a Monotype machine, was partly for effect, and that the real goal was an arrangement that would minimize unemployment. Concern about dilution of skill was also expressed. 'The real typographer should be able to judge the engraving ... correct its faults, verify the work and give to the whole an impression of beauty, of perfection that the composing machines will never attain.' Followed brutally by: 'There are two irreconcilable things ... the perfection of the type and speed.'33 Several strikes occurred against the introduction of new equipment. Lille printers hissed and jostled some of their number who were working a new machine, while also hissing the plant director; printers in Toul fought a union directive that they accept the machines and simply negotiate conditions of their work.34 German printers summed up the whole impulse: 'The composing machines must all be tossed on the junk heap.'35
But this was not the position taken. All the printers' unions
recognized the inevitability of new mechanization, and this helped reduce overt hostility. Workers themselves were able to realize some of their objections in the conditions normally imposed over the machines' use. Training was controlled both to limit new entry to the profession and to maintain traditional skills. Hence a variety of regional and national agreements, in all the industrial countries, reduced the number of apprentices allowed per worker (cutting it by half in Germany, for example, while in London the daily newspapers were forbidden from taking apprentices at all and no apprentice could do machine work until after three years of manual training). Everywhere employers were forbidden to train apprentices just on machines.36 Efforts to reduce hours of work were undertaken with a special eye to the unemployment problem. A poster in Brussels justified a reduction demand as designed 'to attenuate as much as possible that crisis that the inevitable introduction of the composing machine will create.'37 And printers could be tenacious on insisting on nine, even eight hours of work because of their concern over this issue, more than once rejecting compromise proposals.38 There were also some informal efforts to reduce the pace of work on the job; in 1901 English printers were accused of ca'canny on the new presses.39 German unions fought, without much success, to abolish production minimums; the French union accepted them in collective bargaining agreements (agreeing to 3000 letters per hour).40 Concern about undue production does not seem to have been widespread, once machines were actually in operation. Far more important, and ultimately the basis for acceptance of the machines, was the insistence that machine work be paid more than hand. From France: in insisting on a raise printers 'wanted mechanization, that killer of hand labor, to be not an instrument of misery but one of liberation; they wanted its intrusion less violent and its employment more remunerative.'41 From England, in asking for a 10 percent minimum advantage: 'machines being an innovation should be treated as such.. . and [made] as costly as possible to the introducers.'42 German agreements set the rate at 25 percent above the minimum for hand wages; Belgian did much the same.
Obviously agreements of this sort at least mitigated the anticipated effects of mechanization. And to an indeterminate degree the strong union approach slowed the process outright, by making it quite expensive; this undoubtedly played a role in the lagging mechanization of German and Belgian printing. Unemployment remained a problem, but no greater than before; the industry still expanded moderately. Admittedly printers, with their special union tradition and special
economic setting, achieved gains that many other workers could not. Their situation contrasts, for example, with that of German bottle-makers; here, machines actually improved health conditions, and they did not result in massive dismissals because employers agreed among themselves on a gradual approach and because the machines continued to require skill. But workers generally felt harmed by mechanization, perhaps fearing more unemployment for the future, given the immense productivity of the new machines, but even more obviously because their weak unions were given no voice in setting conditions at all.43 A sense of control, then, undoubtedly enhanced the printers' adaptation. But their willingness to accept machines, however reluctantly and with important conditions, was probably not distinctive in any industry not threatened with extinction. Here the subsequent experience of printers actually on the machines was particularly informative.
There were some reports of nervousness on the job, but these came mainly early in the period, from Germany where the theme of nervousness was particularly common.44 Once the machines were installed complaining came mainly from hand compositors, who resented the competition. British printers criticized their brethren on the machines for their high wages and their desire to go at a piece rate to earn still more. Machine work itself was not unpleasant. Workers reported less satisfaction with the skill involved, although some claimed that working with two hands instead of one proved something of a challenge. A few noted that machine work was too specialized, in that they could not see a whole manuscript through; but others found it interesting to deal with more materials, of greater diversity. Certainly they did not regard themselves as ordinary workers. And they had no desire to go back to hand composing; they admitted they were out of practice, but also mentioned their positive satisfaction with shorter hours and higher earnings.45
The example of printers, then, suggests not only that in certain circumstances workers in the craft tradition would win some sense of control over the mechanization process but that they could maintain some pleasure in work. Certainly the biggest objections to the process came from those anticipating it or still outside it. But in this instance new machines also pushed workers toward a more instrumental view of their job; intrinsic satisfactions remained, but at a reduced level, and the advantages of the work were partly defined in terms of benefits off the job.
In so far as many factory workers developed or imported reasons for choosing their jobs that were quite similar to those of artisans, it is not
surprising that their reactions to machinery harbored many of the same ambiguities. But with some important exceptions the shock was less great and the fear of displacement less widespread. In certain situations workers could find positive advantages in increased levels of mechanization, because of previous adaptation to technical change and special features of their industry. A historian of the British pottery industry has characterized the workers' reaction to new levels of mechanization, with attendant introduction of semi-skilled (often female) workers, as one of 'grumbling acceptance,' and it will be hard to improve on this judgement overall.46
Complaints abounded, of course. Shoe workers were particularly vulnerable, because many had worked in artisanal shops before and were actually new to machines of any sort. So they criticized the noise and vibration of larger machines, while fearing that the new technology plus the introduction of unskilled labor would create massive unemployment.47 Shoe workers in Nancy touched on this latter threat in asking for a reduction of hours in 1913: 'The intense development of mechanization in our industry has led to an unheard-of increase in production.'48 There were accusations in Britain that workers went slow on the machines, to limit production, leading employers to oppose a piece rate and the union to strive for 'quantities statements' specifying the type and amount of work each category of worker could do. In the craft tradition the British union also tried to set ratios of apprentice to adult labor, to limit displacement. Indeed in the early 1890s the union had to prod its members to work on the machines at all, lest outsiders take their work away.49 Generally, however, shoe workers issued few explicit condemnations of mechanization once they were in the factories; their ire was more likely to be directed against the persistence of home workers, which suggests that they had quickly come to find mechanized work appropriate. Like the printers their concern was to win appropriate rates for work on the new machines. A strike in a Paris factory, when a new heel machine was introduced, said nothing against the equipment; it was directed at a resultant reduction in the piece rate, which workers said lowered their pay. Fougères cutters, stirred by the rumored arrival of new cutting presses, reacted only by insisting on a special rate.50
Ironically, this kind of adaptation did not prevail so quickly in the textile industry; but here we can penetrate a bit further into the reasons for worker resistance. Right up to World War I textile workers on the Continent opposed the introduction of multiple looms. In Venders they were unanimous against two looms, claiming that every time they had
tried two looms the employers exploited them and unemployment resulted. Hence weavers quit companies that enforced two looms whenever they could, and a major strike resulted over the issue, forcing the employers to back down. German weavers complained about fatigue on the machine, along with the glare from bright lights. The great Crimmitschau strike resulted from a 60 percent increase in machine speed, which harmed worker health and produced insistence on a shorter work-day. German workers widely claimed that the introduction of multiple looms increased physical effort to traditional manual levels, so overt resistance was not surprising. Strikes in Monchen-Gladbach and elsewhere opposed the introduction of two looms.5l And such strikes were endemic in France. Twelve thousand Cholet weavers struck when multiple looms were introduced, saying 'the profit will be for our exploiters and the fatigue for us.'52 Workers in Hazebrouck struck against new looms, citing existing unemployment in the area and the overwork and accidents that resulted from new machines. Here, deterioration in the quality of product was mentioned as well, for the worker could no longer watch over the entire production process. Roanne weavers agreed to experiment with a higher number of looms, but refused to accept the new level or even repeat the experiment with higher wages (the vote was 2434 to 67). Arrnentières weavers successfully insisted as late as 1913 that a two-loom system would be exceptional.53 Finally, although union policy favored accepting multiple looms so long as pay was maintained (as indeed was the case in France) several strikes by wool workers in Britain opposed the very introduction of multiple looms.54
Yet the problem in all these cases was not the principle of technical change itself, for these workers were accustomed to machines and could see some benefits in them under proper circumstances. The only complaints against the whole idea of multiple looms came from some older workers, who did not think they could handle them. Even the fear of unemployment did not come too often. Arrnentières weavers, to be sure, were concerned about the effect of two looms on their sons' opportunities, for apprenticeship would be limited. Hence they won an agreement in 1907 that gave the employers only 10 percent savings in labor costs on the second loom while protecting their older single loom rates. Concern for familial employment was undoubtedly involved in other cases even if not directly expressed. Spinners were thus less successfully concerned about technical change than weavers because their incomes, as wives and children of male workers, were supplementary and their jobs not so important to the family economy.
But two other related factors more generally explain the cases of opposition. New machinery in textiles meant new piece rates, and it was easy to feel cheated (whether this was true or not). Hence the pervasive notion that employers pocketed the whole profit. Even more important was the poor quality of machinery and materials that Continental manufacturers typically provided. Weavers in Ourscamp, refusing to work on three looms, explicitly noted the inadequacy of the machines which, unlike equipment they knew of elsewhere, did not stop automatically when the thread broke. Machines of this sort meant more work and effectively less pay, for production could not increase as much as employers claimed in restructuring the piece rates.55 And the invocations of greater physical strain and damage to health have to be taken seriously. A letter from a Verviers worker urged manufacturers to perfect their equipment instead of burdening the worker; for if they provided American-style machines workers would do ten looms without complaint. But as it was, 'the intensity of the work is abnormal, disproportionate to the vital energy of a man.'56
Textile workers thus had a traditional basis for assessing what machinery should accomplish. Often in poor health, sometimes, as in Germany, new to the industry, they may have been unusually sensitive to physical strain. But machinery itself was not an issue. Hence, even on the Continent, the opposition to multiple looms had no echo in spinning, where equipment was also changing rapidly. The main reason was simple: there was no way to increase the number of spindles a worker operated without improving the equipment substantially, and the pressure on piece rates was far less severe. A more dramatic contrast results from an examination of British cotton weaving, where multiple looms were accepted readily. Larger companies, with more capital and technical experience and a stronger union structure prevented most of the difficulties that developed on the Continent. There was some fear of unemployment by the 1890s —and indeed levels in the industry were at least as great as across the Channel. And workers' technological openness was not indefinite; the initial introductions of Northropp looms resulted in several strikes, and the workers insisted on a ten-loom limit and a reduction in machine speed lest they be overtired. Employers claimed that the workers slowed up on the machines; workers said that the coarseness of materials provided caused inadequate production and hence inadequate pay.57 But generally British cotton workers were not only receptive to more mechanization but could even insist upon it, and the problems with the Northropp loom resulted primarily from the pay rates offered. Multiple looms
were accepted early, and the textile unions were quite willing to reduce piece rates in response: 'our object being to see that the amount of labor performed by our Members is not increased, nor their wages reduced.'58 Oldham spinners saw that Bolton workers gained, from the introduction of bigger mules, and agreements in spinning normally specified that manufacturers could not reduce the number of spindles per worker below a certain figure. Piece rates were generally set so that workers believed that they won half the benefit of any technical improvement, while a daily wage minimum was deliberately designed to encourage the manufacturers to introduce new and larger machines since they would be obligated to pay a set amount to each worker regardless of machine size.59 A far cry, obviously, from the situation of Continental weavers. Yet while admitting the greater industrial experience and probably better health of British cotton workers, it is obvious that their reasoning did not really differ from that of their Continental counterparts. Machines were fine if they lightened labor and produced some wage benefits for the workers.
The final modern industry that developed significant resistance to new levels of mechanization was, ironically, machine building itself. Here the anguish could resemble that of the artisanal trades, for the good reason that many of the workers were former artisans or, as in Britain, had developed a craftman's stake in their skills. From a letter to the Amalgamated Society of Engineers in 1900: 'Wherever automatic machinery is introduced we find that craftsmanship becomes a thing of the past, [and] cheap labour is introduced.'60 From an unemployed iron moulder: 'It almost makes me tremble for the future, especially those of us who refuse to be hoodwinked to the tune of "better times."'61 And many British workers refused to operate new equipment, claiming it was beneath their dignity. Some tried to go slow on machines, preferring to try to protect their jobs to winning higher pay. Far more refused to train unskilled workers, barred them from the union, and demanded that all machine jobs go to traditionally-skilled labor. As often noted, a host of demarcation disputes resulted, particularly in shipbuilding.62 A nine-month strike in Hull fought for the general principle that 'machines which supersede hand-skilled labour should be manipulated by skilled and full-paid men.'63
Some similar sentiments could be found on the Continent. A skilled metal worker in Germany proclaimed his resistance to machine work, saying he preferred to earn lower wages: 'I will not be degraded to a machine.'64 Shipbuilders noted that mechanization and greater specialization had made their work duller, but also more tense and
dangerous; the noise of air-hammers was cited particularly.65 But generally Continental workers were less vociferous in their objections to machinery than British engineers, less indeed than their counterparts in textiles. They saw that machines could defend their industry's competitiveness; some were aided by Marxism to appreciate the need for technical progress. They had not had the time to become attached to specific skills in the industry, and the generalized hostility which a craft background could produce was no substitute for this. Similarly, in Britain itself, workers in new industries such as electrical equipment did not resist consistent technical change. The absence of skill-specific unions in Continental engineering both caused and reflected greater openness to change; unskilled workers were admitted without difficulty and there was no major effort to limit apprenticeship. Adaptation was aided by the continued rapid growth of the industries, which it also facilitated; here was another difference from the British pattern. In Germany the number of unskilled workers in machine building increased by 187 percent in the decade after 1895, but this barely eclipsed the 145 percent growth of skilled labor. Finally, the relative youth of the Continental labor force contrasted with Britain, where the labor force was older and the voice of senior workers more fully protected. Germany reported a number of disagreements between older and younger workers about machinery. Handworkers in Berlin instrument manufacture argued with their younger relatives who went into machine shops without a qualm, where they easily earned more money than their elders. The new workers operating the riveting machines in the Bremen shipyards were satisfied with their work and their considerable pay advantage, but the workers in the older divisions of the company grumbled and cut their production levels to protect their jobs.66 The same division might exist in England, but here the older workers were more numerous and less likely to have been demoted to unskilled jobs.
Unskilled workers generally seem to have found the new levels of mechanization untroubling in machine building, if only because they were able to earn so much more than their traditional wages. Hence French automobile workers were long satisfied despite the growing speed of their machines, with no interest in unionization or in a reduction of hours of work. The unskilled in Germany worked the machines according to rule, with no apparent complaint. But here even skilled workers could find some pleasure in machines. It was noted that they enjoyed tinkering with the equipment if a breakdown occurred, for they felt some personal involvement and challenge.67 One skilled
worker, while complaining about the dust and noise in his factory, commented that he was not only used to his job but also capable of understanding his machine — on which he could do repairs — so it seemed his tool rather than his master.68
So while machines were rarely welcomed in metal work and engineering, the British recalcitrance was unusual. It played an important role in retarding British industrial development, in combination with the manufacturers' unwillingness to push technical advancement too hard. It was not, contrary to some analysis, part of a general British resistance to new technology, for British textile workers, printers, and many artisans were more open to change than most of their Continental counterparts. Even British metallurgy contrasted with the situation in engineering. The smelters' union supported technical improvements 'provided we get a fair share of the plunder.'69 Machines such as new loading devices were welcomed, for they improved the regularity of operations; and generally technology was seen as a means of reducing physical strain in the industry. Fear of unemployment was mild, so that traditional skills such as puddling could be let go without lament. And heavy industry did not have the constant readjustments of piece rates common in engineering, so that a sense of being cheated did not develop. In fact metallurgists had little difficulty winning more favorable rates whenever new machines were introduced. In all of this British metallurgists were not different from their counterparts elsewhere, for acceptance of changing technology was common in the industry — accounting in Germany, for example, for low levels of unionization. Generally there were fewer outcries than in machine construction, for the same reasons as in Britain. All of this merely enhances the realization that British engineering constituted an important exception to the pattern of response to advancing mechanization in factory industry.70
Technological change in other industries evoked little comment. A few miners refused to work the new coal cutters, and the German mine union leader cited greater tension and fatigue due to the shaking it involved. But there was little resistance, and many workers welcomed the relief from hand digging so long as they thought their wages would benefit. And of course the introduction of new equipment was gradual.71 British railway workers cited the increased size of trains in claiming that 'the labour, both physical and mental, of the men . .. has been greatly intensified, and their risks and responsibilities have been increased.'72 But generally rail workers were known for their fascination with machines. A German engineer enthused over his sense
of power, even aesthetic pleasure, as he drove through the countryside. Engineers generally were proud of their locomotive, often supervising repairs to make sure they were done right.73 This was unusual attachment, of course, though we should not minimize the number of workers in every industry who thought they could 'feel with their machines.'74 It was not impossible to regard machines as new, immensely productive tools — for people whose traditions gave them a special reliance on tools and who might find real benefits in some relief from physical strain. Hence workers who judged machines useful and even took a personal interest in them, though less articulate than the opponents of further mechanization, were not rarities.
And in general, without playing down the immense diversity in reactions to new technology, from individual to individual as well as one industry to the next — which could divide the working class significantly, by background and age as well as occupation — the overriding impression must be one of pragmatism. The working class was not in love with machines, but nor was it hostile to mechanization in principle; only those not yet involved in the process but fearing its advent really fell in the latter camp. To be sure, the most obvious advantage of most of the new machines, the reduction of physical strain, did not usually overbalance the increasingly explicit fear of unemployment. This tempered enthusiasm generally. And, perhaps particularly for workers new to the factory system itself, citations of nervous exhaustion could counter any physical relief; this was a widespread impression in German factories. Workers accepted new machines when their bad effects seemed minimal — hence the obvious difference between industries with high unemployment and those with low levels. Where hostile at first their opposition usually softened quickly, again suggesting the absence of a firmly principled antagonism. Softening was aided by the aging of older skilled workers and the possibility of younger workers to move to other fields, as in the case of Carmaux glass workers. Where machines brought advantages, in terms of greater regularity of work and particularly of higher earnings, they could even be welcomed; this was widely true among the new categories of semi-skilled workers. Certainly generalizations about a sense of depersonalization in the face of advancing technology would miss the mark. The machine could make sense to the worker as an individual; it could fit his goals at work.
This leaves a few questions unanswered, of course. We cannot fully resolve the question of whether workers' pragmatism was due primarily to a sense of helplessness, since the time for direct resistance to
machines had long since passed. Unskilled transport and hauling workers, lacking the experience of earlier frustrations in fighting the machine age, alone tried frontal opposition, but only briefly and sporadically. The declining artisans who hated the machines more knew they were powerless. Opposition was further weakened by the fact that every organized labor movement advised against it. There is no question that workers were frequently more eager to attack new machines than their leaders were. The leaders' ideological belief in progress was often involved here, as was their common-sense understanding that there were advantages to be won from an increase in productivity and that resistance was almost surely futile (and futility damaging to a union or party). The fact that they did not have to work the machines themselves was not irrelevant. So local as well as national leaders worked to dissuade workers from opposing machines — urging them to seek compensatory advantages as well — and not infrequently negotiated agreements that they could barely persuade their constituents to accept. It took years for the French textile union to induce its members even to experiment with two looms, though the union was amenable as early as 1904. Beneath official policy a number of British cotton workers were hostile to multiple looms and co nducted some strikes against them.75 But this kind of clash occurred mainly at the first sight of machinery, not as an ongoing tension; and the willingness of workers to challenge their unions more massively on other issues suggests that the gap between official and constituent attitudes was not too great.
Resentment against new technology could burst forth in ways other than direct protest. Strikes against the dismissal of workers could at least implicitly challenge technological displacement; this was the case with some general laborers' strikes in England. Workers troubled by mechanization might simply develop a high rate of agitation, without directing it explicitly at machines. Of all French construction workers carpenters were most seriously affected by new methods; this may well have accounted for the fact that their strikes lasted longest and most often touched more than one company, as well as frequently i nvolving demands for a reduction in hours of work.76 In English shoe manufacture, clickers, the last skilled group to be mechanized, seemed to take an undue lead in agitation at the end of the 1890s, as they anticipated the change. So the generalized effects of resentments over mechanization should not be minimized. But we should not neglect the effectiveness of much direct protest over technological change either. In a number of cases hostility to new machines slowed, if it rarely
prevented, their introduction. Workers were not totally out of control of the situation, except in the case of rural craftsmen forlornly viewing the rise of urban factories in their trade. Even British engineers, who lost every direct battle over efforts to limit the entry of unskilled workers, clearly played a role in retarding technological change, to the ultimate disadvantage of the industry. So we need not assume that workers who wished to protest technology would have sought indirect methods alone. Change did Cause uneasiness and raised a host of specific issues, but most workers were able to adjust sufficiently to make massive confrontation unnecessary.
Crucial to the adjustment in many cases, as we have seen, was a willingness to accept higher pay for what may have been a more disagreeable job. It seems undeniable that technological change in this period encouraged workers to take a more instrumental view of their work, seeing compensations off the job as essential to make the job endurable. The role of young workers, eager for higher earnings and not yet tied to specific work methods, was crucial here. But a more instrumental view of the job should not be confused with any sort of thorough-going alienation. Few workers found their sense of skill completely eroded by the new machines, and countless unskilled workers, upgraded to a semi-skilled category, may have found their sense of worth on the job increased — even though we do not hear from them directly. Few of the types of workers who can be studied in some detail emerged from experience of machine work without some belief that the job was still interesting, even if it had deteriorated somewhat. Technological change was sufficiently gradual, and the workers were sufficiently adaptable, to prevent a sense of despair. Where, as was not uncommon, workers could relate the new machines to their own interest in tools and in control over production they might even be stimulated by technological change.
This does not close the subject, of course. The new technology was related to other changes in the workplace, for it often created new requirements of discipline and co-ordination. And these changes, in turn, could antagonize workers considerably. But it remains significant that human arrangements on the job, more than technology directly, roused concern in this period. Partly this was because these arrangements changed more rapidly than technology required, partly because workers could see injustice when human agents were involved that could less clearly be perceived in the case of mute machines. In any event, most workers now viewed technological change as a fact of life; only its rate and the conditions surrounding it aroused persistent concern.77
Notes
1. E. Seidel, 'Der Einfluss der Maschine im Getreideumschlagsverkehr,' Die Neue Zeit (1911-12), 1015; H. A Clegg, General Unions in a Changing Society (Oxford, 1964).
2. Amédée Dunois, 'Le Lockout de la maçonnerie,' Pages Libres (1908), 52; H. A. Clegg et al., A History of British Trade Unions since 1889 (London, 1964), I, 348 ff.; Raymond Postgate, The Builders' History (London, n.d.), 370.
3. J. B. Platel, 'La Grève des boutonniers de l'Oise,' Voix ouvrière (1909), 237 ff.; Jean Vial, La Coutume chapelière (Paris, 1941), 241; Cari Ergang, Untersuchungen zum Maschinenproblem (Karlsruhe i.B., 1911); Grenoble et sa région 1900-1925 (Grenoble, 1925), 468-9.
4. Theodor Leipart, Die Lage der Arbeiter in der Holzindustrie (Stuttgart, 1909); Paul Flattau, Das Schlossergewerbe zu Berlin (Leipzig, 1916); Albert Aftalion, La Fabrique et le travail à domicile dans les industries de l'habillement (Paris, 1906), 7 ff.
5. Alan Fox, A History of the National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives (Oxford, 1958), 129 ff.; Friedrich Behr, Die Wirkung der fortschreitender Technik auf die Schuhindustrie (Leipzig, 1909).
6. Schulze-Gaevernitz, The Cotton Trade in England and on the Continent (London, 1895); W. J. Ashley, The Progress of the German Working Classes (London, 1904).
7. Albert Aftalion, Les Crises périodiques de surproduction (Paris, 1913), II, 7 ff.
8. Hermann Muller, Die Uberzeugung im Saarldnder Huttengewerbe von 1856 bis 1913 (Jena, 1935).
9. A. L. Levine, Industrial Retardation in Britain (London, 1967); Friedrich Schinder, Tradition und Fortschritt; Hundert Jahre Gemeinschaftsarbeit im Ruhrbergbau (Stuttgart, 1959).
10. Roland Kenney, Men and Rails (London, 1913), 104 ff.
11. Levine, Retardation, 433 and passim; Frank W. Galton, éd., Workers on Their Industries (London, 1896), 63; James B. Jefferys, The Story of the Engineers (London, 1946), 119.
12. The International Federation of Ship, Dock and River Workers, To Shipowners (London, 1896); M. Pappenheim, Die Lage der in der Seeschiffahrt beschàftigen Arbeiter (Leipzig, 1902), II, passim.
13. Dockers' Record, September 1912.
14. Munster Staatsarchiv, Regierung Arnsberg I 73, Mining agitation 1908—9; Emile Vandervelde, La Belgique ouvrière (Paris, 1906), 242; Léon de Seilhac,' 'Les Grèves du bassin de Longwy,' Musée, social (1906), 390.
15. Voix du peuple, 18 July 1909.
16. Seidel, 'Einfluss,' passim. A labor leader in Le Havre also argued that machines represented progress and an improvement in the workers' lot, but here his coal-loader constituency initially disagreed. They did finally consent to work the machines for a one
franc raise, which might suggest they were open to persuasion; but they also agreed among themselves to slow up in their work, in order to prevent unemployment. C. Géeroms, 'L'Affaire Durand,' La Vie ouvrière (1910), 737.
17. Royal Commission on Labour, Digest of the Evidence, Group 'B' (Transport by Water and Transport by Land (London, 1892, C 6795), 44; Norman Dearie, Problems of Unemployment in the London Building Trades (London, 1908), 53; Operative Bricklayers' Society, Annual Reports, 1908, 1911.
18. Fédération du Bâtiment, Annuaire (Paris, 1911), 286.
19. Paul Mantoux and Maurice Alfassa, La Crise du Trade-Unionisme (Paris, 1903), 292.
20. Arthur Shadwell, Industrial Efficiency (London, 1906), II, passim; Adolf Levenstein, Die Arbeiterfrage (Munich, 1913), 127.
21. Max Morgenstern, Auslese und Anpassung der industrieller Arbeiterschaft betrachtet bei den Offenbacher Lederarbeitern (Freiburg i. B., 1911), 24.
22. Webb Collection (London School of Economics), XXIV, 1893 flyer on a dispute over new finishing machines.
23. Ministère du travail et de la prévoyance sociale: office du travail, Enquête sur le travail à domicile dans l'industrie de la chaussure (Paris, 1914), 369.
24. Robert Wilbrandt, Die Weber in der Gegenwart (Jena, 1906), 96.
25. FriedrichiBehr, Die volkswirtschaftliche Bedeutung der fechnischer Entwicklung der Schuhindustrie (Leipzig, 1909). By 1909 machine work was being paid 40% more than handwork in the industry in Germany.
26. Leipart, Lage, passim.
27. Postgate, Builders, 317; Raymond Joran, L'Organisation syndicale dans l'industrie des bâtiments (Paris, 1914), passim.
28. Archives départmentales des Bouches-du-Rhône M6—2037; Archives départmentales de la Loire, 92M/130, report of 1905; Richard Ehrenberg, 'Regenerativ-Ofen und Arbeiterbewegung in der deutschen und englischen Grùnglasindustrie,' Thûnen-Archiv (1909), 18 ff.; E. Backert, Geschichte der Brauarbeiterbewegung (Berlin, 1916); Verband der Brauerei und Mùhlenarbeiter, Zweigverein Hamburg, Unsere Lohnbewegung im Jahre 1911 (Hamburg, 1911).
29. Levine, Retardation. Printers' employers were of course small on the average, though all craft employers were; this reduced their resistance. Perhaps their unusual contact with intellectuals made them more liberal — hence unusual sensitivity to workers' demands. More relevant is the absence of significant international competition in printing. But all this mainly differentiates printers from factory workers, not from other artisans. Alexander Tille, Lohntqrifabkommen und nationale Arbeit (Sarrbrucken, 1906), passim.
30. A. E. Musson, The Typographical Association (London, 1957), 102.
31. Le Typographe lillois, 23 October 1909.
32. Musson, Association, 243.
33. Fédération française des travailleurs du livre, Compte-rendu du neuvième congrès national (Paris, 1905), 322.
34. Archives départmentales du Nord, M621/31, report of August, 1909; Fédération des travailleurs du livre, 8ième Congrès national (Paris, 1900), 19.
35. Korrespondent fur Deutschlands Buchdrucker und Schriftsgiesser, 29 May 1900.
36. Max Morgenstern étal., Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeit erschaft (Leipzig, 1912); Board of Trade, Report of Collective Agreements between Employers and Workpeople (London, 1911, Cd. 5366), xxviii; Tille, Lohntarifabkommen.
37. Archives de la ville de Bruxelles, 197, report on 1900 printers' strike.
38. Gustav Conrady, Histoire de la Federation locale (Brussels., 1921), 103 ff.
39. Musson, Association, 202.
40. Fédération des travailleurs du livre, 8ème Congrès, passim; Korrespondent fur Deutschlands Buchdrucker und Schriftsgiesser, 6 August 1901.
41. La Typographie française, July 1906.
42. Musson, Association, 230.
43. Carl Ergang, Untersuchungen zum Maschinenproblem (Karlsruhe i.B., 1911), Glass workers in Carmaux faced even greater trauma, for this was an industry in which technical change could be startlingly rapid. With craft skills displaced older workers resorted directly to socialism and a major strike (in 1895); this was one case where intergenerational change did not work. But union defenses were inadequate. Older workers could only grumble, or head for other areas, particularly villages, in which manual methods of glassblowing were still possible. But even this instance forms only a brief exception to the theme of adaptation. New workers were recruited for the machines who thought they benefited by their elevation to at least a trace of a skilled craft, while the sons of the older artisans headed toward new fields. Protest, relatedly, dissipated. Sudden incursions of technical change cannot be ignored, but the glass industry was unusual and even its workers, overall, not deprived of possibilities of adjustment. Joan Scott, The Glassworkers of Carmaux (Cambridge, Mass., 1974).
44. Korrespondent fur Deutschlands Buchdrucker und Schriftsgiesser, 1899.
45. Musson, Association, 253; Hans Hinke, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiter im Buchdruckgewerbe (Berlin, 1910), passim.
46. W. H. Warburton, The History of Trade Union Organisation in the North Staffordshire Potteries (London, 1931), 213.
47. National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives, Monthly Report, March 1897.
48. Voix du peuple, 10 August 1913.
49. National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives, Monthly Report, June 1905, and Conference Report (London, 1906), and Report of the Tenth Conference (Leicester, 1892); Labour Gazette, March 1895.
50. Archives nationales (France), F7-12766, report of September 1909; Archives de la Préfecture de police de la Seine B/al367, report on the Derréal company, 1900.
51. Laurent Deschene, L'Avènement du régime syndical à Verviers (Paris, 1908), 235, 376; Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, passim; Der Crimmitschau Kampf um den Zehnstundentag (Berlin, 1905); Heinrich Brauns, Der Ubergang von der Handweberei zum Fabrikbetrieb in der niederrheinischen Samt und Seiden-Industrie (Leipzig, 1906); Zentralverband christlicher Textilarbeiter Deutschlands, Geschàftbericht, 1910, 53.
52. Voix du peuple, 4 December 1910.
53. Achille Maertens, La Grève du tissage Planche d'Hazebrouck (Lille, 1908), 55-9; L'Ouvrier textile, 1 May 1914; Archives nationales (France) F7-13820, report of March 1913.
54. Labour Gazette, passim; Ben Turner, History of the General Union of Textile Workers (Merkmondwike, 1926); H. A. Turner, Trade Union Growth, Structure, and Policy: A Comparative Study of the Cotton Unions (London, 1962), 258 ff.
55. L'Ouvrier textile, 1 May 1914; Jules Uhry, 'Les Grèves en 1901,' Musée social (1903), 546—7; Voix du peuple, 23 November 1902; William Reddy, ' Family and Factory; French Linen Weavers in the Belle Epoque,' Journal of Social History (1974), passim.
56. Le Peuple, 8 August 1904.
57. Turner, Growth, 258; Roland Gibson, Cotton Textile Wages in the United States and Great Britain (New York, 1948), 70 ff.
58. Amalgamated Association of Card and Blowing Room Operatives, Quarterly Report, June 1890.
59. John Jewkes and E. M. Gray, Wages and Labour in the Lancashire Cotton Spinning Industry (Manchester, 1935), 71, 118 and passim.
60. Quoted in Levine, Retardation, 419.
61. Associated Iron Moulders of Scotland, Monthly Report, July 1891.
62. J. C. Carr and W. Taylor, History of the British Steel Industry (Oxford, 1962), 277 ff.; Levine, Retardation, All and passim; Labour Gazette, June 1897; Jefferys, Engineers, passim. The ASE twice pushed for admission of the semi-skilled, but a vast majority of the membership voted this down.
63. Jefferys, Engineers, 143.
64. Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, 51.
65. Josef Neuman, Die deutsche Schiffbauindustrie (Leipzig, 1910); Carl Severing, Mein Lebensweg (Berlin, 1950), I; Heinrich Herkner, Problème der Arbeiterpsychologie (Leipzig, 1912); Waldemar Jolko, Untersuchungen iiber die Entlôhnungsmethoden
in der Berliner Metallindustrie (Berlin, 1911), 71; Levine, Retardation, 452; Niedersâchsiches Staatsarchiv (Hannover), Polizeiakten des Oberpràsidenten der Provinz Hannover (Hann. 122a XI), 70, report on Bremen, 1903.
66. Alphonse Loyau, 'La Semaine anglaise en France,' La Vie ouvrière (1912), 379; Walter Timmermann, Die Entlôhnungsmethoden in der Hannoverschen Eisenindustrie (Berlin, 1906).
67. Le\enstem,Arbeiterfrage, 90.
68. Levine,Retardation, passim.
69. Carr and Taylor, Steel, 277; statement by John Hodge.
70. Arthur Pugh, Men of Steel (London, 1951), 110; John Hodge, Workman's Cottage to Windsor Castle (London, n.d.) 89 ff.;Otto Hommer, Die Entwicklung und Tàtigkeit des deutschen Metallarbeiterverbandes (Berlin, 1912), passim. In contrast, metal workers and engineers were often bewildered by the new piece rates introduced along with novel machines, so that they might have no understanding of what they were earning. Alfred "Williams, Life in a Railway Factory (London, 1915), 183; Generalkommission der Gewerkschaften Deutschlands, Correspondenzblatt, 1911.
71. Larkhall Miners' Association County Union Reports, 1901 (Manuscript archive); Otto Hué, Die Bergarbeiter (Stuttgart, 1913); J. E. Williams, The Derbyshire Miner (London, 1962), 373; Max Metzner, Die soziale Fursorge im Bergbau (Jena, 1911).
72. Amalgamated Society of Railway Servants, Minutes of Executive Committee Meetings, (1905), report on a London rally.
73. Hermann Sinn, Aus den Erinnerungen eines alten Eisenbahners (Leipzig, 1944); Waldemar Zimmerman, Die soziale Verhaltnisse der Angestellten im preussischen Staatsbahnbetriebe (Altenburg, 1902), 9 ff.
74. Comment by a German metalworker: Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, 65.
75. Léon de Seilhac, La Grève du tissage de Lille (Paris, 1910); Shadwell, Efficiency, I.
76. Municipal Workers' Association, Quarterly Report, June 1911; Peter N. Stearns, Revolutionary Syndicalism and French Labor (New Brunswick, 1972), 127, 132-3.
77. As against this see the recent assumption, offered with no real effort at proof, that semi-skilled workers on the new machines were 'dehumanized.' Edward Shorter and Charles Tilly, Strikes in France, 1830-1968 (Cambridge 1974), 19, 80-1.
CHAPTER 5 RELATIONSHIPS WITH EMPLOYERS
More obviously than technology, changes in business structure set the decades around the turn of the century off from the preceding period. This was a time of rapidly-growing company size and the proliferation of corporations, trusts, and cartels. Direction of work became more impersonal and workers were herded into larger and larger units of operation. Surely, as even non-Marxist historians have noted, class hostility could only increase and relationships on the job became even more tense. This has recently been invoked as an explanation for the post-1909 strike wave in Britain, while analysis that claims a correlation between political radicalism and the size of units of employment would have obvious applicability to this period in all industrial countries.1
We can grant the existence of pockets of traditional deference. Elbeuf was described in 1900 as a city in which factories of any size dated from only thirty years before, and many small companies dotted the landscape here. Many workers had held their jobs for twenty years or more and their relations with employers were excellent. A few manufacturers noted a waning sympathy during the 1890s, but most workers trusted the owners to deal with them fairly. Women workers in Germany, often deeply religious, objected to any agitation against the Herr; their loyalty was reinforced with a bonus when they stayed out of a strike. Many workers of both sexes, freshly in from the countryside, maintained similar deference. Catholic union organizers in Germany noted how hard it was to rid Silesian workers of the feeling 'that there are only masters and servants,' inherited from their experience on the landed estates.2 Flemish workers, similarly resigned, talked of fearing to offend the 'rich people' were they to strike or join a union.3 But this kind of traditionalism would be quickly eroded by the advance of large units of industry, for the sanctions of deference would not long protect the anonymous boards of directors of corporations. Younger workers, at least, would learn to speak out; and we have already mentioned that even many rural immigrants were sensitized in advance to impersonal controls, for growing formality had driven them away from agricultural employers.
Unquestionably, for large numbers of workers we are dealing with the advent or solidification of big business came as a shock. We know
something of the resentments against anonymity that big business can rouse; surely they would develop most readily when the beast was first encountered. Many of the observers who commented on work during this period noted the feelings of separation that were growing between workers and employers. German machine workers, for example, were assigned numbers by a faceless bureaucracy and complained that they were working for the profit of some unknown millionaire.4 A familiar and highly plausible description, which the historian could easily confirm. And the issue of employer-worker relations raises directly the question of the meaning of socialism, though we must disclaim any pretense at a full analysis. Both contemporaries and subsequent analysts have assumed a relationship between employment in big business and the rise of socialism (and later, communism).5 Certainly socialist factory workers — and by no means party leaders alone — could pour out a bitter hatred against their employers. Metal workers in Nuremburg spoke directly of the basic relationship during a bitter strike: 'The director of this company still believes he holds the power.'6 A Belgian miner saw the forces that controlled him even more abstractly, as he condemned the government for failing to regulate the use of explosives: 'This is gambling with our life and death. Ah! we can feel how the present government supports and protects the shareholders. We would impose other guarantees under a democratic regime ... When will freedom come then, to bring us at least a bit more security in our harsh work.'7 Other workers, not oppressed by any particular crisis, related socialism above all to the issue of control at work. A Saxon metal worker interestingly combined signs of a traditionalist deference to social hierarchy with this kind of approach:
You know, I never read a social democratic book and rarely a newspaper. I used not to occupy myself with politics at all. But since I got married and have five eaters at home I have to do it. But I think my own thoughts.... We really do not want to become like the rich and refined people. There will always have to be rich and poor. We would not think of altering that. Eut we want a better and more just organization at the factory and in the state.8
And there were violent attacks on the persons of employers. On four or five occasions workers in an isolated factory town in France invaded the manufacturer's mansion in what was really a local revolution against all-pervading company power. Violence was even more common when
the normal resentment against employer control was enhanced by the emotions of a long strike. This accounted for the explosives placed at the manufacturers' homes in Chambon-Feugerolles. In Osnabruck, similarly, metal workers stoned and shot a manager who tried to disperse them as they crowded around a struck plant.9
Finally, the scanty available polling material that dealt directly with employer-worker relations produced similar evidence of anger. Adolf Levenstein's queries to several hundred socialist workers produced more complaints about the problem of dependence than anything else; the figures are given some credibility, despite the small sample involved, by the fact that areas of known deference, such as Silesia, listed the complaint least frequently. Thus 39 percent of the miners cited dependence as a leading problem, along with 37 percent of the textile workers; one textile worker noted that his material needs were small, but he resented the necessity of obeying a boss who could fire him so easily. Metal workers, whose industry was increasingly dominated by big business and whose unions were relatedly weak, put dependence at the top of their list in 53 percent of the responses.1 ° One lamented: 'The consciousness of dependence on the employer embitters me, has made me an irritable man. A gesture of the director... is enough to make my blood boil.'11
None of this is meant as a definitive comment on the meaning of socialism to German or Belgian workers. One can easily find other material suggesting that socialist voting was often seen in more prosaic terms; miners interviewed in the second Belgian general strike most commonly associated a socialist victory with higher wages alone.12 But the link between political protest and big business is more than plausible. It could certainly help explain the stunting of socialism in England, where trade union power muted the impact of impersonal business forms.
A chapter on worker-employer relations cannot, however, be simply an embellishment on the theme of alienation from big business. Without intending to refute the framework suggested thus far, it must at least be modified. Most workers were not as angry about their undeniable dependence as the ones depicted above. Violence against employers was actually rare, even in France. Verbal attacks were not always meant to be taken literally. German dockers blasted employers in a public meeting, scaring them in the process, but then admitted to a socialist journalist that many were normally friendly and fair. And, though we need more information on the industrial incidence of socialist voting, the association of political protest with subjection to
big business was certainly incomplete. If the special example of England is illuminating, so is that of the United States, where much of the support for political protest came from artisans, not factory workers. Such was indeed the case in Germany and Belgium as well. After the miners, for example, it was Belgian artisans who supported the socialist general strikes most avidly; metallurgical workers lagged. And while artisans unquestionably had organizational problems of their own, which we will discuss shortly, they were not exposed to the leading edge of the rationalization effort.13 Quite apart from the thorny question of socialism, it is dangerous to theorize too abstractly about reactions to rationalization and bureaucracy. Workers can be studied as models of a modern accommodation to organizational control at least as fruitfully as rebels against it.
The following discussion will offer several major points in lieu of a simple pursuit of a protest theme. First, predictably, the question of diversity. Not only were pockets of traditional deference large, but the types of employer-worker relations defy generalization. We must discuss the artisan, the unskilled worker, and the factoxy hand separately because their situations differed so radically, though each was touched by some aspects of the rationalization process. Each group had different possibilities of response, which can bring us back to some effort at political correlations. National circumstances differed as well, for rationalizing manufacturers were not faceless types, immune from distinctive cultural and political causation. For all groups, but particularly for factory workers who obviously constitute the most important case, we will offer three other considerations. First, rationalization was not an abstract issue for most workers; it had to be seen in human terms and responses would vary according to the personalities, as well as the systems, involved. This does not necessarily displace the alienation model, but it at least adds depth to it. Second, rationalization proved extremely hard to attack directly, partly because of the weapons big business possessed but partly because of distinctive ways in which most workers judged their employers, large or small. Difficulty in direct attack may bring one back to the question of more general political response, but this is not the only point. For, third, rationalization brought some benefits to some kinds of workers in terms of the framework for their job. We will find ambiguity at many points, as workers resented new, impersonal controls but complained mightily about the personalized abuse to which they had been subject earlier. German miners might, for example, have been somewhat less concerned about dependence in the abstract than metal workers, as
Levenstein's figures suggest, for they were under more individualized direction; but they were far more upset by the results of whimsy. Most workers were dependent, and big business could make them more so; but within a system of dependence new organizational forms could alleviate some of the problems of being directed by other people, which is what the whole subject of 'relationship to employers' meant to workers on a day-to-day basis.
The most general point is this: rationalization probably did not greatly heighten sentiments of dependence. Only among some unskilled was a demonstrably new claim for dignity and freedom being pressed. Many other workers were capable of some effective counteraction against organizational change. Still more widely, business structure was judged mainly in terms of the personalities involved. Intermediaries might mute organizational tensions or draw workers' fire; in either case they distracted from what an outsider might judge to be an increasingly impersonal job structure. For most workers personal dependence was in fact more galling than big business controls, but it was by its very nature extremely variable. Hence a theme of general hatred would be misplaced; among other things personalization meant that all but the most acerbic workers might relieve their tensions by changing companies. Class consciousness was rising in politics, and changes in business forms may have played a role here. On the job, however, it is difficult to perceive any consistent pattern of growing structural tension. Even the personal battles maintained a rather constant rate.
The speed of rationalization can be roughly measured by the growth in the size of units of employment, as far as the impact on workers is concerned; diversity, which takes on the expected contours of craft vs. factory, can be briefly charted as well. We need not linger too long over the inadequacy of the statistics. In Britain numbers of employers and of workers can be compared in key industries, conveying fairly adequately differential rates of growth; but these rates cannot be placed against French or German figures, where the number of companies is known. Belgian figures similarly result from a worker-employer comparison with some predictably misleading results; as the number of managerial personnel outstripped workers in mining, for example, the probable modest growth of the companies in the extractive industries is obscured. Even for France and Germany, where figures are most reliable, exact comparisons are faulted by the fact that France treated independent producers separately; this makes little difference in heavy industry, but inflates French figures vis-à-vis German in the light industries and crafts. Differences in definition of key categories also
mars any comparative effort.14
All that comparison suggests (Table II) is the essentially common range of the industrial countries. Belgium, as an older industrializer, had much more concentrated firms than Germany in 1896; even the big German surge thereafter did not bring Germany up to the Belgian levels of a decade earlier. The heavy influence of craft structures in Germany is readily apparent; from the working-class standpoint, Germany was not a distinctive home of big industry. Nor, to get at another tenacious stereotype, was France exclusively the haven of small shops. In contrast both to Germany and to Belgium, French mining was highly concentrated, while metallurgy and chemicals were within a common range. German textiles, and quite probably other light industries, were less concentrated than French or Belgian. Printing was remarkably similar, as were the more traditional crafts. The German distribution of workers among sizes of companies probably leaned a bit more towards larger units than did the French, though precise figures on the latter are lacking, if only because of the different balance among industries. But the differences were not great. The example of Belgium suggests that, given the huge influence of crafts and small shops, age of industrialization more than sudden upsurges of concentration in the most visible branches of production explains national differences. Were British figures available they would undoubtedly point to a similar contrast, for the shop form was much less important in Britain than on the Continent.
For the range of company sizes, and worker distributions within the various categories, was considerable in all the Continental countries (and indeed in Britain as well, though the variations were less pronounced given the greater previous penetration of factory organization). Only in heavy industry was there virtually no small-shop sector. Light industries at the end of the period occupied a middle range. Few were so large, for example, as to prevent some contact between employer and those workers who remained with the concern for any period of time. It seems clear that until right before World War I less than a quarter of the work-force (considerably less in France and Germany) was employed in units in which impersonality was dictated by sheer company size. The artisanal trades, some of them huge users of labor, constituted yet another category, in which the average firm rarely employed more than five workers even after 1900. (Printing was an exception, because of the virtual absence of tiny units.) Averages are to some extent deceiving here, but not in terms of overall range. Only in construction did the small average size increasingly conceal a sharp
gap between the majority of big-city workers, employed in units over fifty, and a minority of small-shop or independent producers. In industries such as woodworking or leather, the average company size reflects fairly even gradations of workers from the small shop to the large factory. In the German wood industry in 1907, the average company employed 3.2 workers; the average worker was employed in a unit with a labor force of almost exactly thirty people. This figure in turn is too simple; 11 percent of all woodworkers held jobs in factories with over two hundred employees, another 12 percent in units of over one hundred.15 But in so far as averages can convey anything, in these industries where a division had opened between shop and factory, it remains fair to characterize the normal experience as one in which the worker held a job in a unit near the borderline between shop and factory. Finally a few large industries were still dominated by shop and home work. Almost 80 percent of all French bakers were employed in units with less than five workers in 1906, and almost half of all clothing workers. The size of firms was increasing; between 1906 and 1911 the number of bakery owners dropped about 3 percent, while the number of bakers increased about 2 percent, but the small firm remained preponderant.16 For the working class as a whole it is clearly impossible to talk about a common employment experience.
Furthermore, while the evolution of company structure reduced the gaps within the working class — a development of real potential significance — it did not eliminate them. And the differential quality of the evolution raises some additional problems of its own (Tables III and IV). In general, company growth was relatively modest in sectors such as heavy industry, just as it was slower in countries (such as Belgium and probably Britain) in which the big firm had already established itself. Thus except to an extent in Germany, where the mines had been relatively small, the rate of expansion was not great. Metallurgy gained somewhat more rapidly but was rarely a leader. For workers in these industries, especially new entrants, it seems safe to suggest that adjustment to the fact of large units, more than rate of change, would pose an ongoing problem; and indeed there were few expressions of a new kind of concern. In the lighter industries such as textiles and engineering, the advent of the big firm was newer and the rate of change far greater. Machine builders were thus faced with new business structure as well as new techniques, textile workers with bigger companies along with a pronounced decline in the industry's vitality. The experience of key artisanal sectors was potentially at least as troubling, for high growth rates were coupled with a firm traditional
attachment to small units of organization. Printers were relatively immune from change, but for woodworkers, food processers in some areas, and leather workers this was a period of real upheaval. Even more consistently, the construction industry entered a period of intensive rationalization.
Thus the notion of advancing rationalization seems quite accurate in describing the pre-war decades, but its impact on the working class was more subtle, and for this reason more pervasive, than attention to the progress of cartels and industrial finance might indicate. Change was now hitting the middle sectors of manufacturing, and this, more than the solidification of big business in heavy industry, affected a large percentage of the working class. Despite the rapidity of change, however, it can again be noted that the effects on workers tended more to divide generations than to displace individuals. Even in Germany, where the traditional base was substantial and the rate of change considerable, no category actually decreased in size. Most workers employed in units with less than five employees, for example, could expect to remain in such a unit. And in no category did the average size of firms increase massively. What was occurring was a tremendous shift in the relative importance of each type of firm, with the larger units
Table I Differences in Company Size
Germany 1907, average size (workers per company) |
France 1906 |
|
Large mines 163.5 |
Large |
mines 984 |
metallurgy 141.6 |
metallurgy 711 |
|
machines 11.9 |
||
printing 11.1 |
||
chemical 16.3 |
||
Intermediate |
||
textiles 8.0 |
wool |
|
construction 7.5 |
weaving 341 |
|
food |
wool |
|
processing 4.0 |
comb ing 694 |
|
metals 5.6 |
Intermediate |
linen |
leather 4.2 Artisanal |
spinning 268 cotton |
|
wood 3.8 |
spinning 234 |
|
transport 4.6 |
||
heavily domestic clothing 1.9 |
Table II Comparative Suggestions (German figures: 51+)
% Workers in Companies |
|||||
1-5 workers |
6-50 workers |
51-50 worker |
500+ orkers |
||
Chemicals |
|||||
France 1906 |
4.5 |
27.9 |
45.4 |
21.2 |
|
Germany 1907 |
69.8 |
||||
Printing |
|||||
France 1906 |
10.0 |
41.5 |
40.3 |
||
Germany 1907 |
43.3 |
43.8 |
|||
Textiles |
|||||
France 1906 |
13.9 |
53.1 |
26.1 |
||
Germany 1907 |
16.7 |
67.5 |
|||
Belgium 1896 |
|||||
mechanical cotton spinning |
26.7 |
||||
mechanical dotton weaving |
25.8 |
||||
mechanical linen spinning |
64.5 |
||||
Metallurgy |
|||||
France 1906 |
79.9 |
||||
Germany 1907 |
47.0 |
||||
Belgium 1896 |
|||||
steel |
70.9 |
||||
blast furnace |
18.7 |
||||
Mines |
|||||
France 1908 |
86.8 |
||||
Germany 1907 |
96.7 |
||||
Belgium 1896 |
25.9 |
||||
Belgium 1896 overall |
13.9 |
25.9 |
36.6 |
23.5 |
|
(1,4) |
(5-49) |
(50-499) |
(500+) |
||
Germany 1895 overall |
39.9 |
23.8 |
36.3 |
||
(1-5) |
(6-50) |
(51+) |
|||
Germany 1907 overall |
29.5 |
25.0 |
45.5 |
Relationships with Employers
Table III Evolution of Company Size
A. Germany
1-5 Workers |
6-50 Workers |
51 + |
||||||
avg. size |
% total |
% increases in workers |
avg. size |
% total |
% increases in workers |
avg. size |
% total |
% increases in workers |
1896 1.6 |
39.9 |
13.6 |
23.8 |
162.0 |
136.3 |
|||
1907 1.7 |
29.5 |
.2 |
14.5 |
25.0 |
42.7 |
170.0 |
45.5 |
69.8 |
B. Belgium
1890 average size |
1910 average size |
% growth |
annual rate |
|
extractive industry |
124.1 |
107.2 |
- |
|
construction |
3.7 |
5.2 |
40.5 |
2.0 |
manufacturing |
4.1 |
5.7 |
39.0 |
1.9 |
C. France
1896 average size |
1906 average size |
% growth |
annual rate |
|
wool weaving |
118 |
341 |
189.0 |
18.9 |
wool combing |
366 |
694 |
90.0 |
9.0 |
linen spinning |
129 |
268 |
50.0 |
5.0 |
cotton spinning |
110 |
234 |
47.0 |
4.7 |
metallurgy |
508 |
711 |
40.0 |
4.0 |
coal mining |
897 |
984 |
12.0 |
1.2 |
Table III (continued) D. Germany
1895 average size |
1907 average size |
% growth |
annual rate |
|
All companies |
3.7 |
5.2 |
40.5 |
3.4 |
construction |
2.3 |
7.5 |
226.1 |
18.8 |
transport |
2.9 |
4.6 |
58.6 |
4.9 |
textiles |
4.8 |
8.0 |
66.7 |
5.6 |
machines |
6.6 |
11.9 |
80.3 |
6.7 |
metals |
3.7 |
5.6 |
51.3 |
4.3 |
metallurgy |
85.5 |
141.6 |
65.6 |
5.5 |
chemicals |
11.1 |
16.3 |
46.8 |
3.9 |
leather |
3.1 |
4.2 |
35.5 |
3.0 |
wood |
2.7 |
3.8 |
40.7 |
3.4 |
mines |
129.8 |
163.5 |
26.0 |
2.2 |
printing |
9.0 |
11.1 |
23.3 |
1.9 |
food processing |
3.8 |
4.0 |
5.2 |
.4 |
clothing |
1.6 |
1.9 |
17.6 |
1.5 |
E. Britain
% growth 1891-1911 |
annual rate |
|
metallurgy |
70.1 |
3.5 |
chemicals |
119.0 |
5.9 |
machines |
28.4 |
3.7 |
vehicles |
120.0 |
6.0 |
building |
38.0 |
1.9 |
printing |
15.7 |
.8 |
textiles |
19.0 |
.9 |
food processing |
84.6 |
4.2 |
gaining ground most rapidly. In Britain, for example, while workers in factories increased by 21 percent between 1897 and 1907, those in shops still advanced by 3 percent. In important individual cases, such as construction work in Paris or Berlin, workers would clearly have to shift from one form of business organization to another during their own working life. More commonly, however, it was the new entrant to the labor force — particularly among the skilled workers — who supported the rise of the large firm. The persistence of the small company requires some brief attention before we turn to the more obvious sectors of change. And the intergenerational nature of much of the change, the fact that young workers had to move from the kinds of structures in which their fathers had been employed, complicates an assessment of the impact of change.
We can begin to fill in the human outlines of the rationalization process by a brief look at the two most traditional sectors of manufacturing, both declining though in the one case not too rapidly. Domestic manufacturing requires little comment. Its practitioners might have a host of complaints, and their material situation was bad, but a sense of dependence on the employer rarely loomed large. Some were employers themselves, and exploited their apprentices; this reduced any class sense.17 More commonly they were at the manufacturer's mercy, as domestic industry became steadily less competitive. But the scattered character of the work and its operation, often by women or workers who did not depend on it for their entire support, reduced any ability to articulate resentment; the urban concentration that had produced earlier revolts, such as those of Lyons, had largely disappeared. Hence the home workers studied by public officials usually expressed a sense of personal control over their work, even if they lamented dire poverty. Belgian workers were normally courteous to their employers, who often visited them if they were ill. Their fear of unemployment ironically made them grateful to the manufacturers who deigned to give them work.18
We can assume that those older home workers who hung on despite the growing competition of factories blamed, not their employers, but outside forces. We might also hypothesize that those sons and daughters directly forced into the factories lamented their loss, having seen an alternative form of employment to contrast to factory life. But if so they are mute on the subject. We do not know how many people were displaced directly, for the shrinking of the domestic labor force was due more to attrition through death or the voluntary retirement of people who could or would not move and for whom this work had always been
supplementary. Ironically those factory workers who were articulate on the subject condemned the system. This reflected their fear of low-wage competition, of course, but also some acceptance of factory employment if not of factory employers. Some might even recall the personal tyranny possible over apprentices and aides within the domestic system, for the control of factory life could seem more remote. Unionized French clothing workers put it this way:
Considering that all home work .. . can only be harmful from all points of view to the working class and especially to our corporation, that it is only in shops that we can attain our goals and profit from the laws regulating our corporation . . . the Syndicat de Bordeaux expresses the wish that each Union issue the greatest possible propaganda to attain the complete suppression of home work and the return to the shop.19
Here, in one of the only cases in which the domestic system was still spreading, many workers preferred organization to the vagaries of a more individualized economic structure.
Ambiguities within the small-shop artisanry can be explored more fully, though they run along the same lines, almost certainly dividing urban from small-town craftsmen in key trades such as baking, butchering, barbering, tailoring, and even some traditional branches of metal work and woodwork — indeed in all the fields where a vast number of workers labored in units of less than five employees, many serving as the only worker in the shop. The small-shop workers spoke scarcely a word about their lot, but many of them were clearly satisfied by it. In Verviers, 95 percent of all bakers expected to become employers in their own right, and believed that they had essentially the same interests as their bosses. French hat manufacturers worked alongside their employers, whom they respected so long as the manufacturers knew the trade. Signs of solidarity were compatible even with unionization. British brass workers, in a well-known example, co-operated readily with the employers to maintain high quality standards and limit production; ultimately the resultant high costs priced the brass bedstead out of the market. Skilled cutlery workers in Solingen co-operated similarly with employers in keeping wages up as a means of reducing competition in the whole craft. Furth metal beaters banded with their masters to resist the rising prices imposed by the capitalistic manufacturers of the raw materials. In Graulhet the owners of small tanneries encouraged the union as a means of inhibiting the
Table IV Evolution of Company Size: Summary
Annual % Rates of Growth (betweeen census periods: Germany, 1895— 1907; France, 1896-1906; Belgium, 1890-1910; Britain, 1891-1911).
French wool weaving |
19.9 |
German construction |
18.8 |
French wool combing |
9.0 |
German machines |
6.7 |
British vehicles |
6.0 |
British chemicals |
5.9 |
German textiles |
5.6 |
Germany metallurgy |
5.5 |
French cotton spinning |
4.7 |
German transport |
4.9 |
German metals |
4.3 |
British food processing |
4.2 |
French metallurgy |
4.0 |
German chemicals |
3.9 |
British metallurgy |
3.5 |
German wood |
3.4 |
Germany—all industries |
3.4 |
German leather |
3.0 |
German mines |
2.0 |
Belgian construction |
2.0 |
British building |
1.9 |
German printing |
1.9 |
Belgium-all manufacturing |
1.9 |
German clothing |
1.5 |
French mines |
1.2 |
British textiles |
.9 |
British printing |
.8 |
German food processing |
.4 |
growth of large, mechanized companies.20 Augsburg bakers and their masters formed a single, anti-socialist union, dedicated to loyalty to the master and defense of hand work. Belgian bakers urged their employers to organize, noting that 'Our future ... is intimately linked to that of our employers,'21 so that if they controlled the trade more fully workers could only benefit. In a similar display of solidarity, woodworkers in the Taunus region sang the following refrain to the founders of their shops:
Health to the Noble Founder You did a good job of work For us and for our children And for the working man. Hail to the Firm!22
Surprising sentiments perhaps, but they are worth attention for two reasons. First, although they come from waning manufacturing forms, the types of workers involved, along with their employers, would not yield easily. Birmingham brass workers were headed for near-oblivion, but the small-town baker could hold out for decades. So the numerical importance of this form of work is not only a turn-of-the-century oddity. Second, they remind us of the difficulty of interpreting even highly personalized employment. A gut reaction to the Taunus song could easily be to assume that it was forced sycophancy. It may not have been; gratitude could have been genuine or at least intermingled with disgruntlement. The ambiguity is worth noting because it will recur when we deal with highly sophisticated business organizations.
In France and Germany, the testing ground of reaction to traditional craft norms came over the question of masters' providing board and room to their workers. Only two points are certain. Board and room were surprisingly persistent in these traditional trades. And in contrast the opinion of all articulate workers was extremely hostile. An investigation in Germany, during 1908, revealed that of 5542 bakers, employed in 2111 companies, 3771 were boarded and housed, 810 more housed by their employers — often in very meager conditions. In 416 butcher shops 1194 of 1370 workers were boarded and housed and 106 more just housed. The practice was almost universal in German barber shops, widely noted also among tailors and millers, and rare but not unknown for some smiths, bookbinders, saddlers, cobblers, woodworkers, and transportation workers. In 1904, 47 percent of all German bakers were boarded and housed, while four years later the
percentage may have risen to 60 percent; and many others were tied to partial arrangements. Even socialist observers had to admit that many bakers were contented or at least uncomplaining, for their view of the employment structure was frankly pre-industrial. But the system was gradually decaying, though statistical information is unclear. The German bakers' union, for example, managed to win abolition of board and room for 4000 workers in 1905, and this was not an uncommon strike goal. The picture in France is less clear, for the small size of the French bakers' union suggests an even greater attachment to the old order.23 More and more workers turned against their obvious dependence, complaining about their inability to own a home or start a family as well as the inadequacy of their material conditions: 'Nowhere are the conditions for the workers so bad as in the baking profession.'24 Verviers bakers, though attached to their employers, decided they wanted the freedom — and sufficient wages — to eat out. And this in an industry whose structure was changing imperce ptibly if at all. For workers of this sort the example of factory employment might have suggested greater freedom. Certainly something was stirring in this traditional setting, which trade unions reflected as well as promoted. For their part many traditional masters found their labor force increasingly difficult. A Rhineland master noted: 'The familial relationship between Master and Journeyman is disappearing.'25 Many of the surrogate guilds formed in these professions in Germany, the Innungen, worked vigorously against the workers' union movement. Perceptions were changing on both sides — indeed the notion of sides was new; and without much alteration of actual practices a sense of constraint gradually developed.
For the bulk of the artisanal trades, as we have seen, structural change was quite real. Far fewer construction workers or metal workers had ever been employed in a one-to-one relationship with an employer, but the experience of some equality was relevant here too. The head of the French typographers' union commented that his workers were accustomed to small shops where they could work alongside their employer, who was sometimes a former comrade. This was pushing things a bit, in terms of the actual structure of French printing, but reflected the possibility of considering even a shop with twenty or thirty workers as falling within the range of a comradely txadition. These were industries also in which the sense of dependence was clearly muted by the fact of having dependents under one's own direction. Skilled construction workers had aides, and they often lorded it over them; German masons for example used the familiar form of address to
their aides, but expected the formal pronoun in return. So where growth in company size was not excessive there may not have been a complete overturning of traditional relationships. And the range of companies in these crafts, combined with the skill of most workers involved, provided the possibility of some choice. Workers in British printing, where over 1700 companies had less than nineteen workers in 1909, compared to less than 120 with more than twenty, or in German woodworking, still had the possibility of opting for the small-shop environment, often at some sacrifice in pay and conditions, if this was particularly important to them. Of course, this was not a free choice, and the rapid rate of concentration in most of these industries steadily limited it. But these were workers long separate from the literal artisanal relationship of master and journeyman, and they experienced this new set of structural changes without.much explicit complaint.26
Only in the construction industry was change so great as to cause particular remark. In the Parisian building trades between 1901 and 1906 the number of companies with fewer than twenty workers declined by 160, while those with over a hundred rose from twelve to twenty-five. This kind of structural change brought a number of innovations in the organization of work. In all the industrial countries the scale of operations in the construction trades, around the major cities, increased immensely; hence a widespread effort to set firm conditions on travel costs. The use of foremen spread widely; by 1899, encouraged by the unions, the system of subcontracting had largely ended in the London building trades, and foremen replaced them. These in turn could be quite nasty to the workers, but here was a case in which rationalization could at least potentially remove a longstanding grievance against more personalized exploitation. French construction workers continued their traditional struggle against subcontractors, whom they accused of forcing the pace of work while trimming the wage payment in order to make good their contract; even in big-city construction, traditional organizational forms did not give way easily. Parisian workers claimed that the number of subcontractors actually increased as companies grew. The advent of big companies also produced a host of complaints, in both France and Germany, about poor training and shoddy planning. The upsurge of protest in the Parisian trades between 1906 and 1909 directly reflected the advent of big employers, and the union made an overt attempt to attack the new capitalists while protecting the smaller units.27
But here, and certainly in manufacturing crafts where structural changes were less great, skilled workers quickly developed or elaborated
a response to new organizational forms. Craft unionism was a direct counter to the decline in personalized employment. It expressed the tensions that the new business forms created, but it also maintained many of the traditions of the craft. Where craft unionism was already well developed it tried to expand its functions to take the new organization of the industry into account. In 1899 the British plasterers' union attempted to force foremen to join the organization, to preserve the mutuality if not the personalization of the industry (Parisian construction workers did the same in the 1906-1909 uprising.) The plasterers had to back down on this demand, but continued to claim coequal rights with employers to determine what work a plasterer should do. And British construction unions attempted, with considerable success, to maintain an elaborate set of work rules which gave them considerable authority in the work site despite the growth in company size. This was in addition to the proliferation of collective bargaining agreements, which the construction unions pushed for vigorously; in 1899, 141 of 173 new agreements signed were in the building trades, which by then had almost 500 pacts in 260 towns and cities. French construction workers signed many local agreements; as in Britain, most contained conciliation and arbitration procedures which maintained some mutual contacts between employers and workers.28
The significance of the craft approach in mitigating a changing industrial structure stood out most clearly in Germany, where these unions were almost alone in winning collective agreements. A Munich building contractor in 1903, noting the rapid rise of bargaining, reflected the relatively conciliatory spirit that normally characterized craft employers as well as workers: 'Worker organizations . . . have become powers that must be reckoned with and must be given a voice in job conditions.'29 Collective bargaining spread quickly in the smaller metal companies, in wood, and in food processing as well as construction. General agreements were won with some of the masters' guilds in metals as in construction, while in contrast company-wide agreements penetrated factories rarely and usually when a strong craft element was present. In 1912 it was estimated that between 70 and 80 percent of all agreements in Germany involved companies with forty workers or less.30
This is not the place to rehearse the detailed history of craft unions, but it seems obvious that they played a major role in the reaction to changes in company size. The German statistics suggest that they were most successful in companies that grew relatively modestly; a few agreements were won in the larger metal, wood, and food processing
plants (far more than in heavy industry) but most workers were not covered. And some of the victories even in the crafts were hard-won, as employers in construction and woodworking periodically mounted counter-attacks. But on the whole crafts unions could maintain a reasonably conciliatory stance and their achievements undoubtedly moderated organizational pressures. Here, then, is a case where change produced a response of great significance, but by that very token avoided complete disruption. An artisanal tradition that might have turned against more advanced forms of organization was instead used, particularly in the medium-sized shops, to elaborate compensatory organizations which preserved some important elements of mutuality. The artisans involved seemed able to adjust to the greater impersonality involved.
In contrast, unskilled workers demonstrated acute symptoms of anxiety over the new business structure in which many of them were now employed. Figures are unavailable on the sizes of companies employing unskilled workers, but obviously changes in the construction industry and in transportation (See Table III D) affected them considerably. The rise of big shipping companies transformed the docks as well as the merchant marine, and it is here that the most anguished reaction developed. Rationalization had a number of potential advantages in this area. When German shippers set up a job office workers welcomed it, despite its unilateral character, for it eliminated the traditional corruption by which jobs were obtained through personal contacts with inn-keepers, often with a generous dosage of bribes. In the 1890s Hamburg sailors had specifically complained about the expense of working through middle-men, who paid no heed to their professional competence but charged them considerable fees and often dictated where they could sleep or buy uniforms. Big companies like the Hamburg-Amerika line, and then a shippers' union, eliminated this problem. But generally attachment to a personalized system was greater than this. British dockers, for example, were often on good terms with their foremen, who gave them drinks or tips if they lacked work. Construction laborers frequently followed a familiar foreman from job to job, hoping to get work. And, with a few exceptions, rationalization seldom quickly eliminated the element of corruption. Foremen for the big companies building the Paris subways required the laborers to buy from their canteens. In the long run the advantages of rationalization may have become more apparent, and it is true that the bitterest battles that big business triggered among the unskilled had given way to more restrained dealings by 1914; but few records exist of a positive
adjustment.31
For the unskilled worker new business structures meant closer or at least less sensitive supervision. Many disputes by tram employees broke out when a new administration, bent on rationalizing inherently decentralized procedures, decided to tighten its grip. A strike in Charleroi resulted when inspectors flooded a line without warning — soon after tram lines in the Center had been consolidated; a conductor was accused of falsifying figures on the electricity he used in his daily run, and fired. His reply summed up the outraged dignity that characterized so much of the agitation of the unskilled: 'You not only want to rob me of my bread, but also you want to dishonor me.'32
The reaction to larger units of organization was particularly keen in the seaports. Sailors were touched not only by big companies but by the increased size of their ships as steam won the day from sailing vessels. French seamen had long been under tight discipline; the state gave captains immense disciplinary authority, including corporal punishment, while desertion or rebellion were punishable by military law. This was not new, but organized resistance was; and the trigger clearly was the new structure on board ship. Particularly in Marseilles, in the period of recurrent agitation on both docks and ships between 1900 and 1904, attacks on strike captains were endemic. Many a captain, accused of strict discipline, had to quit in order to prevent a company-wide strike; ultimately the captains organized to protect themselves. The sailors more generally complained that the 'familial' relations that used to prevail on board had given way to a strict hierarchy of command. The Marseilles outburst was unique, but German seamen similarly agitated against despotic captains. And in Britain big business brought a more specific complaint, particularly in the years immediately before World War I. Medical examinations, an obvious part of rationalized personnel procedures, seemed an intolerable intrusion.33 Sailors felt 'mauled about and handled as though they were a piece of New Zealand mutton.'34
Clearly the advent of big business, more than any other innovation, caused an extraordinary outburst among many unskilled workers, in word as in deed. Disruption of personalized direction brought an intense desire for greater dignity and liberty. Ironically the advent of big business corresponded with the settling down of many previously nomadic workers; so a traditional outlet for resentments against employers, simply wandering to another area, had less validity — again resulting in the demand for freedom on the spot. Quarry workers in Argenteuil asked for abolition of obligatory company housing and
canteens. Marseilles sailors insisted on abandonment of the 'red book' in which any dereliction of duty was recorded and which could serve as the basis for a general blacklisting. Carters wanted to be treated as something more than 'beasts of burden,' while merchant seamen claimed that they were 'impelled by a sense of dignity' to 'revolt against our tyrants'.35 Sentiments of this sort helped produce in turn the upheavals on the docks (London, 1889; Hamburg, 1896; Marseilles, 1899—1904) that have justly received attention as part of a new kind of working-class unrest.36 Potentially, at least, reaction to big business could impel unskilled workers into the mainstream of the working class for the first time. But insecurity of employment and the power of the big shipping and construction companies reduced the first wave of unrest rather quickly. Shipping companies set up their preferential hiring lists with only a hint of worker representation in their governance or, as in Parisian construction, enforced a lockout, and the wildest effervescence was over. The result was that during most of the pre-war years unskilled workers were exposed to big business without real intermediaries, for their unions had been beaten down. Small ports like Sète or Flensburg saw unions replace traditional hiring corporations and take a major role in dealing with employers; in Sète this even involved a union shop. But in the big ports rationalization proceeded without steady opposition, with a result that workers had to abandon any desire for a return of personalized direction. The fact that rationalization may, after its first onslaught, have brought some benefits could have played a role as well. Certainly when these workers were ready to rise again, as in Marseilles after 1909 or on the British docks in 1911, they were much readier to pit their organization against that of the employers. The bitter, personalized disputes, against an individual hiring boss or captain, gave way to more structured, usually calmer struggles. British sailors in 1911 thus asked not that medical examinations be abolished but that they or the union be allowed to supply the doctor; they sought no return to personalized hiring but wanted control to be taken out of the shippers' office, to be shared at least by the union.37
A similar clash between experience of personalized direction and the reality of new business forms characterized other unskilled or semiskilled workers. Impressionistic evidence suggests that new women workers in the factories were extremely sensitive to personal grievances — more so than to any other problem on the job. We have suggested already that some found the factories a source of freedom, as against parental control or domestic service. But this very sense of
freedom created sensitivities when the factory proved disappointing. Charles Booth found that factory girls rarely complained about their work, pay, or even fines, but excoriated 'the foremen who treat us like animals.'38 A strike in a Nuremburg shoe company resulted when a foreman talked crudely to female workers, while several strikes in French textile companies raised similar grievances.39 Here, of course, it was the quality of personal treatment, rather than business structure, that most obviously triggered agitation. But unskilled workers generally responded more to personal examples of harshness than to the sources that might produce them. It remains true that exposure to new business forms brought large numbers of previously docile workers to a realization of new rights. In the case of women, the desire for individual dignity could turn against labor organizations as well. In 1906 female textile workers in Denton rejected a union membership campaign because the union had repeatedly insulted them and ignored their interests in the past.40 And for unskilled workers generally it would take time for the imperatives of organization to be sufficiently accepted to permit a coherent campaign against the new structure of employment. We can glimpse only the outlines of this evolution, precisely because it was incapable of producing elaborate records; but it was almost certainly the most poignant clash between worker expectations and the new world of business.
Factory workers, still most directly under the thumb of big business, had a variety of complaints about the changes in company structure. British miners suffered as their companies grew, for their foremen and managers were now more rigorously controlled by the Home Office. Not only did they work to keep costs down, but also they became less receptive to worker complaints. Young Welsh miners, returning from a year at Ruskin College, were appalled at the arrogance of the managers, for all their newly-polished manners. Foremen now referred workers to the managers, who stalled them in turn: 'What the bloody hell are you bothering me about?'41 Workers at English Ford resented the tight supervision under which they worked and the requirement that they wear badges. Locomotive manufacturers complained about the new system that compelled them to report to the company doctor and the manager after an illness, feeling this was a threat to their job; some felt that workers regarded as troublesome were dismissed for false medical reasons. And again the report of constant supervision, leaving workers in a state of continual agitation and suspense.42 German miners grew more discontented with their piece rate when it was set by a remote central office.43 Grievances of this sort can be multiplied, and they are
undeniably significant. But, impressionistic as they are, they fall short of a general, articulate resentment against new business forms per se. More commonly, workers displayed anxiety lest a new management change their conditions or attacked the personality of the employer directly. When a new combine took over several electrical utilities companies in Paris, workers struck to guarantee maintenance or improvement of conditions. Older miners in the South Ruhr worried about the big companies' insistence on closing unproductive pits, which forced them to move north to keep their jobs.44 More directly steel workers in Aachen attacked their multi-millionaire employer as a man who treated workers, 'not as men, but as tools,' while leather workers in Chaumont blasted one new director 'who was only a financier anxious to get rich as fast as possible.'45
Clearly, factory workers were troubled by new business structures. But they were divided in their response, to a greater extent than most other groups within the working class. Some of them found advantages in big business. Far more directed their attention to older issues, which rationalization exacerbated but did not cause. Partly because the structural changes imposed on factory workers were less radical than those in the artisanal or unskilled sectors, partly because the factories maintained an unusual repressive power, workers rarely tried to confront big business directly. Issues of principle were seldom posed, for workers judged big business as it affected them on the job, and these contacts were judged mainly by the personalities involved. Change produced some general uneasiness, and unquestionably the development of the labor movement in the factories owed much to this. But aside from some workers who spent much of their free time hating the employing class generally,46 the impact of rationalization was assessed mainly through a variety of intermediaries.
Divisions in reaction were partly a matter of personality. Others resulted from important differences among industries. The survey of German socialist workers, while producing a general distaste for dependence, suggested that metal workers were more troubled than their colleagues in textiles or the mines — for the good reason that the factory system was newest in this industry. The loudest laments about impersonality came from workers whose operations had previously been organized on a shop basis — like engineers or leather or woodworkers now forced into factories. A locksmith in Germany, village-trained, recoiled at the very sight of the factory's size: 'I didn't feel really at home in the big hall.'47 Others found their foremen, traditionally more like craft masters than employer representatives,
joining them in resisting the systems analysts who began to set standards in some big companies. Metal workers in the Rhineland resented the tone of the educated young bureaucrats who replaced the old masters in their concerns.48 British engineers were even more openly hostile, for they had a more precise small-shop tradition for reference. They nearly rebelled against being ordered about instead of being left free to determine their own tasks. Hence the blasts against 'policemen in various shapes and forms and under different names' who forced workers to be 'watched and dogged by a whole army of non-producers.'49 Textile workers, though also undergoing a rapid expansion of company size, did not evince this kind of anxiety, because they were already accustomed to a factory system. Change, then, rather than degree of bureaucratization was the key to specific response. Hence metallurgical workers, although their companies were five times as big as those of the machine workers and their treatment far less flexible, evinced little concern about business forms. Still other reactions resulted from differences in specific traditions and circumstances in the industry. Structural changes in the mines were less significant than those in metallurgy, but miners were far more likely to show uneasiness about a loss of freedom. A few even produced pleas for liberty similar to those of unskilled workers; thus miners in Montceau, rising against a local tyrant: 'We ask only our place in the sun.'50 Miners had a tradition of protest. They were residentially more dependent on the factory than many metallurgists, who could move more freely. Reaction to the employer depended on a host of factors beyond sheer company size or level of bureaucratization.
Important aspects of the rationalization process reduced tensions on the job, at least for some types of workers; this can help explain the incomplete correlation between business size and worker anxiety. Indirect ownership could reduce the visibility of employer wealth. British miners resented their managers putting on airs. Metal workers in Chambon attacked their employers' new cars. But the only rebellions against the trappings of wealth came in older settings, in factory towns where the manufacturer's mansion was evident for all to see. Absentee ownership caused uneasiness and a sense of loss of control, and unimaginable profits were often evoked in strike meetings; but the most specific targets were now rather remote. Big business could produce more positive satisfactions. Workers could gain prestige from association with a large firm. Many took pride in saying they worked for Zeiss, for example, a 'world-famous firm.' Most large companies had a group of stable, older workers who felt they had shared in the
company's success. Big business meant better-designed factories. British metallurgical workers welcomed the spread of corporations because the factories were better-built. Even in engineering, the fact that German plants had better facilities than their British counterparts helps explain the lower level of German unrest. Nor, of course, was big business necessarily impersonal. Again, German firms may have gained an advantage by treating individual workers, at least on occasion, with a certain dignity. Many trained their officials to take an interest in the workers, whom they called 'Mr.' when they listened to complaints. Of course this system was incomplete — state concerns were reputed to have developed it much more fully than private — and it created its own tensions for those workers who preferred a closer personal touch. But there may be a significant contrast with Britain, where big business tended to sweat a local manager instead of providing him with an adequate staff, leaving him in personal contact with his workers but without the time to know much about them. In Ruhr mines the foreman-to-worker ratio actually increased under bigger business; foremen had 53 workers under their charge in the 1890s and only 49 in 1907, so that in a literal sense personal contacr increased.51
Certainly rationalization tended to reduce the personal authority of workers' direct supervisers, and it was an interesting test of reactions, to bureaucratization to see if this was perceived as a benefit. German machine plants began hiring engineers to set piece rates, so that 'Calculation Departments' replaced foremen in this operation. A number of complaints resulted. Workers criticized the stiffness of the system, where rates were set by people not actually on the job. Turners in the Borsig company struck in 1897, seeking individual worker-employer agreements on each piece instead of the Kalkultionsburo, and the movement spread to some other companies. But the result was interesting; initial employer resistance gave way, not to a return of personalized direction, but to a modification of the complaint procedure; worker-management committees could now hear grievances over the appropriateness of piece rates.52 One new structure thus supplemented another. More generally the limitation of personal initiative on the part of immediate supervisors found fairly wide favor. Krupp had 15 supervisors to make sure foremen actually paid the wage levels the company set, and to prevent foremen from forcing workers to do gardening or other service jobs for them. The piece rate itself was replaced in some British steel plants by divisional determination of pay rates, and the workers seemed to welcome this. The Kalkultionsburos generally reduced complaints about bad treatment
and arbitrary action in the German factories.53
Workers did not of course write hymns to the virtues of big business. Satisfied workers rarely leave records at all, their existence being noted most commonly by self-interested outsiders, so it is risky to emphasize either their number or the extent of their satisfaction. Examinatio n of the kinds of workers most vocally hostile to their employers does suggest that personal tensions, more than impersonal ones, were most productive of grievances and that rationalization, intelligently carried through, could actually answer some of the workers' desire for fair standards of treatment. Tension was greatest, then, where big business grew without changing the chain of command, so that a foreman, still expected to serve as something of a friend and adviser, was turned into a driver of men. Incomplete rationalization, of the sort endemic ia the mines and many engineering firms as opposed to the really large units of employment, caused most disputes.
In fact the most direct clash between workers and employers had little to do with rationalization at all, though its implications may illuminate aspects of the worker reaction. Paternalism continued to characterize the approach many manufacturers took toward their labor force. It was less prevalent in England than on the Continent, and certainly far more powerful in heavy industry than in textiles; but its influence was widely felt. Paternalism involved a network of benefits to the workers. Silesian mines offered canteens and consumer co-operatives, company schools, libraries, and holiday camps, topping it all off with a free 'Arbeiterfreund' subscription and calendar and an annual picnic. French miners received pension programs (mutually contributory), medical service and drugs plus support when ill, and — again the personal touch, with political overtones - twelve francs for each son's first communion and a tip on the Sainte-Barbe holiday. The total cost in 1900 was over 200 francs per worker, a. full sixth of the annual money wage. Company housing continued to spread in the mines (even in parts of Britain) and the metallurgical centers. In 1883, 12 percent of all Ruhr miners were housed by the companies (and provided with gardens and stalls for pigs and goats); in 1900, despite the huge growth in the labor force, the figure was 21 percent. The metallurgical firms in French Lorraine provided reasonably comfortable housing for up to 65 percent of the labor force. Older paternalistic companies, like Le Creusot, added new benefits such as showers and refectories to their long list of programs.54
The carrot could not conceal the stick, for the benefits were intended to create a docile, stable labor force. Not only housing but
also pension rights were lost if a worker left his company. At an extreme, the Lorraine metallurgical firms charged their workers so much in dues and fees for the company store that many were in debt to their own employers. Workers in many companies, even in factory towns in England, could not contemplate leaving their firms to defy the manufacturers, for they stood to lose too much. Merely a complaint could bring dismissal; eviction of troublemakers was frequent in British as well as Continental mines. And the paternalistic approach involved outright interference in workers' activities off the job. Some British engineering firms set rules against gambling and swearing. In French factory towns paternalistic employers typically served as mayors, where they could try to forbid political meetings or even ban the entry of union organizers.55
Worker reaction in this situation was difficult. Even the basic outlook is hard to assess, for again there were obvious divisions. Some workers, for example, avoided company housing to preserve their liberty, but others welcomed the relief it provided their budget and did not complain. Workers themselves, in memoirs, reported that many of their colleagues judged the paternalistic employers good fellows and professed themselves satisfied. The most elaborate benefit programs reduced job-changing; Krupp, for example, suffered only 60 percent as much worker instability as other firms in the area. Is this a sign of active satisfaction or enserfment? It is impossible fully to decide. Clearly some workers did react less strongly than others, and a certain amount of positive choice was involved, whereby workers most eager for this kind of security would head for the most paternalistic firms. Other workers suffered their dependence keenly but felt powerless to complain, while still others found the means to protest.56
Strikes by quarry workers in France and Belgium were often explosions of anger against the dictatorship of a company town. Glass workers struck frequently against traditional employer controls such as a system of payments in kind. Miners still more persistently defied paternalism. The Blanzy company at Montceau was unusually heavy-handed. The company supported a variety of recreational associations and churches as well as the usual benefit programs. It also watched over the workers' habits and organized the labor force on behalf of the employer's political campaigns. Workers were screened on hiring for their political reliability and then watched over by an elaborate secret police. But in 1899 rebellion came, in the form of a massive strike; and from that point onward workers maintained strong interest in union and socialist activities, while radically reducing their rate of attendance
at church.57 Risings among metallurgical workers were far rarer. Workers at Le Creusot in 1899 struck for union recognition, as did metallurgists in Lorraine in 1905. Lorraine workers also attacked the system of company stores as a 'perpetual millstone' both for their budgets and for their freedom to organize. In each case the workers were defeated, many evicted and dismissed. But unlike the miners, who also frequently suffered defeat and retribution, their action had no aftermath; no subsequent unions formed, and there was no recurrence of the strike movement. Metallurgical employers thus were almost completely successful in maintaining the paternalistic stance, except in Britain where they did not attempt it seriously in the first place. In Germany as in France the unions were barely able to penetrate the metallurgical companies and never won the right to bargain collectively.58
The one concession the metallurgical companies (and also mines in the Ruhr, after 1905) made to possible discontent was the proliferation, of joint committees to deal with grievances. Workers initially responded with considerable suspicion. They feared employer control; even elected delegates often refused to speak, because they were resigned to employer dominance. And they properly sensed that most of the committees would be given no jurisdiction over important matters. In Germany, for example, many were confined to discussion of the benefit programs and sanitary measures, only infrequently being consulted on actual work conditions. Hence elections to the committees rarely drew much interest at first; in the German mines, only 11 percent of the eligible voters came to the polls in 1905. But participation tended to mount; many workers began to ask for committees in German metal works by the mid-1890s. Initially fearful of turning in complaints, workers began to come forward more readily. Even the committees in Le Creusot, though hand-picked by the employer after the great strike, handled several hundred complaints a year over wages and conditions, more often than not ruling in the workers' favor.59 Joint committees in a Belgian metallurgical factory reported on several dangerous pieces of equipment, a harsh foreman, the need for a second bassin of water to speed up the cooling of metals, and the desirability of a larger coffee heater in each lounge — prompting one worker to tell an investigator: 'Gradually we perceived we all had the same interest — the good functioning of the enterprise; there resulted a very marked improvement in our relations with management, which can even lead to a m ore complete collaboration in production.'60
Clearly, workers were not ready for a complete rebellion against a
barely-modified paternalism. The greater size of metallurgical companies, enhancing their power to control, helps explain the relative docility of workers in the industry in comparison with miners. And many workers, blocked from unionization by employer repression, turned to socialist voting as their only protest outlet.61 Paternalism unquestionably caused great tension. Efforts to attack it failed repeatedly — hence a high rate of strike defeats in most industries in which paternalism prevailed, including German (but not French) mining; workers could only learn caution from this pattern. But the checkered response to paternalism was not simply the result of repression. Some workers could find more than material benefits from the paternalistic system, for it could correspond to the rather traditional standards of fair dealing and suggestions of some personal interest which they expected from employers. A minority in all the Continental countries joined yellow unions, intimidated by their employers but in some cases also convinced that class conflict was not the right approach. Far more workers, including many who were unionized, were dissuaded by the various aspects of paternalism from direct attack on the bases of employer control in the firms.
Paternalism unquestionably complicated the reaction to business rationalization. It was an old system, dating from the beginnings of industrialization. Growing worker uneasiness resulted less from changes in the system than from increased consciousness of rights. In this sense the ambiguous reaction to paternalism resembles the artisanal response to the traditional masters' controls, simply writ large. Business growth heightened the impact of paternalism. More workers were now grouped under a single paternalistic roof. Employer associations spread the paternalistic principles of control more widely. Manufacturers' organizations worked to break strikes and blacklist troublemakers — in Germany even using employment agencies to weed out dissidents — and while their effectiveness was limited they added to the difficulties of response.62 Most important, the persistence of paternalism showed that manufacturers' own attitudes were evolving far less quickly than the actual business structures.63 That they still had the power to maintain this system of controls could not conceal the growing challenge. Innovations such as the joint committees responded in part to new worker demands and even more to the need to compensate for the growing impersonality of management, which paternalism had intended to avoid by its provision of favors and individual supervision. But change was less important than persistence, forcing those workers most concerned about their relationship with management to deal with the
general issue of power rather than the more specific effects of rationalization.
For most factory workers, the actual problems of relationship to management were largely personal. Paternalism may have encouraged this in the bigger plants, because of the stress on the employer's personal responsibility rather than problems of organization of cont rol. In industries such as textiles and even engineering, most companies remained small enough that the personal element could more legitimately seem predominant. Personal issues themselves reflected the changes in industrial organisation to a significant degree, but indirectly and only as filtered by the character of the people involved.
Foremen were the key to the worker's perception of management. General issues of company size or paternalism or even the character of the director or owner normally paled before the question of what the foreman was like. A good socialist in the Ruhr might realize that foremen were themselves exploited by capitalism, but far more justly blamed the individual right above them. And here, precisely because of the personalization of work supervision, a host of reactions was possible. Many workers judged the endurability of their job by the personal atmosphere surrounding them, and the foreman was a key here. A friendly greeting could make all the difference. For most factory workers foremen were the agents of hiring and firing. They set the pay rates and assigned the work, so that many workers believed, with considerable justification, that whether they earned well or not was entirely up to the foreman's assignments and his calculation of pay. In small companies foremen also kept records on the job, informing workers of pay rates only orally. And the worker depended to a considerable extent on the foreman's good opinion for his own judgement of the work, which is why he was so quick to react to insults as well as favoritism and demonstrable bad treatment.64
Complaints against foremen vastly outweigh praise in the available records. But individual foremen were greatly admired. Not a few strikes resulted from the transfer or dismissal of a man regarded as fair in his dealings. Even in the larger companies elements of the traditional master-skilled worker relationship remained, so that one observer described the relationship as 'half cordial, half subordinate.'65 For some skilled workers the foremen's role was almost a spin-off of their own direction of subordinates, which could still include hiring and determination of pay. The ambiguous position of the foreman was reflected in a number of efforts to keep him in the union. In 1905 nine unionized machine adjusters in a Paris automobile plant struck against a
harsh new foreman, asking initially for no supervision at all; a compromise was finally reached when the employer asked them to select one of their own number. In the British cotton industry foremen were almost invariably chosen from the union in the 1890s. And generally skilled workers wanted to be sure that their supervisor was well qualified. Some might not want the responsibility themselves - this was claimed in German textiles — but for others it was a sought-after chance for mobility and workers generally wanted to make sure the man knew his job and that he rose appropriately from the ranks. Correspondingly many foremen sided with workers against employers, for as a breed they remained uncertain of where their loyalties lay.66
This close relationship was the basis for many a dispute. Steel smelters in Gravesend criticized their company in 1914 for bringing a foreman in from outside instead of promoting from the ranks. Urban workers might resent a rural-born supervisor. A foreman, once a colleague, could easily disappoint his fellows by acting high and mighty and siding consistently with the boss. If they served as strikebreakers it would be all the worse. Many were unreceptive to workers' complaints and suggestions, thus demeaning the whole job as well as making it more difficult. Favoritism was often claimed. French workers were particularly vulnerable here, because of the country's political and religious disputes; many felt discriminated against by Catholic foremen in the assignment of work. But the complaint was widespread, particularly in the mines. Insults and beatings were another sore point, for many foremen were harsh and overburdened.67 A German mine strike broke out when a foreman berated a worker - 'You idiot, you pitiable scum'68 — while in a metallurgical company in Saint-Etienne a series of strikes resulted when a new foreman 'dishonored' the workers by telling them they were too slow.69 In the Belgian Hasard mining company workers struck against foremen chosen not from the best workers but according to their sycophancy or their kinship with employers. Women workers were often sensitive; shoe workers in Knighton Fields moved against a 'nagging' forewoman. And direct violence against hated foremen was not uncommon.70 For, quite apart from the material aspects of the relationship, foremen could draw upon themselves the full resentment against dependence which many workers felt so keenly: 'I once gave the foreman the pleasure of giving, me notice. I'll never do it again; I never want to give such joy to any foreman again.'71
Rationalization unquestionably worsened relations between workers and foremen, without removing the highly variable personal factor. The
number of foremen increased, for supervision and record-keeping gained new importance. In industries such as textiles Germany and Belgium had long maintained a higher ratio of foremen than Britain and France, putting one in each department or each room of the factory and leaving workers little initiative, so the change probably had its greatest impact in the latter countries; but it was generally felt. Older British workers particularly resented supervision by interlopers who, they believed, did not really know the work. Foremen were put more clearly under the employer's authority, and were fired when they did not suit. British engineering firms began to insist that foremen not "be part of the workers' union. For their part, many foremen began to view themselves more distinctly as professionals, without the possibility of rising to their own business but with interests quite separate from those of the workers. Increasingly they adopted a distinctive, middle-class style of dress. In all probability fewer were recruited from the ranks or were sent to technical schools for training, which helped create a separate mentality. Rationalizing companies sought more highly edu cated supervisors or brought outsiders in from more advanced competitors. Several strikes in the shoe industry resulted from the introduction of a foreman with experience in engineering shops, for fear that he would force the pace. Above all, foremen were the agents responsible for raising productivity, as they were paid a bonus for output above a certain level. Here, most clearly, rationalization hit workers through personal intermediaries.72
The whole development of rationalization in practice discouraged many factory workers from adopting appropriate counter-measures, which among other things accounts for the lack of correspondence b e-tween the size and sophistication of company organization and the level of formal protest. The personal element loomed too large, so that whether satisfied or not workers had little immediate sense of the changes in business structure that were in fact shaping their lives. Undoubtedly the rise of unionization and strikes reflected more impersonal management, but for the most part indirectly, as workers found it difficult to express grievances in their relationships with employers except on the personal level.
Where there was a craft tradition, as in British engineering, some unions tried to adopt the artisanal approach and set their own rules, to counteract remote management. The effort failed, for the companies were too big to control in this manner. Thus efforts to regulate job conditions by the British boilermakers' and engineers' groups foundered. More logical still was agitation for collective bargaining, as a
counterweight to a powerful management. This did mean the creation of yet another impersonal agency, and workers could easily feel this simply added to their problems. Many British railwaymen, for example, criticized the formal conciliation procedure developed after 1907 because it was far less effective than the older system of direct petitions to management. And the general rebellion against the rigidity and delays in grievance arrangements in Britain after 1910, on the railways and elsewhere, owed something to this sentiment, for attachment to personalized relationships ran deep. But the clearer difficulty with most collective bargaining efforts in factory industry was that they could not influence the actual impact of rationalization within the workplace.
Employers vigorously resisted collective bargaining in most cases, and certainly any intrusion into the determination of conditions on the job. A Lyons manufacturer put his case succinctly: 'There would be two powers in the factory instead of one.'73 Even in Britain efforts to control the work of supervisors normally met with refusal and in some cases outright dismissal. The latter was the fate, for example, of Scottish miners who asked that checkweighers be appointed to review the piece payment determinations of the foremen.74
On the Continent collective bargaining was rare in factory industry. Worker interest was present — union recognition figured prominently in the major French metallurgical strikes, for example — but it rarely bore fruit. In Germany by 1913 there were but three agreements in the mines, covering 82 workers, and only 1376 in metals and machine building (covering 207, 472 workers), the vast majority in the smaller shops. Less than 16,000 textile workers were covered, less than 6,000 chemical workers. The pattern is clear. The approach that worked quite well in the crafts had almost no impact in industry. Employer resistance was the most obvious cause, but the difficulty of developing worker unity over the question of power in industry played a role as well.75 The situation was less bleak in France and Belgium. Collective bargaining existed in the coal mines and in many textile factories, though metallurgy was rigorously excluded. It could be widely hailed. Verviers workers saluted their first agreement: 'Ended, henceforward, the reign of the master's whim . .. Labor has just won a Parliament at Verviers, and the laws that will be decreed there will be applicable by and for everyone.'76 But rarely did collective bargaining in factories include clear grievance procedures. A few individual mining companies in Belgium had arbitration groups, which removed the need to strike against foremen. The Graulhet leather factory established an elaborate procedure in 1910, by which unions and employers would discuss any
grievance case, during which foremen were prohibited from firing any workers involved while workers agreed not to strike. But here the craft tradition gave some basis for the approach. After the 1910 railroad strike French companies set up local joint committees, with worker delegates elected, to transmit grievances, which management hailed as a 'simple and rapid means for workers to express their desires.' Generally, however, collective bargaining meant periodic meetings to discuss wages and hours, not to deal with on-the-job complaints. This was the case in the famous Arras agreements in the French mining industry, for example, and in most textile plants where bargaining was accepted at all. Unions tried to take individual cases in hand, but there was no systematic means to do so. And in contrast to the artisanal situation, there were no union delegates on the spot. German printing shops, for example, were supervised by elected worker representatives (Vertrauensmanner) who dealt with any dispute over the execution of the bargaining agreement and were protected from dismissal if they ruled against the company. Rarely could factory workers claim anything remotely comparable, which meant that they were little better off, in terms of on-the-spot relations with management, than workers in the paternalistic firms who had only a tame committee for appeals. Small wonder that sweeping structural demands, within the company or industry, made little sense and that workers viewed even many tirade union efforts with suspicion.77
The situation in Britain was obviously somewhat different. Stronger, older unions and a more pervasive defense of skills within the factory created a situation more analogous to that of the crafts. Fluctuations in union membership, which could mount to over a hundred percent annually in the industrial unions on the Continent, were less great. Formal demands for union recognition were much more common, and agreements covered hundreds of thousands of workers in mining, metallurgy, railroads, and textiles. Of 2,400,000 workers under agreements in 1910, 900,000 were miners, 500,000 railwaymen, 460,000 textiles workers, and 230,000 metal workers — a majority or near-majority in all the industries involved. Relatedly, it may be argued that English employers were somewhat milder than their Continental counterparts. Paternalism was less extensive and efforts t o form yellow-unions less widespread. A German worker living in England commented on the same contrast more personally, noting that English employers regarded workers as human beings, less as commodities. They had learned to accept strikes as a normal part of industrial life, so that retaliation, though not unknown, was less common. Worker initiative
on the job was encouraged, in contrast to Germany where a more rigid hierarchy was held responsible for preventing worker suggestions on the job.78 The early experience of British employers, their liberal political culture, perhaps even their waning entrepreneurial zeal, created an atmosphere in which workers could be treated with greater equality, at least in comparison with the authoritarian approach of Continental manufacturers.79 The possibility of a distinctive national culture should not be excluded, though it is already clear that it should be applied only to skilled workers; British employers treated unskilled dockers more harshly than was true on the Continent.80 But a persuasive argument is still possible concerning the skilled group, which had long been of prime importance in British industry. Lower rates of job supervision as well as the prevalence of collective bargaining show that the argument has some validity. But rationalization was cutting into tolerance, and the very incidence of s-trikes over union recognition should warn against too benign an interpretation. British factory workers were being brought under stricter supervision, even if the style remained somewhat less bureaucratic than that of Germany or Belgium. New controls in many cases were meant to compensate for the country's reduced level of technological change. Hence, while granting the far higher rate of strikes involved, it is worth noting that their rate of success was no greater than those in France or Germany. And collective bargaining agreements, though u ndeniably important, usually did not deal with on-the-job control. The steel workers had a joint committee for disputes. Lancashire cotton workers had widely-traveling union agents to take care of individual grievances. But again, only craft workers had representatives on the spot, as in printing where the 'Chapel Father' served as a recognized spokesman. Other unions worked for similar arrangements, and the growing popularity of the shop stewards' movement right before World War I attested to the desire to flesh out the existing collective bargaining system. But for most British factory workers during most of the pre-war period, collective bargaining meant, as in Continental industry, periodic negotiations on wages and hours. British workers were little more protected against the impact of rationalization; foremen were no more under control.81
In this situation the symptoms of grievance against management were typically indirect and ineffective. In France, Belgium, and Germany agitation against individuals was the most immediate expression of hostility, and it proved difficult to bring this under control. In both Belgium and France the percentage of strikes asking that foremen, managers (or, more rarely, hated workers) be fired
tended to go up with time, while in Germany it remained stable, despite the fact that these were among the most difficult of all strikes to win. In France, for example, strikes for dismissals failed 52 percent of the time between 1900 and 1913, as against an overall failure rate of 42 percent. Admittedly the strikes were small on the average, and often brief; in Belgium, at least, they showed some tendency to grow smaller after 1900, so that the percentage of strikers involved was more distinctly lower than the percentage of strikes. But generally, apart from the official statistics, a large number of strikes that ultimately produced broader demands were launched because of a personal dispute, and there are few signs of change in this regard.82 Strikes strictly over dismissals, which alone can be measured with any precision, clustered in the industries where companies were large and the change in business structure most rapid — in metals above all, then in mining and the lighter factory industries, followed at some distance by the crafts. (See Table V).83 Yet this was a primitive kind of strike precisely because of its dependence on a personal spark. It reflected the tensions rationalization caused, but it did not bring the process itself into basic question. Union leaders of all ideological stripes warred against the personal strike, save where the justification was unusually clear; they recognized how likely it was that these strikes would draw only a handful of workers and then fail. Yet, as the persistence of these strikes demonstrates, workers continued to use the personal attack as a means of expressing their anger. The form was primitive but the purpose was not: outside of the crafts, employer resistance had largely prevented any more structured statement of the kind of rage that arose commonly on the job. Correspondingly, in Britain, where collective bargaining had seemingly penetrated farther into factory industry, the wave of unrest that developed after 1909 in challenging the superficiality of these agreements brought the personal strike to a new level of sophistication. Particularly on the railroads, thousands of workers walked out several times to protect the rights of an individual against management. When a Newcastle driver, not due on duty for thirty hours, was demoted for drunkenness on his own time, 35 00 workers struck despite union opposition. In 1913 a guard refused a foreman's order to add three cars to a train, because he knew full well the train lacked the brakes to handle the load; again agitatLon developed, though this time union backing won a company reversal.84 Even here, workers were not directly attacking the business structure, but through the personal focus they expressed much of their frustration.
Table V Strikes for Dismissals (or More General Personal Issues)
A. France
% of such strikes in major industries |
|
Average |
11.8 |
Transport |
9.4 |
Metals |
19.8 |
Mining |
13.9 |
Wood |
12.8 |
Construction |
9.3 |
Carpentry |
8.3 |
Leather |
13.7 |
Textiles |
11.2 |
Paper/Printing |
13.8 |
Chemicals |
11.5 |
Food Processing |
8.1 |
Quarries |
13.0 |
B. France—% over time
1899 |
10.4 |
1900 |
10.3 |
1901 |
15.0 |
1902 |
13.3 |
1903 |
11.4 |
1904 |
12.0 |
1905 |
16.1 |
1906 |
10.6 |
1907 |
11.9 |
1908 |
10.8 |
1909 |
12.1 |
1910 |
13.0 |
1911 |
10.3 |
1912 |
13.0 |
1913 |
12.2 |
C. Belgium—% over time
Strikes |
Strikers |
|
16.0 |
4.8 |
1900 |
24.7 |
15.2 |
1901 |
31.5 |
24.5 |
1902 |
21.4 |
17.5 |
1903 |
22.2 |
30.4 |
1904 |
20.3 |
4.4 |
1905 |
18.3 |
7.7 |
1906 |
14.4 |
11.6 |
1907 |
24.7 |
18.2 |
1908 |
19.3 |
26.0 |
1909 |
27.8 |
8.3 |
1910 |
23.0 |
8.2 |
1911 |
27.4 |
8.5 |
1912 |
28.2 |
20.8 |
1913 |
22.8 |
13.8 |
average all years |
D. Germany - % over time
Strikes |
Strikers |
|
1900 |
19.6 |
_ |
1901 |
22.6 |
19.1 |
1902 |
19.1 |
13.2 |
1903 |
23.7 |
17.7 |
1904 |
22.6 |
16.6 |
1905 |
10.2 |
6.4 |
1906 |
21.9 |
15.4 |
1907 |
19.8 |
11.8 |
1908 |
21.6 |
17.2 |
1909 |
21.0 |
21.1 |
1910 |
18.6 |
11.9 |
1911 |
21.7 |
15.4 |
1912 |
19.0 |
2.3 |
1913 |
20.5 |
10.8 |
average all years |
20.9 |
16.8 |
Yet the whole interaction between workers and management remained inconclusive, at almost all levels of industry. It is accurate to sense that the recorded disputes between workers and management, at whatever level, are but the tip of an iceberg, But we must be careful that we do not exaggerate the dimensions of the iceberg. Workers were not, en masse, in direct rebellion against rationalization. At various levels of industrial organization some workers derived benefits from it; in the crafts, particularly, they were able to modify its impact by new or expanded organizations of their own. And quite widely, if most noticeably in the factories, the fact that personalities more than systems were under judgement obscured any general issues. Variety pervaded every industry; even in the mines, some companies were known for their fairness and generosity and certainly within companies there were wide differences from unit to unit depending on the foreman involved. Hence personal disputes could rarely spill beyond the boundaries of a single company — the unrest in Britain right before World War I had no analogue in other periods or areas — and typically involved only a small group of workers within the company.85
In a sense, then, workers had not been called upon to adjust to impersonal organization in the abstract; there were always people involved. And this lent some unity to the working class despite the tremendous differences in structure from one industry to the next. In small shops as in paternalistic factories many workers grew increasingly conscious of their dignity, but never with such unanimity that the whole organizational structure was challenged. All workers were dependent; this, more than distinctions in levels of rationalization, produced response. Factory workers were unquestionably more likely to challenge their dependence than small-shop workers, but they were no more able, as a group, to deal with organizational trends than were barbers or bakers able to rise up against their restrictive board and room arrangements. In addition to repression, each group reflected divisions over how dependence was felt. Young workers were quicker to take offense in every category. They were less trammeled by family obligations and may have found in factories and shops unattractive similarities to a parental domination which they had already learned to resent.86 But youth did not rule, and so the working class remained divided and ambiguous in its response to management at eve ry level.
But this does not mean, finally, that the penchant for personal rather than structural judgements was random. From the crafts to the factories workers had certain standards by which they measured employers. Fairness and competence were expected, and personal
disputes normally involved a belief that one or both had been violated. A strike in a mine near Liège broke out when a worker was fined for refusing to use a defective spike; workers realized that the foreman was incompetent through his insistence. British cotton workers, in insisting that bad materials were the manufacturer's fault, claimed it 'unreasonable' for them to take a loss as a result. If hierarchy was accepted, it was on certain conditions.87 And here, unquestionably, rationalization seemed to be changing the rules of the game. Growing companies, more heavily bureaucratized, became increasingly concerned about production standards in the abstract. In the process they imposed or tried to impose procedures on workers that were judged unfair and unprofessional. Here was where the real battleground lay at the workplace.
Notes
1. Christliche Metallarbeiter-Verband Deutschlands, Protokoll uber die Verhandlungen der sechsten Generalversammlung (Duisberg, 1910), 44; see also Seymour Lipset, Political Man (Garden City, N.Y., lt960); Standish Meachem, ' "The Sense of an Impending Clash" : English Working-Class Unrest before the First World War,' American Historical Review (1972), 1343—64. As against this two recent studies of strikes confirm the complexity of employer-worker interaction. Edward Shorter and Charles Tilly, (Strikes in France, 1830-1968 Cambridge, 1974) find indirect correlation between comnany size and strike frequency, and although they do posit a link between size and unionization this bears most clearly on developments after 1918. Michelle Perrot, Les Ouvriers en Grève (Paris, 1974), II, more directly stresses the personal factor, in relation with foremen, over any abstract relationship.
2. Paul Bureau, Le Contrat du travail (Paris, 1902), 82; Adelhard Kopp, Die Jugendgeschichte einer Arbeiterin (Munich, 1930), 69 ff.
3. R. Seebohm Rowntree, Land and Labour: Lessons from Belgium (London, 1911), 85.
4. August Lôhr, Beitrdge zur Wurdigung der Akkord-Lohnmethode (Mônchen-Gladbach, 1912), passim; Lipset, Political Man.
5. Martin Offenbacher, Der Ausstand und" die Aussperrung in der Bayerischen Metallindustrie (Nuremberg, 1905), 19.
6. Jules Lekeu, A Travers le Centre; Croquis et moerus; enquête ouvrière et industrielle (Brussels, 1907), 27.
7. Paul Gohre, Drei Monate Fabrikarbeiter (Leipzig, 1913), 115.
8. Peter N- Stearns, Revolutionary Syndicalism and French Labor (New Brunswick, 1971), passim; Niedersàchsische Staatsarchiv
(Hannover); Polizeiakten des Oberpràsidenten der Provinz Hannover (Hann. 122a XL), 71, report of 1906. 9. Adolf Levenstein, Die Arbeiterfrage (Munich, 1913), 196 and passim.
10. Cyr. van Overbergh, La Grève générale (Brussels, 1913), passim.
11. M. Pappenheim et al., Die Lage der in der Seeschiffahrtbeschâftigen Arbeiter (Leipzig, 1903), II, 580; Stearns, Syndicalism; Emile Vandervelde, L. de Brouclcère, and L. Vandersmissen, La Grève générale en Belgique (avril, 1 913) (Paris, 1914); John Laslett, Labor and the Left: A Study of Socialist and Radical Influences in the American Labor Movement (New York, 1970).
12. Ministère de l'industrie et du travail, Recensement général de la population, 1890-1910 (Brussels, 1892-1912); Census of England and Wales (1891, 1901, 1911); Ministère du commerce (later, Ministère du travail), Résultats statistiques du recensement général de la population, 1896—1911; Statistik des: deutschen Reichs, Neue Folge, 102-119 and 202-222. See also George Neuhaus, Die deutsche Volkswirtschaft und ihre Wartdlungen im letzten Vierteljahrhundert, 2v. (Munich, 1913) and Jan Lewinski, L'Evolution industrielle de la Belgique (Brussels, 1911).
13. Bernhard Schilbach, 'Arbeitstarifvertrâge in der Holzindustrie,' Jahrbucher fur Nationalôkonomie (1910), 807 ff.
14. Ministère du travail, Résultats statistiques du recensement général, 1911; A. L. Levine, Industrial Retardation in Britain, (London, 1967).
15. Ludwig Hagen, Die Lederwaren-Industrie in Offenbach am Main und Umgebung (Karlsruhe, 1905), 33 ff.
16. Ministère de l'industrie et du travail, Les Industries à domicile, VI (Brussels, 1904), passim.
17. Fédération d'industrie des travailleurs de l'habillement, Ville Congrès national (Avigonon, 1911), 94.
18. Paul Flattau, Das Schlossergewerbe zu Berlin (Leipzig, 1916); Otto Hommer, Die Entwicklung und Tàtigkeit des deutschen Metallarbeiterverbandes (Berlin, 1912), passim; Michael Gasteiger, Die gelben Gewerkschaften (Munich, 1909); Laurent Deschene, L'avènement du régime syndical à Verviers (Paris, 1906); Jean Vial, La Coutume chapelière (Paris, 1941), 283; Otto Jeidels, Die Methoden der Arbeiterentl'ohnung in der rheinischwestfàlischen Eisenindustrie (Berlin, 1907); Generalkommis sion der Gewerkschaften Deutschlands, Correspondenzblatt, L912; Alan Fox, 'Industrial Relations in Nineteenth-Century Birmingham,' Oxford Economie Papers (1955), 57-70.
19. Deschene, Avènement, 515.
20. Paul Arndt, éd., Die Heimarbeit (Jena, 1909), I, 177.
21. Richard Calwer, Das Kost- und Logiswesen in Handwerk (Berlin, 1908), passim; Verband der Backer, Konditoren, und -verwandten Berufsgenossen Deutschlands, Jahrbuch, 1908; Konrad Frick, 'Zur Lage der Bàckereiarbeiter,' Die Neue Zeit (1904-05), 624030;
Zentralverband der Backer, Konditoren und verwandten Berul'sgenbssen Deutschiands, Jahrbuch, 1908;Konrad Frick, 'Zur Generalversammlung, 1905.
22. Generalkommission der Gewerskschaften Deutschiands, Correspondenzblatt, 23 April 1904; a notice put up by non-unionized bakers.
23. Bâckerverband Rheinland, Offizieller Bericht iiber die Verhandlungen des XVI. Verbandstages (Cologne, 1901), 5.
24. Confederation générale du travail, XlVe Congrès national corporatif (Bourges, 1904), 128; Alexander Wende, Die Konzentrationsbewegung bei dem deutschen Gewerkschaften (Berlin, 1913), 153 ff.; A. E. Musson, The Typographical Association (London, 1954), 93. (The figures in British printing suggest less concentration than in France or Germany — again pointing to the impossibility of correlating company structure in the crafts with overall levels of industrialization.)
25. Raymond Joran, L'Organisation syndicale dans l'industrie des bâtiments (Paris, 1914), 183; 'Onlooker' (A. A. Telling), Hitherto (London, 1930), 55.
26. Labour Gazette, passim; H. A. Clegg et al., A History of British Trade Unionism since 1889 (Oxford, 1964), I, 154; Raymond Postgate, The Builders History (London, n.d.); Revolutionary Syndicalism, 89-90.
27. Albeijt Huglin, Der Tarifvertrag zwischen Arbeitgeber und Arbeitnehmer (Stuttgart, 1906).
28. Dora Lande, Die Arbeits- und Lohnverhàltnisse in der Berliner Maschinenindustrie zu Beginn des 20. Jahrhunderts (Leipzig, 1910), passim; H. Kôppe, 'Die Fortschritte des Arbeitstarifvertrages,' Jahrbùcher fur Nationalôkonomie (1912), 362 ff.
29. Charles Booth, Life and Labour of the People in London (London, 1893), II; Edward G. Howarth and Mona Wilson, West Ham (London, 1907), 221 ff.; Pappenheim II.
30. Le Peuple, 22 September 1909.
31. Ambroise Colin, La Navigation commerciale au XIXe siècle (Paris, 1901), 417; André Sayous, Les Grèves de Marseilles en 1904 (Paris, 1904), 62 and passim; Labour Gazette, July 1911; Conrad Miss, 'Der Kampf der Seeleute,' Die Neue Zeit (1905-06), 466-73.
32. National Union of Seamen, History (in manuscript at the Union office).
33. Archives de la préfecture de police de la Seine B/a 1359, report of 6 October 1909, on a carters' strike; Adrien Veber, 'Mouvement social,' La Revue socialiste (1901), 361, 362, statement by sailors in the 1901 strikes, in Le Havre and Marseilles; Archives nationales (France) F7-13887 on strikes in the merchant marine; Archives départementales de Seine-et-Oise, M, Strikes 1909, on the quarry workers; Sayous, Grèves, 10.
34. Ferdinand Tônnies, 'Der Hamburger Strike von 1896—97,' Archiv
fur Gesetzgebung und Politik (1897), 673—720; S&yous, Grèves; Antony Schoux, Des Grèves maritimes (Paris, 1910); Llewellyn Smith and Vaughn Nash, The Story of the Dockers' Strike (London, 1889).
35. Stearns, Syndicalism, 85; E. H. Phelps Brown, The Growth of British Industrial Relations (London, 1959); Labour Gazette, July 1911.
36. Booth, Life, IV, 310.
37. Verein deutscher Schuhmacher, Protokoll ùber die Verhandlungen der Generalversammlung, 1903.
38. Barbara Drake, Women in Trade Unions (London, 19 21).
39. Wil Jon Edwards, From the Valley I Came (London, 1958), 204; Public Records Office HO 218781, reports on mines strikes.
40. Alfred Williams, Life in the Railway Factory (London, 1915), 304; see also United Kingdom Pattern Makers' Association, Monthly Trade Reports, 1914.
41. Gerhard Adelmann, éd., Quellensammlung zur Geschichte der sozialen Betriebsverfassung; Ruhrindustrie unter besonderer Berùcksichtigung des Industrie und Handelskammerbezirks Essen (Bonn, 1960), I, passim.
42. Gaston Guirard, P'tite Gueule (Paris, 1938), 156, Aufsàtze ùber den Streik der Bergarbeiter im Ruhrgebiet (Schriften der Gesell-schaft fur Soziale Reform) (Jena, 1907), 5. '
43. Arbeiterausstand beim Aachener Hutten-Actien-Verein (Aachen, 1906), 19.
44. Adolf Levenstein, Die Arbeiterfrage (Munich, 1912), 107 ff.
45. Richard Ehrenberg, 'Schwàche und Starkung neuzeitlicher Arbeitsgemeinschaften,' Thunen-Archiv (1911), 514.
46. J. Zitzlaff, Arbeitsgleiderung in Maschinenbau-Unternehmungen (Jena, 1913); Jeidels, Methoden.
47. James B. Jefferys, The Story of the Engineers (Lozndon, 1946), 172.
48. Bouveri, 'La Grève des Montceau-les-Mines,' Musée s-ocial (190 1), 328.
49. Moritz Bromme, Lebensgeschichte einer modernen Fabrikarbeiters (Leipzig, 1905), 246.
50. Heinrich Reichelt, Die Arbeitsverhàltnisse in einem Berliner Grossbetrieb der Maschinenindustrie (Berlin, 19 06); Jeidels, Methoden ; Max Eichhorst, Die Lage der Bergarbeiter im Saargeb let (Eisleben, 1901); Jack Owen, Ironmen (Middlesbrough, n.d.), 107.
51. Lande, Arbeitsverhàltnisse, passim; Waldemar Jolko, Untersuchungen ùber die Entlôhnungsmethoden in der Berliner Metallindustrie (Berlin, 1911); Franz Sahulte, Die Entlôhnungsmethoden in der Berliner Maschinenindustrie (Berlin, 1906); Elaine Glovka Spencer, 'Between Capital and Labor: Supervisory Personnel in Ruhr Heavy Industry, Journal of Social History (1975).
52. Sidney Pollard, History of Labour in Sheffield (Liverpool, 1959),
229; Reichelt, Arbeitsverhàltnisse.
53. Adolf Gûnther and René Prévôt, Die Wohlfahrtseinrichtungen der Arbeitgeber in Deutschland und Frankreich (Leipzig, 1905), passim; Wilhelm Brepohl, Der Aufbau des Ruhrvolkes im Zuge der Ost-West Wanderung (Recklinghausen, 1948); Delcourt-Haillot, 'Les Avantages accordés aux ouvriers mineurs par les compagnies,' La Revue socialiste (1901), 830-35; Kônigliche Oberbergamt in Breslau, Arbeiterverhâltnisse und Arbeiter-Wohlfahrtseinrichtun-gen im oberschlesischen Industriebezirk (Breslau, 1904), passim.
54. Gùother and Prévôt, Wohlfahrtseinrichtungen, passim; R. M. R. Dehn, The German Cotton Industry (Manchester, 1913); J. H. Clapham, The Woollen and Worsted Industry (London, 1907), 184 ff.; Alphonse Merrheim, 'Le Mouvement ouvrier dans les bassins de Longwy,' Mouvement socialiste (1905), 432 ff.; Ludwig Radloff, 'Die Lage der preussischer Eisenbahner,' Socialistische Monatshefte (1909), 1500-1505; Alphonse Merrheim, Les Serfs de Meurthe-et-Moselle,' Vie ouvrière (1910), 285.
55. Adelmann, Quellensammlung, passim; Karl A. Gabel, Kàmpfe und Werden (Sarrbrucken, 1921), passim; Friedrich Syrup, 'Studien ûber den industriellen Arbeitswechsel,' Thùnen-Archiv (1912), 261 ff.
56. J. Lapierre, 'La Grève des platrières du bassin de Paris,' Vie ouvrière (1912), 11-14; Amdédée Dunois, 'Mouvement ouvrier chez leg verriers,' Pages libres (1908), 1715; Paul Bureau, Montceau les Mines et le paternalisme (La Chapelle-Montligeon, 1900), 8, 12.
57. Merrheim, 'Longwy, 447 and passim; Schulte, Entlôhnungsmethoden.
58. Jeidels, Methoden; Max J. Koch, Die Bergarbeiterbewegung im Ruhrgebiet zur Zeit Wilhelms II (Dusseldorf, 1954); B. Bodenstein, 'Die Arbeiterausschùsse im rheinisch-westfâlischen Bergbau,' Glùckauf (1906), 525; Hans J. Teuteberg, Geschichte der industrieller Mitbestimmung in Deutschland (Tubingen, 1961), passim; Musée social: Annales (1912), 361.
59. Paul Henriot, L'Organisation pratique des rapports entre patrons et ouvriers; les conseils d'usine (Brussels, 1914), 39.
60. Leo Loubère, 'Coal Miners, Labor Relations, and Politics in the Lower Languedoc, 1880-1914,' Journal of Social History (1968), passim.
61. Reichelt, Arbeitsverhàltnisse, passim; Peter N. Stearns, 'Against the Strike Threat,: Employer Policy toward Labor Agitation in France, 1900-1914,' Journal of Modern History (1968), 474 ff.
62. Lawrence Schofer, 'Patterns of Worker Protest: Upper Silesia, 1865-1914,' Journal of Social History (1972), 447-63, discusses the persistence of paternalism in terms of the problem of inadequate employer modernization. For discussion of paternalism in its earlier stages see Reinhard Bendix, Work and Authority in Industry (New York, 1963) .and Sidney Pollard, The Genesis of Modern Management (Cambridge, 1964).
63. Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, 65; Lande, Arbeitsverhàltnisse; Phelps Brown, Growth, 110.
64. Gohre, Fabrikarbeiter, 86; Elisa Herrmann, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Wollhutsindustrie (Munich, 1912); Lande, Arbeitsverhàltnisse; Spencer, 'Between Capital,' passim.
65. Archives du préfecture de police de la Seine B/a 1384, report of September 1905; Cotton Times Monthly, 23 June 1893; Amalgamated Society of Engineers, Monthly Report, August 1913; Georg Werner, Ein Rumpel. Erzàhlung aus dem Leben der Bergarbeiter (Berlin, 1930), 12.
66. British Steel Smelters, Mill, Iron and Tinplate Workers Association, Monthly Report, March 1914; Heinrich Herkner, Problème der Arbeiterpsychologie (Leipzig, 1912); Korrespondent fur Deutschlands Buchdrucker und Schriftsgiesser, 1907; Voix du peuple, 16 February 1913.
67. Vorstand des deutschen Bergarbeiterverbandes, Der Bergarbeiterstreik und die Untersuchungskommissionen (Berlin, 1905), 3.
68. Archives départementales de la Loire 92 M 202.
69. National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives, Monthly Report February 1913; Le Peuple, 3 January 1907.
70. Carl Fischer, Denkwurdigkeiten und Errinerungen eines Arbeiter (Leipzig, 1904), 386.
71. Dehn, Cotton; Jeidels, Methoden; Jefferys, Engineers, 125; Heinz Potthoff, Die sociale Frage der Werkmeister (Dusseldorf, 1910); Henri Charricault, Le Belgique moderne (Paris, 19100, 335—36; Levine, Retardation; National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives, Monthly Report, 1912; Lande, Arbeitsverhàltnisse.
72. United Society of Boilermakers and Iron Shipbuilders, Annual Report, 1911; George Dangerfield, The Strange Death of Liberal England (London, 1961); Royal Commission Appointed to Investigate and Report on the Working of the Railway Conciliation and Arbitration Scheme of 1907, Minutes of Evidence (London, 1911, Cd. 6014), 319.
73. Jules Huret, Enquête sur les grèves (Paris, 1901), 68.
74. Larkhall Miners' Association, Minute Book, 1890—91.
75. Kaiserliches Statistiches Amt, Abteilung fur Arbeiterstatistik, Die Tarifvertràge im Jahre 1913.
76. Deschene, Avènement, 360, from Le Travail (Verviers), 31 October 1906.
77. L'Ouvrier mineur, January 1903, 70; Public Record Office HO 13867, report of May, 1910; Hans Hinke, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiter im Buchdruckgewerbe (Berlin, 1910); Compagnie du chemin de fer de Paris à Orléans, Assemblée générale des actionnaires du 29 mars 1912 (Paris, 1912), 41.
78. Board of Trade, Report of Collective Agreements between Employers and Workpeople (London, 1910 Cd. 5366), iii; Ernst Duckerstoff, How an Englishman Lives (London, 1899), 40;
Arthur Shadwell, Industrial Efficiency (London, 1896), II, 51 ff.
79. To pursue these various suggestions, a good start would be a combination of Bendix, Work; Pollard, Genesis; and Levine, Retardation.
80. Peter N. Stearns, 'National Character and European Labor History,' Journal of Social History (1970), 95 ff.
81. Arthur Pugh, Men of Steel (London, 1951), 601 ff.; Branko Pribicevic, The Shop Stewards' Movement and Workers' Control (Oxford, 1959); Jefferys, Engineers, 130 ff.; Phelps Brown, Growth; Bolton Operative Cotton Spinners' Association, Annual Reports, 1891-96.
82. Stearns, Syndicalism, passim; Schulte, Entlbhnungsmethoden.
83. Statistik des deutschen Reichs, Neue Folge 278 (1914), 27; Board of Trade, Labour Correspondent (later Labour Department), Report of the Strikes and Lockouts of, 1889—1914; Direction du travail, Statistique des grèves et recours à conciliation, 1899—1914; Ministère de l'industrie et du travail., Les Grèves et Lock-outs en Belgique, 1899-1910 (Brussels, 1904-1912) plus Revue du travail, 1911 — 1914; Generalkommission der Gewerkschaften Deutschlands, Correspondenzblatt, 1903—1914. British strike figures do not contain anything close to a dismissal category, which is not to say that strikes over this issue were infrequent.
84. Philip S. Bagwell, The Railwaymen (London, 1963), 338 and passim a
85. Edwards, Valley, 129.
86. Adelmann, Quellensammlung, I, passim; on the working-class family, see below, ch. VIII.
87. L'Ouvrier mineur, January, 1903; Bolton Operative Cotton Spinners' Association, Annual Report ( 1891 ), 13.
CHAPTER 6 A FRENZIED PACE
Changes in the rhythm of work were obviously related to technology and business structure. The workers' sense that jobs were "being speeded up often served as a comment on new machines or new foremen, and to a considerable extent the pace of work provided as a subjective catch-all for organizational and technical problems that workers rarely phrased directly. But workers could legitimately isolate issues around the pace of work as well, particularly when they had some experience in factory industry. Lancashire cotton workers based their willingness to accept technological change on the absence of any 'driving' by the employers; but by the 1890s they were growing uneasy largely because the pace of work was increasing along with mechanical innovation.1 Workers newer to the industrialization process — dockers, in contrast to factory labor; or German or French workers more than British — had less ability to discriminate, and for them the pace of work summed up many different features of their jobs. Quite generally, however, there were efforts to speed work up apart from pure technical change. Everywhere workers were forced into new, often agonizing decisions about piece rates and overtime — prosaic issues, but ones on which even fundamental developments in the labor movement could hinge. In some industries, particularly after 1900, they had to come to grips with the first stages of assembly line organization. For workers generally this, more than the first phase of industrialization, was the period when intensity and regularity came to dominate the work experience. Factory workers had been whistled to their jobs from the early days, of course. But now they, and also many craftsmen and laborers, were not only called to work at a certain hour but regulated minutely while on the job. Devices to measure speed and effort replaced the factory whistle as the symbols of industrial labor.
Pace of work is a subjective topic. In contrast to discussions of business structure or new horsepower, few statistics can be provided. In fact the statistics available, inherently inexact, must call the notion of a vast change in the pace of work into some question. Many industries saw little alteration in per worker productivity during the pre-war decades, and given considerable technological change this can have signified a positive decline in the human effort expended. Between
1890 and 1907, for example, British output per worker increased only .1 percent each year. Coal mining provides a more specific example. Ruhr miners produced an average of .87 tons per shift in 1898, .86 tons in 1911 ; in Silesia the change was from 1 .4 to 1.1 ; in Britain 1.1 to .96 ; in France from .78 to .68; and in Belgium from .59 to .54 - and this after a period of considerable productivity increase up to the early 1890s. British mining, fading gradually until 1907, then declined still more rapidly; thanks first to the slump and then to the eight-hours law, per worker productivity in 1913 was moire than 10 percent below 1907 levels. French miners produced 735 kilograms per day between 1910 and 1913, compared to 815 in the years 1890—1895. Changes of this sort are not incompatible with increased work intensity, but given the advent of cutting machines they suggest the possibility that workers' perception of a heightened pace was either inaccurate or produced a highly effective counterplay. While precise figures for the construction industry are not available, productivity Ln key trades such as masonry and bricklaying almost certainly declined, despite new loading devices. Here, effective reaction by workers and their organizations was definitely responsible.2
Other industries would reveal a different picture, of course, though statistics are hard to assess without a quantification of the impact of new techniques. Per worker productivity in textiles was rising little, perhaps less than new technology should have dictated. In France between 1895 and 1913 overall textile production rose 1.9 percent annually. In contrast, during the earlier decades of industrialization the increase had been 3.4 percent. In food processing, clothing, and even metals figures for production increases (at .5, 2.7, and 3.2 percent annually, respectively), when measured against the growth of the labor force and technical changes, do not suggest a significant increase of human effort. Only in a few industries, in which as we shall see the most advanced changes in work organization were imposed, does the theme of heightened intensity clearly ring true. French metallurgical production increased at an 11.2 percent annual rate after 1895, electrical equipment 14.5 percent, chemicals a more questionable 4.7 percent. In France and elsewhere per worker productivity on the docks and railroads probably increased notably as well, beyond the effects of more workers and new equipment. French ports, for example, handled 50 percent more tonnage in 1913 than in 1900.3
Nevertheless, while the agony of intense work was most keenly felt in branches of engineering and by some unskilled workers, its reports come from almost every industry. We can explain part of the
conundrum by noting the obvious, that manufacturer efforts and worker reactions were circling viciously; we cannot even assume that the manufacturers' initiative always came first. Hours were being reduced everywhere, around the turn of the century, through collective bargaining and even more by law. France imposed a tea-hour limit on any industry with women and children involved, fully effective in 1904; Germany followed a few years later. Most countries Limited mining hours between 1908 and 1910. Britain required at Least six days' holiday for women and children workers, and most men in textiles benefited as well; France imposed a weekly rest in virtually every branch of manufacturing. With this kind of limitation facing them, and in an atmosphere of increasingly hectic internationaL competition, employers naturally stepped up the pace during the remaining hours of work. Rising pay or trade union demands could induce a similar response. Parisian construction workers faced a reintroduction of the piece rate after their 1909 strike, resulting in greatly increased production for a time. So we are talking most clearly of a regularization of work, an intensification within the work period, and not necessarily of increased effort overall.4 Hence the symptoms are more often subjective than not, as we will see. Some of the worst j ob misery was still to be found in the unmodernized sectors of manufacturing. Domestic producers were forced by competition into agonizing hours — 14—15 per day — complaining that they lacked the time even for meals. Traditional artisans faced more physical job hazards than most factory workers. Antwerp diamond workers, their lungs choked with dust and working in damp, close shops, suffered unusually high rates of tuberculosis; manual printers encountered far more lead dust than their mechanized brethren.5 A few cases can be discussed in which increased intensity may have produced more accidents, but in general this kind of precise correlation cannot be found. Instead we must deal with reports of a higher accident rate and, still more, "with claims of nervous tension and fatigue.
What workers were involved in was a regularization, indeed a modernization, of their work effort — imposed not only "by manufacturers but by labor organizations as well. Here again was a unifying theme across the working class, even though the pace of work varied greatly from job to job. There was real change, as artisans faced new machines and key mechanized industries, such as engineering, encountered unprecedented speed-up attempts. But generally perception outstripped reality, for we are dealing with a complex new consciousness. As in the case of unemployment, this new consciousness
could make traditional conditions suddenly seem intolerable; hence some of the rebellions against long hours by bakers or diamond cutters. Or it could exaggerate the sense of change. But in this instance, except in the few industries where a massive produ ctivity increase developed, reaction involved some redefinition of work itself and thus became part of the process of change.
Why should a textile worker, whose job was almost certainly not becoming more difficult, claim growing strain at work? Why were the laments so much louder than in the first phas e of industrialization when productivity mounted more rapidly and technical changes were greater and more novel? Growing experience and the availability of a labor movement accounted for much of the articulation, but we need not press this too far. Indeed the labor movement caught on partly because workers were becoming more concerned. Very generally it can be suggested that the first stage of industrialization did not impose massive changes in the pace of work. Mechanization and long hours accounted for the heightened production. Of coarse a new sense of time was in the air and was partially imposed, but a brief survey of conditions, particularly on the Continent, even in 1900 allows us to judge its incomplete effects.6
Most workers during the 1890s continued to labor for long hours, with relatively frequent breaks and — admitting the imprecision of this measurement — at a relatively traditional pace. Dockers, garbagemen and porters worked up to fifteen hours a day (or, in the case of many dockers, thirty-six hours at a stretch when they were employed). Some were learning to complain about this, but usually vaguely. British porters in 1910, working fourteen hours a day, could only say that 'something should be done.'7 Many of the m ore traditional crafts faced similar hours. Some British bakers could be found with days of over fifteen hours by 1908. Small-shop workers generally labored long hours, rather like the domestic manufacturers; in Belgium 80 percent of the companies imposing 11 1/2 hours or more had under five workers.8 But several highly industrialized sectors followed a similar pattern. Except in Britain, where eight-hour shifts gained some ground, metallurgical concerns continued on a twelve -hour basis throughout the period. Railroad workers accepted notoriously long hours, their tolerance heightened by pride in the job but above all by the fact the pace of work often remained rather traditional. Hence Prussian and French railroad workers had eleven- or twelve-hour days, while in Britain only locomotive engineers had less than a sixty-hour week even by 1914 and Scottish workers regularly did more.9 Construction
workers had similar averages. Hours in Germany ranged from ten to fourteen except in the biggest cities, which pulled the overall weekly average to 59. Hours in Belgian construction averaged 63 ; again the big city level was lower, for weekly hours in Brussels were only 57. But generally the shorter hours in the big-city crafts resulted in lower production; Berlin masons, for example, laid only a bit over half as many stones per day as their smaller-city counterparts, while British construction workers, whose general average, at 52 1/2 per week, was lower than the Continental, also produced less. The big-city pace may have been a bit higher in construction, but not enough to compensate for the tradition of shorter hours, which was really a response to fear of unemployment and the greater travel time involved rather than to a vast increase in the pace of work prior to 1900.10
Long hours could characterize a whole industrial economy. Belgium serves as the prime example of a country which maintained rough industrial competitiveness, despite a slow pace of work, through long hours. Belgian miners, faced with unusually difficult pits, labored up to an hour and a half more than British, though still under ten on the average each day. With them excepted, the Belgian average was 10 1/2— 11 hours. This included the many artisans, of course, but also textile workers, 74 percent of whom worked over eleven hours. Only machine builders, of the factory groups, were significantly under 10 1/2 hours. French and German hours were a bit lower, but in France only some printers — and then a minority — had workdays under ten hours. German textile workers labored 63 to 66 hours a week, engineers ten to ten and a half.11 These are rates only an hour or two under the levels of early industrialization — a significant reduction but one that did n ot, given the intervening technological improvements, necessitate a significant increase in the pace of work in order to maintain productivity. Only British industry (though not the crafts or unskilled labor) stood as a partial exception during the 1890s. German shoe workers, despite longer hours, produced up to 50 percent fewer pairs of shoes by machine than the British, for they deliberately limited their effort. German textile workers, in the factories two hours more each day than the British, again operated at a slower pace. They had two work breaks each day, and an hour or two for a midday meal, and this plus the lower speed of their machines accounted for much less production per worker. Belgian and French as well as German miners were less productive, though in the former two cases difficult pits account for much of the differential. German engineers worked almost the same hours as British — here the British hours remained high, at
over 59 a week — but again were slower. Observers claimed that they were more meticulous; more concretely they had longer breaks during their day, taking an hour or two off for lunch and pauses.12
A few general points can emerge from this welter of figures. Within each country there was considerable diversity in hours and pace of work as the turn of the century approached. The familiar lines among unskilled labor, traditional crafts, urban crafts (where even in England hours were lowest),13 and factories emerge here. But within a given industry, regional variations were considerable. One of the many factors disturbing the established pace of work before World War I was the inter-regional migration of workers, which heightened fears of differential output. In 1909 Westinghouse workers in Le Havre struck against the arrival of some workers from the Nord who produced more, in a common pattern.14 Only in England had some whole industries begun a clear conversion to the modern pattern of work, in which short hours would combine with a rapid pace to maintain or increase average productivity. Even in England the change had been gradual theretofore. Productivity advantages were due more to better machines, as in textiles, or easier conditions, as in mining where the pits were more accessible (in comparison to France and Belgium) or less stony (in contrast to Germany). Other differences related to the food supply, for English factory workers alone received adequate protein — 50 percent more than Belgian miners, for example. So even the important English advance did not yet produce the claims of strain and attenuation that were to come amid the more rapid changes of the pre-war decades.15
Most workers approached the twentieth century with a relatively traditional pace of work, in terms of personal expenditure of effort. Except for urban artisans and many British factory workers, most still expected to spend the bulk of their waking hours around the work site. Many of the more traditional workers in addition labored beyond their normal working day. Thirty-five percent of all Belgian workers did some manufacturing on Sundays (compared to only 3 percent in Britain). Many German metal workers, even in the larger cities, made wire or tools at home in their off-hours, while a large minority of German masons did extra work during the summer (mainly in agriculture).16 But traditional diversions, plus the slow pace, made this schedule endurable. Rest periods and holidays were both important, even if they had undergone earlier attack. Welsh miners defended their 'Snap' time in the pits (for meals) and their tradition of 'playing' on Saturdays, both of which were threatened by the new regularization of work following the 8-hours bill.17 German painters defended their
evening break in Bavaria, arguing that 'people can't get through the day without beer.'18 English brass workers defended traditional weeks off at Christmas and the August Bank Holiday (plus several breaks for inventories). Belgian workers, especially but not exclusively artisans, maintained that short days on Monday as well as Saturday were the customs of 'time immemorial.' Rhineland metal workers took off for Carnival time before the beginning of Lent.19 Clearly there were important variations among areas and industries, but without positing a misleading homogeneity it is evident that most workers maintained important contacts with a traditional world in which work, though nearly all-consuming in terms of average working hours, was enlivened by periodic interruptions and by a modest pace.
Generally this pattern involved a sense of variety that in turn provided some feeling of control. Workers could step up their effort when they needed extra money, slow down when the pressure was off. The leather union organizer in Périgueux, a man with a modern work mentality, described his disgust at his colleagues who would work like fools at the end of the week, right before pay day, exhausting themselves in the process so that they would not return until Tuesday or Wednesday, having drunk themselves silly in the interim. His remedy: a reduction of hours to regularize habits.20 British dock workers claimed they were their 'own masters' when they could work long stints and then lay off. Irregular earnings bothered their wives, the budget-keepers, more than it did them, and even their wives had to note that if they worked and earned more regularly they would be prone to spend the extra on drink — hence a general resistance to a more regular system of work.21 Obviously the notion of control was more muted in the factories, but it had not disappeared. British iron workers maintained traditions of irregular work attendance and going slow, while older engineers noted how in the past they could rest, even nap — as against the current intensity of work in which some employers even 'stole' a few minutes of the lunch hour.22
The traditional pattern also showed in the profound sense that the quantity of effort should be fixed. British workers believed rather mercantilistically in a 'lump o' labour,' such that if one worker speeded up some other must be unemployed. Shoe workers cited a certain quantity of production that was long recognized as normal for a given wage, which they sought to tabulate in collective bargaining agreements.23 French textile workers more simply claimed that any worke r who did 'more' was cheating another.24
These traditions, challenged already, were about to undergo a
decisive transformation. Their persistence warns us not to expect total change. Obviously one of the principal reasons that productivity stagnated despite speed-up efforts was that workers found means to maintain older habits. But a literal retention was increasingly difficult. Employers, rationalizing their business structure, wanted to rationalize work organization as well. Hence the worker who sought to preserve his customary expenditure of effort increasingly found he was best advised not to insist on his traditional holiday but to ask for an annual vacation; not to defend a Monday afternoon off to recover from a hangover or acquire another one but to ask for an across-the-board reduction of hours. And labor organizers stood ready to support this transition everywhere, for regularization made sense to them. They would be amply supported by some workers who had made the change to a new work mentality already. Belgian miners interviewed in 1909 uniformly argued for a reduction in their hours of work, but only a few stressed that they were too tired; most, if only because they knew what points would score before a general audience, argued in terms of a better organization of work, whereby the same effort could be accomplished in less time. The 'lump o' labour' concept could obviously be modified, as implied by the British shoe workers, to read that work intensity could be heightened for more pay. And where a few workers were ready for this kind of transformation, employers could more easily impose a heightened pace on the rest. Energetic workers, workers unusually interested in higher pay, were everywhere agents of transformation on their own. Against this combined pressure the majority of workers who wanted customs more nearly maintained were powerless. They might strike, as the Belgian miners in fact did when they found that the limitation of hours cut into their rest periods. They might occasionally vote down their union, as the British engineers did, by two to one, when in 1907 their organization offered to accept a reduction in meal breaks in favor of a 5 1-hour week. But they could not prevail.25
So, gradually, a new notion of work developed. Work was to be a limited segment of life, and not necessarily a pleasant one. Even conditions off the job conduced to this kind of rethinking. Expanding cities, even deeper mine pits or larger docks increased the time it took to reach work. As early as 1897 London engineers were claiming that, with travel time, their nine-hour day meant twelve to fourteen hours away from home. French ditch-diggers and Hamburg dockers, a bit more slowly, came to the same realization. Here was another reason to move for a reduction of hours — as many construction workers had
done in the past. But for most workers this too involved a possibly vicious circle. Living away from the job site might already involve a greater interest in home life. More often it reflected simple urban growth and the desire to find cheap housing — except for some artisans, as in London, suburbanization rarely meant embourgeoisement at this point.26 But whatever the impulse, shorter hours, if attained, resulted in new pressures at work that enhanced the need to find compensations elsewhere — at home or in other recreation. Again, without claiming that this process was entirely new around the turn of the century or uniform even then, something of a new work culture was being established. We can trace its birth pains and its inevitable ambiguities before returning to its content or the nature of the compensations it engendered.
Urban craftsmen were most immune from a new pace of work, as opposed to new techniques. A sense of pressure existed. British builders could express regret for bygone days — some even lamenting the reduction of hours of work, which they viewed in traditional terms. Specifics boiled down to a speed-up that prevented them, say, from using pumice stone to finish wood. Pressure might come from traditional sources; the attacks on subcontracting typically involved complaints that bitter competitions for contracts resulted in compulsion to overwork. The most specific new effort towards speed-up came through a general campaign to reintroduce piecework. Berlin painters found some difficulty opposing piecework, partly because a few workers wanted the system; Hamburg masons had the same experience. A Parisian masonry contractor roused great indignation when he offered to accept any hours of work in return for restoration of a piece rate. Workers, citing the overwork that would result, quit en masse, and only unskilled laborers could be hired in their stead. Generally piece rates persisted only for the handful of workers who wished them or for especially old or young workers, whose production was below standard; it remained distinctly exceptional despite employer pressure, and where it did remain it was backed up by a guaranteed minimum daily rate.27 A variant of this struggle developed briefly in Germany, where contractors attempted to introduce minimum production requirements. Berlin masons, for example, had to agree to a 'normal' production level of 500—700 stones per day, but in 1905 this was altered simply to read 'suitable production required' and in 1910 even this was dropped. Workers had regarded the production clause as a deterioration in their conditions, noting specifically that it induced attention to quantity rather than quality in the work.28
Generally, however, pressure on pace was minimal and productivity in construction almost certainly declined. In French construction between 1901 and 1911, labor costs soared 25 percent while productivity fell by 15 percent. Berlin masons claimed that they were setting 20 percent more stones daily than in the past, by 1910, but their rate was in fact below the level of other cities and their employers more plausibly contended that there had been a decline. Strong unions bent on maintaining tradition while also seeking a reduction in hours of work; a new push for equalized pay rates that reduced individual incentive to raise production; and pervasive private efforts to keep output down even below officially accepted rates all worked to keep the craft world separate.29 Craftsmen might talk of deterioration, but it is doubtful that their pace increased.
Even printers, though subjected to new mechanization, avoided most of the pressure on pace. They too talked of nervousness; British workers on the Monotype machine played up the idea of 'greater mental and physical strain' as a bargaining ploy.30 Concrete changes were feared when employers tried to impose a piece rate on the machine workers, particularly when some of the latter revealed an impulse to benefit from the system by producing rapidly; generally, however, the 'piece rate was either avoided or undermined by a guaranteed minimum rate, and machine workers typically held their production down. In Paris a number of typographers went on the group piece, among the only workers to do so eagerly; they felt their skills were roughly equal and showed no great desire to maximize individual earnings as against their fellows — again a craft impulse that could still be valid. Several manufacturers, to counter real or imagined ca'canny, put electric checkers on the typesetting machinery, sometimes supplementing this with a bonus system. British workers blasted this as 'slave-driving,' setting men against each other. In 1911 they agreed to the indicators when manufacturers dropped the bonus system and set up a joint committee for any disputes. German printers had to accept calculation devices in a 1906 agreement, but only a few companies actually introduced them; by 1908 only 28 percent of the companies had any checking system and only 27 of 3600 machine workers were subjected to electrical calculation.31
As always, the impulses of many factory workers resembled those of the artisans, but the actual situation contrasted strongly. Textile workers suffered from frequent recalculations of the piece rate. Sometimes this merely compensated for new machines, but the effect could be unsettling. More ominously, many French weavers, paid by
finished product instead of the meter, found their piece increased by a sixth after 1900. The same was true, during this period, for Crefeld dyers. Rouen manufacturers, reacting to the legal reduction in hours that began in 1900, forced piece workers to maintain their productivity in the shorter time while stiffening rules on tardiness for the day workers. Efforts of this sort, plus the perennial attempt to use shoddier materials without raising the piece rate, could anger workers even when the overall expenditure of effort did not change dramatically.32 Time; clocks were introduced in metallurgy, causing a number of disputes in Britain when workers refused to punch in. German workers, less troubled by the principle, noted that the clocks were often distant from their job and lost them time. Metallurgical workers also saw their rest periods reduced.33 Nothing dramatic, but enough to drive one British ironfounder to complain: 'Things are speeded up now to such an extent that it is impossible to do it.'34 And he added that a reduction of hours would be futile, because 'things' would be speeded up even more.
The most diverse pressure came in engineering and shipbuilding. Some British manufacturers cut out the breakfast break, even though hours had not been reduced; workers had preferred shorter stints. Where hours were reduced, as in Berlin, some companies set up a system of shifts which disrupted workers' family life. In shipbuilding the size of work crews was reduced, ostensibly to compensate for new equipment. German shipbuilders were pressed to do regular overtime; they claimed that many employers announced the overtime at the end of the workday and fired anyone who refused. Foremen were pressed to raise the work standards. In Belgium, in a factory where workers believed that they could grind only fourteen large gears every day (much of the job involving heavy manual labor), a worker was suddenly told that sixteen were expected normally; they rightly feared that the new foreman really planned to drive them to eighteen, so they struck on behalf of a colleague who was fired for refusing.35 More general still was the introduction of piece rates and/or a bonus system. In 1886, five percent of all British engineers were on a piece rate; in 1906 this had risen to 27.5 percent, and in 1914 to over 46 percent. Once the piece was introduced there was steady pressure to lower its rate to force higher production. German riveters often faced a group piece rate, which was manipulated to raise the pace. Metal workers in the Rhineland, though able to accept the piece rate, were suddenly held to minimum production requirements or a time definition for each piece. But outright reduction was more common still. In a common pattern, a Diesel manufacturing company in Ghent revised the basis for the piece
in 1913, forcing a 25 percent intensification of the work. Bonus systems were used instead of or in addition to the piece; they were particularly popular in French engineering. They brought even more complaints of unfairness, because they required a great deal of production for any result and often seem ed impossible to earn; and the few workers that did win them were more obviously singled out by their luck or treason. British workers note d in 1904 that the system was based on 'extreme capabilities of men and machines,' preventing earnings proportional to the work required.37 All the refinements of the bonus and piece rate systems, furthermore, involved detailed studies by engineering experts, reducing the workers' sense of control over his job. British engineers objected to 'feed and speed' systems that had an outside expert set appropriate cutting angles. The time and motion studies set forward in all the industrial countries in the years right before World War I, of which the Taylor system was most famous, brought the pressure to a climax. Workers» were held to systems planned by outsiders, their craft pride hurt, their goals forced them from quality to quantity. Inevitably they were asked to do more, violating what they regarded as a fair day's work; and they knew that if by great effort they produced their new quota, their piece rate or bonus would be lowered to prevent them from gaining any real advantage from their labor.38
Taylorization was impossible in the mines, but most of the other devices used in the metal industries were pushed during the period. Mine owners were pressed not only by unusually low hours of work but also by the growing depth and difficulty of the pits, as the mines began to show their age. The piece rate was standard in the industry, of course, but it could be used in new ways. German miners, paid by the wagon rather than by weight, found a new and larger cart introduced, one that took five or six more shovelsfull to fill, for no increase in pay. Or pit prices were reduced; in Northumberland workers complained that extremely hard work was necessary simply to earn the 'county average,' while earnings much above the average resulted in rate reductions. Increasingly there were accusations that only highly skilled workers, even foremen, were used to test a new pitface, resulting in a piece rate that was unrealistic if not impossible ; this was an important basis for the Welsh miners' uprising of 1909 and of growing importance as the pits became more difficult. Skilled German miners were put on the hardest faces, because the newcomers could only handle the easier conditions; the result was that the skilled had the lowest take-home pay, again because piece rates were not flexible enough to cover the growing diversity of conditions. Everywhere travel time increased in the
mines, spreading complaints about inefficient organization that wasted the worker's day, tiring him in the process, and kept earnings down. Yet when hours were cut the companies responded by eating into traditional work breaks — and miners, for all their advanced trade unionism, were highly jealous of their customary habits. Better-organized than their brethren in metals, miners were able to attack some of these changes directly, for disputes were endemic. British miners, most notably, learned to undermine the piece rate by setting regional, then national, wage minima. But the fight was hard and generally miners had to accept new conditions of work, winning only a better compensation and shorter hours in return.39
The tale of pressure could be extended to every industry. British railwaymen were forced to massive shifts of nineteen hours or more during the 1890s because the increased traffic was not matched by new hiring. Firemen had to shovel more coal into the bigger engines, but were initially given neither assistance nor a raise. French and Prussian railworkers had similar complaints; in France, furthermore, engineers were put on a bonus system which encouraged them to press their subordinate workers in order to save fuel and make good time.40 Dock workers found their crews reduced (from eight men to six, in England, after 1890) while the tonnage they handled mounted. Hamburg dockers had their load increased, from eight to ten sacks in 1892 to twelve to sixteen five years later. Sailors in most countries complained of undermanning, as ship size increased faster than crews. Even garbagemen were not immune. The Paris city council in 1910 voted a new system of heavy cans (weighing 25—30 kilograms) that greatly increased their effort.41
What were workers' reactions to these various pressures? We have suggested the resistance that could be mounted successfully in a few situations; we will return to this theme. But first it is vital to get at the more direct impact of change, particularly to suggest the rifts that almost all the speed-up methods caused within the labor force. For the new systems of work held out one fatal attraction: they normally offered more money than the traditional methods. Craftsmen could resist the systems because their skills and organization all owed them to improve their earnings while shunning hurry-up procedures. Other workers, even miners, were not so fortunate. And some could find a certain merit in the systems themselves. Hence the general theme: concessions, if not outright capitulation, most commonly against the wishes of the organized labor movement, because of the attraction of higher earnings and the continued pull of certain kinds of work
traditions. And a minor but important variation: workers who saw ways to use new systems to preserve traditional values or who enjoyed harder work directly. The result: a deterioration of the quality of work for most workers, with some compensations; considerable difficulty in frontal resistance because of divisions among workers and the compensations available and because the only realistic resistance usually involved further opening to the intensification process. The workers who found merit in the new systems themselves were the lucky ones.
The introduction of new work systems occurred against the backdrop of personal tensions on the job that have already been suggested. Individual workers brought in to set a new pace or simply attracted by new incentives violated their fellows' sense of fair play. A large number of small strikes burst out against the workers who accepted innovations, and even without them personal tensions could poison the atmosphere on the job. Many work sites were divided really into three camps: the minority of workers eager to go on a piece rate or some other new system; a large number of workers hostile to innovation but so devoted to the traditional concept of work that they could not abandon their job ; and a large number who saw agitation as the only way out, even if it meant striking or otherwise risking the job. None of these groups could easily talk to the other. New work systems were typically imposed by visible supervisors — foremen or outside engineers. New systems plus resistance prompted the host of personal disputes and a background of perpetual bickering. Employers accused workers, from mining through construction work, of lying down on the job — not always incorrectly, but invariably insulting a genuine sense of a job pride, for the workers normally viewed their efforts as well within the bounds of traditional work definitions. This atmosphere was easy to translate to the job itself. Day after day, a foreman, himself driven by new incentive systems, told his workers, 'you're not doing enough.' Small wonder that foremen were so often attacked.42
Personal tensions aside, the reaction to new conditions of work can best be tested by examination of overtime, piecework, the bonus system, and the efficiency schemes.
Overtime was not new, but the belief that pressure to work overtime was mounting was widespread; and trade union campaigns against the system brought it into greater prominence in any event. It is not unreasonable to assume that workers, whose earnings were rising on the whole and whose pace of work was definitely mounting, would resist overtime with growing vigor. This was the universal assumption of the labor movement, which could produce a variety of reasons for its
position. The London typographers' union noted that overtime, the result of workers' avarice as well as employer pressure, ruined health and family life; it went to considerable lengths to convince its members that the printing trade could survive quite easily without the practice. The principal concern, voiced particularly in England, was the impact on employment; workers should not benefit at the possible expense of their fellows. As the Scottish boilermakers put it, 'A great wrong is being done by men working overtime in any class of work while we've a single idle member on our books.'43 A number of workers shared these sentiments, and refusals to work overtime were frequent; there were several strikes on the issue. The 1907 agreement in British engineering limited overtime to 32 hours a month, though with many exceptions, and in 1904 unionized engineers had voted to abolish overtime outright if any area was suffering unemployment. Similar arrangements were attempted in the German machine tools industry; Leipzig foundry workers, for example, asked that overtime be confined to clear emergencies, and of course paid at a higher rate.44
But generally such arrangements foundered on the joint interest of employers and many workers in pushing overtime in peak periods. Only in the machine tools industry was there any widespread worker sentiment for limitations, because of the growing problem of unemployment. Unions in printing, mining, and construction pushed for limitations, but they clearly lacked support from their members. The few printers who followed union directions to abstain from overtime were regarded as freaks. Even in machine tools most workers wanted extra work; an agreement in English pattern-making, limiting work to 65 hours a week, foundered on the workers' lack of enthusiasm. Berlin manufacturers claimed that their workers clamored for overtime. And in other industries there was little question that only a minority of workers were hostile to the practice. British printers in 1895 specifically voted against the idea of banning overtime during periods of unemployment. Belgian printers agreed, and companies had no difficulty finding workers to stay late, even during the night. French miners in Avion, though under intense union pressure to resist the extra shifts that were common in the industry, voted two to one in favor of the practice. French construction workers, following union campaigns to reduce hours, turned around and used their gains to maintain, their schedule, while earning overtime rates. A British construction worker noted that his colleagues judged themselves lucky to get overtime work, even when it exhausted them. And there were far more strikes to retain overtime than to resist it. British dockers specifically told a government
commission that withdrawal of overtime would constitute a grievance.45 Hence overtime remained standard in the mines, particularly during early winter; in the Ruhr there were two to four extra shifts a week. Individual dock workers might work over a hundred hours extra during a ninety-day period. Overtime was endemic in the crafts, including construction. In the early 1890s, 72 percent of unionized British engineers reported systematic overtime, ranging up to 19 percent above the regular hours of work. Union efforts may here have done some good subsequently. In Germany machine builders noted a steady decline in employer violations of limitation agreements. And in metallurgy and, normally, in shipbuilding only a minority of workers — about 5 percent — were held to systematic overtime.46
Obviously, workers sought overtime as a means of earning extra money. In Berlin engineering, the unskilled were considerably more likely than the skilled to do overtime during the year, and more of it (88 percent to 62 percent, an average of 355 hours per year instead of 138); the semi-skilled were not distinctive, as 66 percent did an average of 127 hours. Relatedly, older workers were particularly addicted, as they needed to make up for declining hourly production. This kind of breakdown is not available for other industries, but impressionistically the skilled seemed even more eager in construction and mining. There was employer pressure in all industries, and this can no more be discounted than need. But it must be emphasized that overtime made sense to many workers. It was traditional in their industries. In areas like dock work and construction it helped compensate for irregular employment. More generally, in an environment that was fundamentally out of their control, overtime helped workers introduce some rationality into their jobs. They could, with luck and within reason, work more when they needed to earn more. Hence miners pressed on before Christmas, to earn money for gifts, and printers saw overtime as a means of paying for luxuries. Belgian miners, noting they needed Monday off because they were so tired, then insisted on overtime to make up earnings on other days.47 This is not to claim that workers embraced overtime with joy. Construction workers noted their dislike to Charles Booth, adding 'it's right enough if the money is paid.'48 As a disagreeable necessity, overtime fitted the widespread interest in irregular, partially adjustable work. Even with a rising pace of work — save perhaps in engineering — it was not shunned as part of a principled effort to bring labor under collective control.
In this situation most unions could only press for formal recognition of overtime as work deserving extra pay. Here they had unanimous
support, for opponents and proponents could agree. Some might claim, with British bargemakers who won a shilling extra for each overtime hour: 'not. .. because we wanted the extra money, but because we wished to put a stop to the pernicious system of systematic overtime.'49 Other workers, as in the French building trades, simply took the money.
For the most part the dispute over extra work brought a new kind of collective mentality, stressing the importance of a general protection of jobs, into dispute with traditional judgements of how work should be organized. Individual workers, probably in growing numbers, seized upon overtime as an instrument for higher earnings, particularly as overtime bonuses spread with collective bargaining. But, while it was interesting that more resistance to overtime did not develop, given the claims of growing exhaustion, overtime was not directly part of the speed-up process; some employers indeed turned against overtime themselves, as it became more expensive, because their workers put forth so little effort during the extra hours. Arguments over piece work were more complex, because the interest in maximization of earnings could play a greater role. And piece work was against tradition in many industries, more clearly part of the speed-up campaign, which gave resistance a keener edge.
In a number of industries the principle of piece work was not contested, because the nature of the industry and all its traditions supported the system. Such was the case in mining, with its dispersed work sites, most textiles, and metallurgy. German textile workers had no complaints about piece work per se, while Lancashire cotton unions positively insisted upon it. The argument was that piece work alone allowed workers to avoid speed-ups, because they could control their own pace and avoid exploitation during growing mechanization. Many shoe workers agreed; Leicester shoe workers agitated for piece work on machines in preference to the production quotas set by foremen on a daily-pay system. When the union negotiated the piece rate, these workers judged that it defended their own standards of work; and with output rising, they grew restive under a fixed weekly wage. In fact the piece rate here accommodated a mixture of motives, with defenders of a traditional pace and workers eager for intensive labor resulting in high earnings both comfortable under the system.50
This is not to say that the piece rate did not cause dispute. Where technology changed, workers might grant the need for a reduction in the rate but feel cheated at the actual earnings that resulted. Several branches of textiles required frequent changes of rates, to deal with
new products; bad materials could also lead to quarrels over the results of the piece system. Miners, as we have seen, argued that piece rates were inadequate when they did not take difficult pit faces or a poor organization of work into account. High rates of small strikes in both industries owed much to the confusion that piece rates could cause, heightened often (particularly in mining) by employers' reluctance to provide clear information on the basis of earnings. Only metallurgy, of the traditional piece-rate industries, was virtually immune from dispute. In metallurgy the product changed rarely, and new technology did not result in frequent reductions in rate; workers were allowed to keep some of the benefits. So pay did not vary unpredictably from week to week, and workers professed themselves content. Elsewhere the piece rate was accompanied by a growing chorus of complaints about cheating, as workers objected to rapid fluctuations and uncertainty in their actual take-home pay and to adjustments in the piece which suggested a speed-up effort.51 Shoe workers in Bristol, in 1894, even opposed the idea that the piece rate should change with new technology, arguing essentially that labor costs should not be reduced per unit product even when their own earnings improved. 'And the employers got eleven dozen of work done at the price of ten dozen provided [by the old piece rate], and that... involved a reduction of wages.'52 The very traditionalism of the piece rate in major industries then produced a high level of customary disputes. Hence handworkers were involved at least as often as workers in more modern operations; the older docks, for example, produced the most complaints about cheating, as subcontractors kept the rate of pay to themselves and refused to submit to any systematic measurement of the product. Correspondingly the level of anguish in these industries did not necessarily rise even as protest mounted, for again it was execution, not principle, that was in question.53
The industries in which piece work was not actively debated provide some interesting lessons even so, particularly as work conditions changed. Miners accepted piece rates without really believing that earnings should vary too widely. Hence, where employers were willing, it was not too difficult to dispose of most small disputes. Most British mining regions found that county-wide averages, once accepted by the companies, were very beneficial. Here was a minimum that protected the worker from a sense of being cheated; but also a maximum, for workers would accept reductions in pay if their earnings ranged more than five percent above the average. Add, as in Durham and Northumberland, a disputes committee to rule on any grievances and
the employers' willingness to provide wage information on application, and one had a rather effective system. Mines remained open to dispute as pit conditions deteriorated, of course; and for Welsh or Continental miners the system just outlined took a heap of doing, for companies were not so obliging. But miners, in this as in so many other respects, took on a craft mentality toward piece work even while accepting it. The situation in light manufacturing was less clear. Leicester shoe workers, for example, also wanted a minimum, to protect older or less skilled labor; but they had no truck with any idea of maximum. These were people, however reluctantly prodded into factories, who accepted the idea of mechanization and wanted to benefit by it. It was Northampton workers, in British shoe manufacture, who stood for traditionalism in arguing for a daily rate of pay. Mechanization was less advanced in this area, so the piece rate seemed to stand only for sweating; daily pay meant a regular and calm rhythm, with both work and pay shared and shared alike. Information from the textile industry is scanty here, but it was clear that workers accepted considerable variations in earnings as normal, even while seeing piece work as a means of avoiding an excessive pace for most workers.54
In construction, printing, woodworking, and machine building, widespread concern developed over the principle of piecework. The unions in all these industries were hostile to the piece, as was the socialist movement; the peak of resistance came in the late 1890s in England and Germany, a few years later in France. Hamburg workers who accepted piecework were even expelled from the socialist party in 1901, though readmitted subsequently. The arguments of organized labor were vigorous and cogent, and many workers agreed. Piecework was contrary to labor principles because it set one worker apart from his mates in earnings; British metal workers specifically said it was against the principles of unionism for good workers to earn more. Furthermore, for those believing in the 'lump o' labour' concept it was obvious that any system encouraging higher production would also lead to unemployment: 'every three or four men working piecework are responsible for keeping one man out of work.'55 Piecework stressed quantity of production; Belgian stonecutters argued that they could work less well, forced to conceal faults in their products, when the quarry owners talked of converting to a piece rate system .56
Workers could easily supplement these arguments. Piecework, in engineering and machine woodwork particularly, produced extreme fluctuations in earnings. German machine workers reported taking 62 marks home one week and 29 the next, without any definable change
in their own efforts; a woodworker reported 600 percent variations in his biweekly pay. These were industries in which the product changed frequently (this notably distinguished machine work from metallurgy). This, plus the novelty of the system and rapid technological change, produced constant accusations of cheating. Adding to this, in machine tools, was the effort by many companies to set a ceiling on earnings. A worker producing at a great pace would find that his labors resulted only in a reduced rate. Here was the tangible expression of the companies' desire to use the piece to speed work up, and it produced a widespread sense of unfairness. A strike was caused in a Munich locomotive plant in 1905 by regular reductions when workers earned over a certain amount. Even semi-skilled metal workers in Briey worked shoddily because they knew the piece rate would be set to prevent high earnings. Berlin engineers tried to keep their production down so that their rates would not be cut; they knew their fellows would treat them as enemies if they caused a reduction. When, as was often the case, employers resisted even writing the rates down, lest they be hindered in reducing them, the workers' suspicions were more than justified. British engineers put their case mildly, in arguing for piece rates that would at least guarantee earnings above the daily wage, 'to obtain extra pay for the extra effort put forth.'57
So there were many strikes and protests against the introduction of the piece. Sheffield ironmoulders declined a healthy raise in favour of avoiding the piece. Limoges porcelain workers were held to be hostile to the piece as productive of unemployment and unhealthy intra-class competition, except for a few who earned well by the system; even most of the highly paid workers were opposed.58 Belgian cabinet-workers, striking against the system, issued a poster: 'This will fatally lower the wages, already so minimal, and besides we are already too exposed to danger to aggravate our situation further by the disorderly production that inevitably results from this system of work.'59 Metal workers polled in Solingen were 18 percent for the piece rate, 70 percent for hourly pay. Commonly the Germans repeated the trade union phrase: 'Akkordarbeit ist Mordarbeit.' Those interviewed by Adolf Levenstein overwhelmingly preferred time pay: this protected their health; allowed them to set their own pace; gave them money no matter how much work they did, for with the piece the only way to earn enough was to work too hard. Only time rates permitted proper worker solidarity. His sample favored time rates by over 70 percent in metals and even in the mines. As one metal worker noted, only hourly pay was 'just' and 'capable of limiting the selfishness and greed of
individuals.'60
Yet, against vigorous resistance, the piece rate spread steadily in machine tools, vehicle manufacture, and woodwork. It unquestionably speeded the work; one estimate, in textiles, held piece work to be 78 percent more efficient than time. Crefeld cloth printers successfully abolished the piece rate in 1906, but found that production fell so rapidly that their area's competitive position suffered, and with it employment; so they had to reintroduce the system in 1911, after which production recovered nicely.61 So it is safe to assume that competitive conditions and the great power of growing companies in industries such as machine building forced workers to back down. Certainly the unions in metal and woodwork were abandoning their stand by the early 1900s, in favor of imposing some controls over the piece rate. Only in the crafts, with smaller companies, less international competition, and stronger unions, was piecework avoided. The spread of the piece rate system, with its attendant pressure for speed-up, angered countless workers.
Yet even this is not the whole story. The minority of workers actively favoring piecework had some interesting arguments. The position of factory labor differed from that of the craftsmen. Construction workers, for example, opposed the piece because of its pressure and unfairness but stressed their desire for pay not to vary with individual ability. Printers agreed to a considerable extent. Machine workers were accused of greed and did work above their production minima, for wages that were higher than those of manual labor; but they showed few signs of wanting a piece rate, accepting daily rates of pay. Factory laborers did not stress equality in this way. Their unions might, but they were not entirely representative of the membership. Finally, although labor organizations did reflect widespread concern, they faced divisions within the factories that polls or organized workers by definition cannot fully reflect. To an important degree attitudes about piece work could determine whether or not a worker joined or stayed in labor organizations at all. Many unions found it difficult to persuade workers that the piece rate should be opposed. The Hamburg construction workers who accepted the piece simply founded their own organization. Others would stay out of unions altogether. The unions' gradual modifications of policy — outside the crafts — thus stemmed from earlier disputes over the issue within the labor force and the ambiguous cast of mind of factory workers generally. The initial disputes in turn cannot be dismissed as the work of a few greedy individuals, though greed was involved.
Piecework forced a brief war between the collective and individualistic impulses that were both vital to the adjustment of workers to factory life.62
Many workers did like the higher wages that piecework normally provided. Employers were careful, usually, to calculate rates so that workers would earn more than those on a time formula. And people proud of their skills, some from a traditional background where hard work was normal even for low earnings, could easily fit into this system. Hence highly skilled workers were often held to prefer payment by piece. This was true of Jewish immigrants from Russia, in the German leather industry, or of the highly skilled workers in a locomotive plant (where day laborers all preferred time rates). At least until they were unionized right before the war, piece workers in French automobile manufacturing adopted an intense pace without complaint, to maximize their earnings. In German construction work it was rural workers in for the summer who most often accepted piecework (except in Hamburg); hard work was natural and the high pay extremely welcome.63 So it would be possible to suggest a pattern by which traditional standards of work justified the piece rate until workers gained a new consciousness which allowed them to realize how they were being exploited. This could apply also to the greater flexibility that some workers found in the piece rate. Engineering workers in Alsace accepted the introduction of piece rates but did not increase their production; they had no desire to earn more but saw greater freedom from supervision in the new system. Textile workers were judged divided between those who saw in the piece a means of higher wages and those who wanted more flexibility to go and come as they pleased.64
Except in the crafts the popularity of piecework gained ground after 1900, and traditionalism played a decreasing role in this process. The desire to regulate one's own work remained strong; as supervisory systems became more intense this could make the piece rate seem quite welcome. Sheffield steel workers, for example, hailed piecework when it replaced a high-pressure system of subcontracting. But this was not designed to slow up the work. The German workers who preferred piece rates stressed independence from supervision but also their ability to work harder, which made the time pass more quickly. Young and semi-skilled workers were increasingly drawn towards the piece. The system allowed them to gain on the earnings of the highly skilled and, in the case of the young, take full advantage of their strength and vigor. Aides in the British shipyards consistently agitated for the piece, which
would remove them from the control of skilled workers who otherwise forced them to work hard simply to benefit their own piece rate earnings; here the boilermakers' union thwarted them until after 1900. Workers more generally could turn to the piece rate, like the Leicester shoe manufacturers, as they saw output rising with new techniques and supervision; here was the source of the conversion of British gas workers to the system, except in London where socialist motivation was strong.65 High earnings, but also flexibility and the interest it added to work, attracted growing numbers of workers to the piece rate. As with overtime, piecework allowed labor to tailor effort to goal to a certain degree. One of the reasons for high fluctuations in earnings was variation in motivation; German metal workers raised their earnings 30 percent above average in the week before Christmas, for example.66
The minority of workers in Levenstein's survey who spoke up for the piece conveyed these various reasons clearly. They needed the piece to earn enough for their families, but they enjoyed the work more as well; some professed to find less pressure with this system. 'In principle I'm for time pay. At present however I prefer to work on the piece, because I earn more and have to work as intensively on time as on piece.' Only piecework allowed rising earnings to meet inflation; but for another worker only the piece allowed him to be his 'own master.' The piece rate gave more 'value for value;' and one felt 'freer, more alert.' 'Piece is more interesting than when one already knows Monday morning that it will only be 24 marks.'67
One cannot avoid the impression that the piece rate spread in part because it corresponded to many of the workers' own judgements about what the job should be like: somewhat flexible, with effort rewarded — in addition to serving as a speed-up device. Certainly unions came to recognize that so many had accepted the piece that they could hold out no longer. Union men who refused the piece could easily find themselves replaced by unorganized workers who approved of piecework, and there was division within the membership as well. The German metal workers' group, in 1901 against the piece 'as much as possible,' by 1903 began to incorporate it in collective bargaining proposals; similarly the engineering and wood unions turned to an effort to regulate the piece.68 This effort, plus related changes in company policies, could remove many of the objections other factory workers had to the system.
What was sought was clarity on the pay sheets, a minimum that would protect workers against arbitrary actions or production problems that were not their fault, and a rate high enough to repay increased
output above the conventional daily wages. In part to answer or deflect worker agitation, in part because of the rationalization program of companies themselves, employers were increasingly willing to provide set standards for the piece — rather than leaving this up to a foreman's judgement — and to discuss changes in rates with worker representatives in advance. Here, German and probably French concerns, in heavy industry, went further than their British counterparts. The British piece, as it spread in engineering, was usually set rather ad hoc, often for a skilled worker with several aides dependent on him. Despite the higher rates of unionization in Britain it was harder to bring the piece under the kind of control workers wanted ; it was no more a speed-up device, for this was generally true, but it was easier to judge unfair. French machine tools workers, without much collective bargaining, were normally paid on a combination of minimum wage and piece. German workers found their piece calculated more precisely, for each category of the labor force, in the larger concerns. Collective bargaining could supplement this evolution. German unions found they could drop minimum pay guarantees when the rate was worked out jointly and a grievance procedure established. Disputes and strikes continued, of course; French chassis workers, faced with their first experience of compulsory piecework after 1906, conducted a series of strikes, while problems continued with less abatement in Britain. But some mutual accommodation, plus the important linkages between the piece system and factory workers' job expectations from the start, increasingly removed dispute from the area of principle.69
The use of bonuses raised many of the problems associated with piece work. They were more likely to seem arbitrary, particularly when only a few workers could win them. Hence many German workers, as in textiles, accepted piecework but resisted a bonus system. The premium bonus in fact spread only slowly in Germany because employers recognized worker hostility. Where widely used, bonuses were regarded as a natural part of the wage. The 1902 French miners' strike focused on the withdrawal of bonus payments; and in the mines and other French industries unusually heavy reliance on the bonus system was accepted only when the rewards remained fairly predictable. Where bonuses were newly introduced to stimulate production, workers naturally divided. Fifty Northampton shoe workers struck against the bonus system, claiming they could not work hard enough to earn bonuses without hurting their health; but thirty others stayed on the job, happy with their extra earnings. Metal moulders in a Paris company, hostile to a bonus system that they felt forced them to work
too hard, attacked three workers who accepted the system and insisted that they be fired. Most of the French disputes, however, concerned the execution of the bonus system rather than its principle. Trélazé slate workers were given bonuses for high production over a six-month period. It was difficult to maintain the necessary level when a worker encountered faulty stone, so he produced a thin piece to compensate. When in 1913 the company regulated the thickness of the product, workers struck for a raise to compensate (while agreeing that the standardization was desirable). Unquestionably these workers preferred a predictable wage to a bonus system; unquestionably they preferred good quality work to the subterfuges the bonus induced. But they were not willing to rise against the system itself. Bonus payments had deeper traditions in France than elsewhere; this, plus the related possibility that many French workers were drawn to systems that encouraged maximization of earnings, seems to have confined most disputes to questions of detail.70
Not so in Britain, where bonuses were more novel. Perhaps the superior organization of British workers allowed them to articulate grievances felt elsewhere; perhaps the fear of speed-up was greater. In any event quarrels over the bonus system developed in engineering, where the number of union members involved in the system doubled (to 9.2 percent of the total) between 1906 and 1909. Iron workers in West Ham disliked their bonus system because of, its unpredictable results (the familiar complaint) and because their work depended on others. Again the British system of team work, combining skilled workers and their aides, mitigated against the newer methods of payment, for teamwork and individual incentives did not mesh.71 More generally a variety of arguments reflected the sense that bonuses encouraged workers to step up the pace more than they were actually rewarded: workers in a Patricroft machine shop complained, 'the employers are not justified in taking one-half of the men's, earnings due to their extra effort.'72 The Amalgamated Society of Engineers accepted the bonus system in 1902, urging its members to give it a try; the leadership had won a minimum time rate regardless of output, and found this an adequate defense. But this did not suit, and membership objections were so strong that the union dared not let the matter be put to a vote. A 1910 poll revealed a three-to-one majority for a strike against any generalization of the premium bonus system, while in 1911, 95,738 members voted to abolish all bonuses, against only 9965 in favor.73
By this time, however, engineering had become something of a
special case, and not only in Britain, even if numerically a very important one. Generally the methods used to encourage faster work, while they occasioned great debate, did not produce massive confrontations in the factories. The craft sense that pay should not vary with effort was not sufficiently widespread; if only because machine work was dull but productive, a desire to win a greater reward spread widely. Workers wanted some collective defenses, but individual incentives moved them as well. This is not to minimize the unhappiness many factory workers voiced over new systems of work and the uneasiness that was even more widespread. But the most extensive new systems did provide certain attractive inducements, which at least divided the labor force. They did leave some apparent room for the flexibility that workers so desired ; workers were not uniformly pressed to some set standard of production when put on overtime schedules or on a piece rate. Even when the pace went up new systems could make the work seem more interesting, though this is a debatable area to which we must return. Finally, the greatest pressure to step up the work often seemed personal and was translated in individual terms. Attacks on workers who seemed too zealous or on foremen who asked too much were far more common than attacks on the piece rate or overtime in principle. Work was changing, and for many workers becoming less attractive; but its unattractiveness increased only gradually and there was no clear focus for a general assault. The workers most affronted, in the crafts, won much of the immunity they sought; factory workers held off not only because of their employers' greater power but also because their own outlook was more ambiguous. Not so in key sectors of the machine trades right before World War I. Already unusually nervous about new technology and new systems of direction, the engineers were now faced with an explicit reorganization toward greater efficiency, rarely glossed over by adequate incentives. The efficiency campaign revealed the scanty impact that more subtle efforts had had; piece and bonus systems had proved acceptable because they did not force all workers to produce more than they found appropriate and because they left open the question of what was appropriate. Now there was no room for debate: outside experts or unusually efficient workers were taken as models of what all should produce. French automobile companies began measuring each operation by the second — after 1910 selecting the most skilled workers for the test, and the best possible tools — to determine appropriate wage rates; the result, claimed the workers, was a doubling of effort for less pay than before. So workers who had conspicuously shunned trade
unionism before, while working hard on a piece rate system, suddenly became ardent agitators. They asked for a suppression of the chronométrage system, shorter hours, and a permanent works committee to deal with disputes over pay rates. Other French workers struck against 'Taylorization,' sometimes applying the term rather broadly to speed-up efforts such as a reduction in the size of work crews but often correctly identifying new efficiency efforts through time and motion studies.74 Similar disputes wracked British engineering and even some branches of printing. Skilled workers resented the pressure for quantity and the very notion of supervision by outsiders; and some of the planning was quite inexpert. Overseers now determined the best speed of machine tools, in the Taylor-White 'feed and speed' system, depriving workers of their own judgement.75 'In the old days they used to use a lash upon slaves; in these modern times I suppose they would use an indicator.' 'Why should we be asked to work under a system that indicates every movement of our elbow?'76 In this case tensions in Britain were not as great as on the Continent, for British workers were accustomed to a faster pace; many engineers gave a fair trial to the Rowan bonus system, which was based on an efficiency calculation, and then to the 'feeder and speeder' approach so long as they were assured that the pay rates would not be cut.77 Despite all the previous quarrels over work arrangements blatant speed-up was newer to the Continent, so the reaction, as in the French automobile industry, was more intense. Mannheim boilermakers, in one of the relatively few German companies that approached the Taylor methods before the war, stated their shock quite vividly: efficiency systems 'damage our income and our personal freedom.'78 But malaise was widespread in Britain as well. Loss of control over the direction of work, implying a faster pace but also faulty outside judgements and unfair pay determination, would not be accepted without a fight.
Still more generally a consciousness of the difficulties of work was spreading. Individual changes could be absorbed, though often after considerable resistance and division among the workers. Some of the groups most offended were able to deflect new work systems. There was no massive crisis over work. Complaints naturally stand out more vividly than expressions of satisfaction; we cannot be sure how representative the new consciousness was. Furthermore, new concern could outstrip actual conditions. When grain dockers wrote: 'Work on grain ships is dirty, unhealthy, tiring, and dangerous work'79 — a sentiment behind much of the new agitation among the unskilled — they were commenting on conditions that had long prevailed; it was the
outlook that was new. But, on the docks and in industry — quite apart from the special case of engineering — there were enough changes in work pace and organization to stimulate the new consciousness.
Some groups of workers claimed a rising accident rate with the new pace of their jobs. German woodworkers pointed to the danger of machines. Hamburg dock laborers in 1912 told an observer that their accident rate had risen faster than their numbers during the previous decade. German ship-builders claimed that new machines caused an unusually high and rising rate of illness and accidents after 1900. Miners were extremely attentive to accident figures and in Germany could claim some deterioration; the overall accident rate went down but fatalities mounted after 1905, reaching 1890s levels in 1907. Individual miners certainly believed that employer pressure caused more accidents. The fact that most reports about rising concern over accidents come from Germany reflects the newness of the whole industrialization process as much as innovations within factory work. Fear of accidents was intense everywhere, exploding in such reactions to mine disasters as Courrières in 1906, but not clearly increasing. Accident rates were definitely falling — mining fatalities dropped about 10 percent in Belgium in the first decade of the twentieth century. The greatest concern about mishaps, outside of the mines and German industry more generally, came in crafts such as printing and painting, where unions fulminated against traditional hazards such as lead poisoning.80
More novel, and increasingly widespread, were complaints about fatigue. Textile workers linked fatigue with physical strain, as did miners. German weavers talked of the hard work that bad materials or multiple looms caused, in addition to the burdens of monotony; they specifically mentioned how tired they became when they had not eaten well. Crimmitschau strikers complained of a 'chronic fatigue' that damaged their health and caused a high rate of infant mortality, as well as ruining the quality of their family life. Metal workers, however, cited a somewhat different kind of fatigue, due to boredom and personal tensions on the job. A glass worker told of the anger that burst out against anyone holding up the job, and a pace that left him limp even before the day was over. Printing machine workers dropped the traditional complaints over the danger of metal dust, and talked of the headaches and sleeplessness that 50 percent of them claimed to suffer from. Leather workers spoke of the monotony and tensions of the new systems of work. Three-fifths of the workers in the Daimler automobile factory said that their work tired them because of its intensity.81 A Berlin machine worker told how overtime left him exhausted, too tired
to undress or eat or to do more than snap at his children: "My eyes burn so, if I can only sleep.'82 Many of Alfred Williams' colleagues in his locomotive factory were still tired even when they came to work, and could not get out of bed on a Sunday.83
The growing malady was nervous strain, more than physical burdens. British printers, citing the rising pace of work, talked of 'exhaustive' anguish 'through everything being wanted in a hurry.'84" Compositors generalized: 'We live in a hustling age,'85 and noted how the strain of long commuting added to the new burdens of the job. For German machine workers the rising intensity was translated into 'excessive muscular tension, pressure on the knees and elbow, overstraining of the eyes,'86 Scottish railway workers, whose nervousness caused them to fear accidents directly, were exhausted during the 1890s: 'Often the work is done with the men more asleep than awake, and that there are not more accidents is a miracle.' One Scottish worker spoke for thousands, in many industries, when he noted simply, 'My nervous system got into a state of collapse.'87
The impressions mount up, though they remain impressions. We cannot really measure changes in the intensity of work, though in individual cases such as the Scottish rails, with the massive increase in overtime, the workers' case is conclusive. It is clear that, given an understandably conservative approach to work and a still-fragile diet, even small changes in productivity could cause real tension. Continued improvements in worker health suggest that, overall, changes in work were not too damaging, that mental strain, in partially replacing physical strain, could be endured. But what seemed to be occurring was at least as important as what was occurring. A new, obviously modern outlook toward work's burdens was fast arising, stressing the toll on nerves. Whether they should have thought so or not, many workexs judged work less enjoyable than it had been in the past. 'Work was a pleasure compared to what it is now,'88 said a British engineer, while a German, telling how his limbs began to shake two hours before quitting time, recalled that rural work used to last all day but leave energy for laughter in the evening. At an extreme the job had become a 'torture,' because of the mental anguish it caused. 'We are driven like dumb cattle, in our folly, until the flesh is off our bones, and the marrow out of them.' 'The millman has no pleasure of his life; for it seems to me that we are living to work, and not working to live.'89
Notes
1. H. A. Turner, Trade Union Growth, Structure and Policy: A Comparative Study of the Cotton Unions (London, 1962), 258 ff.
2. A. L. Levine, Industrial Retardation in Britain (London, 1967), passim; Manuel Sartzew, Steinkohlenpreise und Dampfkraftkosten (Munich, 1914); Eric Hobsbawm, 'Custom, Wages, and Work Load,' in Labouring Men (New York, 1964), 413; Finlay A. Gibon, A Compilation of Statistics off the Coal Mining Industry (Cardiff, 1922), 11 — 12; Jean Bouviei, 'A Propos d'une enquête statistique: Profit et croissance en France au XIXe siècle,' Bulletin de la société d'histoire moderne (1965 ), 2—7.
3. Jean Marczewski, Introduction à l'histoire quantitative (Geneva, 1965), 148.
4. J. Lapierre,'Les grèves des platrières du bassin de Paris,' La Vie ouvrière (1912), 129; R. B. Forrester, The Cotton Industry in France (Manchester, 1921), 41.
5. Ministère du travail et de la prévoyance sociale: office du travail, Enquête sur le travail à domicile dans l'industrie de la fleur artificielle (Paris, 1913), 309; 'La Grève des diamintaires d'Anvers,' La Revue du travail (1904), 539 ff.
6. E. P. Thompson, 'Time, Work Discipline and Industrial Capitalism,' Past and Present (1967), 56—97 eloquently outlines the new sense of time, but exaggerates the speed of its impact even in England. Hobsbawm, in 'Custom,' more properly notes the traditionalism of work as late as the mid-nineteenth century. I would extend this still further even for many English industrial workers.
7. Society of Amalgamated Toolworkers, Monthly Journal, 1914.
8. Emile Vandervelde, La Belgique ouvrière (Paris, 1906), 711 — 12; Louis A. Hill, White Slavery in the Bakery Trade (London, 1908).
9. William Dawson, The Evolution of Modern Germany (London, 1908), passim; Norman McKillop, The Lighted Flame: A History of the Associated Society of Locomotive Engineers and Firemen (London, 1950), 78; Labour Gazette, 1890 ff.; B. Seebohm Rowntree, Land and Labour; Lessons from Belgium (London, 1911), passim.
10. Ministère du travail: direction du travail, Rapports sur l'application des loisjéglementant le travail en 1911 (Paris, 1912), xxvi; B. Quantz, 'Uber die Arbeitsleisturag und das Verhâltnis von Arbeitslohn und Arbeitszeit im Mauiergewerbe,' Jahrbùcher fur Nationalôkonomie (1912), 643-57.
11. Rowntree, Land, passim; Dawson, Evolution; Ministère du travail, Rapports: Salaires et durée du travail dans les industries textiles (Brussels, 1905), 226, and Salaires et durée du travail dans les industries des métaux (Brussels, 1907), 46 ff. ; Marie Bernays, Untersuchungen iiber die Schwankungen der Arbeitsintensitât (Leipzig, 1911), passim.
12. 'System Ca'canny in der deutschen Schuhwarenindustrie,' Zeitschrift fur Sozialwissenschaft (1909), 555; E. D. Howard, Causes and Extent of the Industrial Progress of Germany (London, 1907); Henri Charriaut, La Belgique moderne (Paris, 1910), 228; Arthur Shadwell, Industrial Efficiency (London, 1906), II, 51 ff.; Dora Lande, Arbeits- und Lohnverhàltnisse in der Berliner Maschinenindustrie zu Beginn des 20. Jahrhunderts (Leipzig, 1910); Kurt Uhde, Die Produktions-Bedingungen des deutschen und englischen Steinkohlen-Bergbaus (Jena, 1907).
13. As in printing, with 52 hours per week, or food processing, with 54. Labour Gazette, passim. In more advanced manufacturing only miners approached this as a group, with 51 to 54 hours per week, depending on the region, in 1890.
14. Archives nationales (France) F713891.
15. Carl von Tyszka, Die Lebenshaltung der arbeitenden Klassen (Jena, 1912); A. Slosse and E. Waxweiler, Enquête sur le régime alimentaire de 1065 ouvriers belges (Brussels, 1910), 61 and 175.
16. Fanny Imle, Kritisches und Positives zur Frage der Arbeit-slosenfùrsorge (Jena, 1907); Otto Hommer, Die Entwicklung und Tatigkeit des deutschen Metallarbeiterverbandes (Berlin, 1912), 35 ff.
17. Miners Federation of Great Britain, Minutes of the Proceedings of the Board of Conciliation Established between the Federated Coalowners and the MFGB (Manchester, 1909); E. W. Evans, The Miners of South Wales (Cardiff, 1961), passim.
18. Verband der Maler, Lackierer, Anstreicher, Tuncher und Weiss-binder Deutschlands, Jahres-Berichf, 1911, 34.
19. Archives de la Sûreté publique de la province de Liège, Carton IX, 1907 report on Huy masons' strike; Otto Jeidels, Die Methoden der Arbeiterentlôhnung in der rheinisch-westfâlischen Eisen-industrie (Berlin, 1907); The Metal Worker, 1907.
20. Ministère du travail, Office du travail, Enquête sur la. réduction de la durée du travail le samedi (semaine anglaise) (Paris, 1913), 240.
21. Eleanor Rathbone, Report on the Results of the Special Inquiry into the Conditions of Labour at the Liverpool Docks (Liverpool, 1904), 54 and passim.
22. Shadwell, Efficiency, I, 145; T. H. Burnham and G. O. Hoskins, Iron and Steel in Britain, 1870-1930 (London, 1943), 147.
23. Levine, Retardation ; National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives, Monthly Report, 1912; R. B. Forrester, The Cotton Industry in France (Manchester, 1921), 102.
24. Hobsbawm, 'Custom,'; Albert Cauvin, La Durée du travail dans les houillères de Belgique (Paris, 1909); James B. Jefferys, The Story of the Engineers (London, 1946), 156 ff.
25. A. L. Pigou, Principles and Methods of Industrial Peace (London, 1905), 29 ff.; Archives départementales de la Loire 92M/219, report of 1913; Zentralverband der Maurer Deutschlands, Der Kampf um die Arbeitsbedingungen (Hamburg, 1909); Ferdinand
Tônnies, 'Der Hamburger Strike von 1896/97,' Archiv fur Gesetzgebung und Politik (1897), 673 ff.
26. Robert Tressell, Ragged-Trousered Philanthropists (London, 1955), 579; Amédée Dunois, 'Le Lockout de la maçonnerie,' Pages libres (1908), 53; Verband der Maler, Lackierer, Anstreicher, Tiïncher und Weissbinder Deutschlands, Protokoll der Tarifverhandlungen im Malergewerbe CHamburg, 1910), 349; La Bataille syndicaliste, 24 April 1912; Archives nationales (France), F712788, report on Rennes carpenters, May, 1908; Kurt Bergmann, Die Stellungnahme der organisierten Arbeiter zum Stùcklohn (Berlin, 1909), 67.
27. Quantz, 'Arbeitsleistung,' passim; Zentralverband der Maurer, Kampf, passim; Verband der Maler, Protokoll, 366.
28. Quantz, 'Arbeitsleistung,' passim; Lucien Ferrand, 'La Hausse des loyers urbains,' La Revue socialiste (1914), 134.
29. A. E. Musson, The Typographical Association (London, 1954), 243.
30. Ibid., 243 ff.;Hans Hinke, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiter im Buchdruckgewerbe (Berlin, 1910), passim.
31. Paul Bureau, Le Contrat du travail (Paris, 1902), 87; Archives départementales des Vosges 8M992, 12-20 August, 1910, strike in Romanchamp textiles; Ministère du travail, Office du travail, Enquête relative aux modifications à apporter à la loi du 7 mars 1850 sur les moyens de constater les conventions entre patrons et ouvriers en matière de tissage et de bobinage (Paris, 1908), 20.
32. British Steel Smelters, Mill, Iron and Tinplate Workers Association, Monthly Report, 1914 and passim; Clemens Heiss, Die Entlohnungsmethoden in der Berliner Feinmechanik (Berlin, 1909), 145.
33. Friendly Society of Ironfounders, First Conference Report (March, 1911), 33.
34. Jefferys, Engineers, 125 ff.; Lande, Arbeitsverhàltnisse; National Amalgamated Union of Labour, Quarterly Reports, 1908,passim; R. Broda and Julius Deutsch, Das Moderne Proletariat (Berlin, 1910), 147;Le Peuple, 8 June 1902.
35. Hobsbawm, 'Custom,' 360; Generalkommission der Gewerk-schaften Deutschlands, Correspondenzblatt, 23 April 1904; Jeidels, Methoden, passim; Jule de Clerck, De Werkstaking Carets, 1914 (Ghent, 1914).
36. Amalgamated Society of Engineers, Monthly Journal, December 1904.
37. Levine, Retardation; E. H. Phelps Bxown, Growth of British Industrial Relations (London, 1959), 86 ff.
38. Miners' Federation of Great Britain, Annual Conference, 1909; H. Stanley Jevons, The British Coal Trade (London, 1915), 528 ff. and passim; Alfred Bosenick, Uber die Arbeitsleistung beim Steinkohlenbergbau in Preussen (Stuttgart, 1906); N. Dethier, Centrale syndicale des travailleurs des mines de Belgique (Brussels,
1950), 127; Alfred Levenstein, Aus der Tiefe, Arbeiterbriefe (Berlin, 1905), 60 ff.; Max Metzner, Die soziale Fùrsorge im Bergbau (Jena, 1911), 40.
39. Philip Bagwell, The Railwaymen (London, 1963); Amalgamated Society of Railway Servants, The Railwaymen 's Charter (London, 1907), 17; M.F.M.N., 'Ce que voulaient les cheminots,' Revue socialiste (1910), 723-4.
40. Ben Tillett, History of the London Transport Workers' Strike (London, 1911), 8; Royal Commission on Labour, Minutes of the Evidence, Group 'B' (Transport by Water and Trans-port by Land) (London, 1892, C 6708), I, 546; Ferdinand Tonnies, 'Hafen-arbeiter und Seeleute in Hamburg vor dem Strike 1896—97,' Archiv fur soziale Gesetzgebung und Statistik (1897), 173 ff.; Musée social, 1910.
41. National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives, Mo-nthly Report, February 1913, from a strike at Knighton Fields.
42. United Society of Boilermakers and Iron Shipbuilders, Monthly Report, December 1893.
43. Jefferys, Engineers, passim; London Typographers' Journal, June 1912; Metallarbeiter-Zeitung, 1911.
44. W. Mosses, The History of the United Pattern Makers' Association (London, 1922), 98; Lande, Arbeitsverhâltnisse; Ellic Howe and H. E. Waite, The London Society of Compositors (London, 1948), 203; J. L. M. Perquy, La Typographie à Bruxelles: au début du XXe siècle (Brussels, 1904), 419; Action syndicale (du Pas-de-Calais) 3 November 1907; Tressell, Philanthropists, 423; 'La Grève des mineurs dans le pays de Liège, ' Bulletin du Comité central du travail industriel (1911), 106; Royal Commission, Minutes, I, 3-58.
45. Metzner, Fùrsorge; Cari Legien, Der Streik der Hafenarbeiter und Seeleute in Hamburg-Altona (Hamburg, 1897); Amalgamated Society of Engineers, Report for the Royal Commission on Labour (London, 1892); Waldemar Jolko, Untersuchungen icber die Entlôhnungsmethoden in der Berliner Metallindustrie (Berlin, 1911); Friedrich Syrup, 'Die gesetzliche Begrenzung der Arbeit-szeit,' Thunen-Archiv (1912), 483.
46. Lande, Arbeitsverhâltnisse; London Typographers' Journal, June 1912; Cauvin, Durée, 176.
47. Charles Booth, Life and Labour of the People of London (London, 1894), V, 108.
48. Royal Commission on Labour, Minutes of the Evidence, Group 'A ' (Mines, Engineering, Hardware, Shipbuilding and Cognate Trades) (London, 1893), C. 6894, 17.
49. Ludwig Bernhard, Die Akkordarbeit in Deutschland (Leipzig, 1903); Alan Fox, A History of the National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives (Oxford, 1958), 263; Elizabeth JSrunner, 'The Origins of Industrial Peace, British Boot and Shoe Industry,' Oxford Economic Papers (1949), 251; John Jewkes and E. M. Gray, Wages and Labour in the Lancashire Cotton Spinning
Industry (Manchester, 1935), 142.
50. Heinrich tsrauns, Der Ùbergang von der Handweberei zum Fabrikbetrieb in der niederrheinische Samt- und Seiden-Industrie (Leipzig, 1906); Walter Timmermanri, Die Entlôhnungsmethoden in der Hannoverschen Eisenindustrie {Berlin, 1906); Arthur Pugh, Men of Steel (London, 1951), 133 ff.
51. Sidney Webb and Beatrice Webb, Industrial Democracy (London, 1902), 401.
52. E. Seidel, 'Der Einfluss der Maschine im Getreide-umschlagsverkehr,' Die Neue Zeit (1911-12), 1015 ff.
53. Jevons, Coal, 356; Fox, History, passim.
54. Jack Ov/en,Ironmen (Middlesbrough, n.d.), 111.
55. Bernhard, Akkordarbeit; Ernst Martel, La Vérité sur le lockout des carrières d'Ecaussone (Brussels, 1910)
56. Timmermann, Entlôhnungsmethoden; Ernst Gùnther, Die Entlôhnungsmethoden in der bayerisrchen Eisen- una Maschinen Industrie (Berlin, 1908); Maurice Vignes, 'Le Bassin de Briey et la politique de ses entreprises sidérurgiques ou minières,' Revue socialiste (1913), 596; Clemens Heiss, Auslese und Anpassungder Arbeiter in der Berliner Feinmecha nik (Leipzig, 1910); Franz Schulte, Die Entlôhnungsmethoden in der Berliner Maschinen-industrie (Berlin, 1906).
57. Amalgamated Society of Engineers, Monthly Report, May 1906.
58. Maurice Kahn, 'Les Evénements de Limoges,' Pages libres (1905), 14; Sidney Pollard, History of Labour in Sheffield (Liverpool, 1959), 229 and passim.
59. Archives municipales de Bruxelles, 203, report of 1912.
60. August Lôhr, Beitràge zur Wiirdigung der Akkord-Lohnmethode (Mônchen-Gladbach, 1912); Adolf Levenstein, Die Arbeiterfrage (Munich, 1912), passim.
61. Hobsbawm, 'Custom,' 138; Karl Fiackh, Die rheinische Seiden-Veredlungs-Industrie (Crefeld, 1926).
62. Booth, Life, V, 110; Howe and Waite, Compositors, 198; Hinke, Auslese.
63. Webb and Webb, Democracy, 286 ff.; British Steel Smelters, Monthly Report, 1908; Jeidels, Methoden; Max Morgenstern, Auslese und Anpassung der industrieller Arbeiterschaft betrachtet hei den Offenbacher Lederarbeitern (Freiburg-i. Br., 1911), 24 ff.; Carl Fischer, Denkwurdigkeiten und Erinnerungen eines Arbeiters (Leipzig, 1904), 387; Alphonse Loyau, 'La Semaine anglaise en France,' Vie ouvrière (1913), 374; Quant, 'Arbeitsleistung,' 643 ff.
64. Otto Bosselman, Die Entlôhnungsmethoden in aer sùdwestdeutsch-luxemburgischen Eisenindustrie (Berlin, 1906); Max Morgenstern et al., Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft (Leipzig, 1912).
65. Pollard, Sheffield, 229 ff.; Marie Bemays, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft der geschlosene Grossindustrie (Leipzig, 1910; M. L. Yates, Wages and Labour Conditions in British Engineering
(London, 1937); Archives nationales (France) F712781, report on Rive-de-Gier mines, August 1908; Eric Hobsbawm, 'General Labour Unions in Britain, 1889—1914,' Economic History Review (1949), 131 ; Webb and Webb, Democracy, passim.
66. Gùnther, Entlôhnungsmethoden, passim.
67. Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, 33—7; see also Bernhard Schildbach, Verfassung und Verwaltung der Freien Gewerkschaften in Deutschland (Leipzig, 1910) and Werner Jahn, Arbeitnehmer-und Arbeitgeber-Organisationen in der deutscher Holzindustrie (Dissertation, University of Cologne, 1921). By 1914 about 47% of German woodworkers' agreements set minimum pay, while 38% set average pay — both potentially satisfactory resolutions of the main objections to the piece rate outside the older craft setting.
68. Lôhr, Beitràge, 31.
69. Friendly Society of Ironfounders, Monthly Journal, 1902 and 1905; Gùnther, Entlôhnungsmethoden; Jeidels, Methoden; Board of Trade, Report of an Enquiry into Working Class- Rents, Houses and Retail Prices. . in the Principal Industrial To wns of France (London, 1909, Cd. 4512); Schulte, Entlôhnungsmethoden; Kurt Bergmann, Stellungnahme der organisierten Arbeiter jzum Stucklohn (Berlin, 1908), passim.
70. Bernhard, Akkordarbeit; Gùnther, Entlôhnungsmethoden; Léon de Seilhac, Les Progrès du machinisme et l'hostilité ouvrière: la grève d'Hazebrouck (Paris, 1909); Jeidels, Methoden; National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives, Monthly Report, 1912; Bataille syndicaliste, 11 November 1913.
71. Jefferys, Engineers, 125 ff.; Edward C. Howard and Mona WiLson, West Ham (London, 1907), 163.
72. Amalgamated Society of Engineers, Monthly Report, May 1902.
73. H. A. Clegg et al., A History of British Trade Unionism since 1889 (Oxford, 1964), I, 343; Jefferys, Engineers, passim.
74. Musée social, 1913, 55; James Laux, 'Travail et Travailleurs dans l'industrie-automobile jusqu'en 1914,' Mouvement social (19*72), 9-26.
75. Phelps Brown, Growth, 86 ff.; Levine, Retardation.
76. Typographical Association, Report of the Quinquennial Delegates Meeting (Manchester, 1908), 31-2.
77. Yates, Wages, 71 ff. ; Amalgamated Society of Engineers, Monthly Report, May 1907.
78. Metallarbeiter-Zeitung, 20 March 1912.
79. Léon de Seilhac, Le Lock-out d'Anvers (Paris, 1908 ), 110.
80. Carl Lindow, 'Soziales aus dem Hamburger Hafen,' Die Neue Zeit (1911 — 12), 209; Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, passim; George-Werner, Bin Kumpel: Erzahlung aus den Leben der Bergarbeiter, (Berlin, 1930), 17; Hans Thiele, 'Der Werftarbeiterstreik von J ahre 1910,' Jahrbuch fur Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung, und Volk-swirtschaft im Deutschen Reich (1912), 754 ff.; Histoire de la Belgique contemporaine, 1840-1914 (Brussels, 1928), I, 246;
Metzner, Fùrsorge.
81. Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, passim; Historische Kommission zu Berlin, Sammlung Saarschmidt 32, poster; Wenzel Holek, Leben-sgang eines deutsch-tschechischen Handarbeiters (Jena, 1909), 320 ff.; Hinke, Auslese, passim; Fritz Schuman, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Automobilindustrie (Leipzig, 1911), passim.
82. Broda and Deutsch, Proletariat, 173.
83. Alfred Williams, Life in a Railway Factory (London, 1915), passim.
84. Ellic Howe, The London Compositor (London, 1947), 323.
85. The London Typographical Journal, August 1909.
86. Deutscher Metall-Arbeiter-Verband, Verwaltungsstelle Bielefeld, Jahresbericht (1906), 9.
87. Bagwell, Railwaymen, 14.
88. Jefferys, Engineers, 132; statement by an engineering worker in 1915, comparing conditions to those of 1900; Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, 65 ff.
89. British Steel Smelters, Monthly Report (1902), 163.
CONCLUSION
It would be misleading to end stressing nervous exhaustion alone. The work experience remained too diverse to be captured by any single formula. Traditional zeal for work or satisfactions that could be found in some of the new work arrangements could produce positive accommodations on the job. Certainly some of the leading developments of the period, such as the rise of big business or the growing sophistication of technology, did not produce a knee-jerk reaction among workers. For many, changes were sufficiently gradual or indirect that their impact was muted. Big business, for example, was often concealed behind its personal emissaries and the policy of paternalism; it could command a certain deference even when tensions on the job mounted. In a situation of evolutionary change, the generational shifts within the working class could also limit hostilities; aging workers could feel disillusioned by their jobs, but the new generation, with a slight shift in motivations, could maintain more optimism. There was some deep despair — T go to work as I'd go to death'1 — but more commonly even the hostile reactions to changes in work were based on a belief that the job could and should have value.
There is no question that, dealing with impressions, complaints of monotony predominate, but expressions of pleasure deserve attention as well. British shoe workers noted that work was faster and more disciplined, but they took pride in their skill, noting that good eyes and judgement had partially replaced a supple hand.2 German weavers — except women with young children who wanted home work — noted the improvement modern methods had brought. 'We don't want the good old days back again, for things aren't bad in the factory compared to what they used to be.'3 Some workers, particularly on the Continent, took pride in a well-ordered workplace, expecting to spend much of their time in it; here the traditional association with the work site meshed with advancing paternalism. German workers thus showed considerable interest in improvements in first aid stations and washrooms, one worker claiming, after conditions were bettered, that 'these rules are worth much more to us than a pay rise.'4 It was not hard to develop a proprietary interest in one's job, granting that there was a clear economic stake as well. Lancashire cotton workers carefully
defended their skills against their aides, who were often their relatives as well, keeping them clearly subordinate; South Wales miners objected to a shift system introduced after the eight-hours bill was passed because they wanted no one else working in their spot. One miner, in his autobiography, noted his workmates' pride at a job well done, when they could fill their trams to the brim in good time.5 Alfred Williams, though himself alienated from his work, talked with some wonder at his many colleagues who welcomed hard work and overtime. Deferential to their foreman — 'Be this all mine, sir?' they asked when they received their pay — they sometimes talked of returning to the country, but rarely did because of their attachment to factory and town life.6 A German miner: 'There is no work so interesting as that of the miner.' A textile worker: 'Work gives me pleasure.' Aad metal workers cited their interest in good machines, in managers who were friendly and, as already discussed, in the challenge the piece rate could bring.7
Against this, the evidence, particularly explicit from Germany, of sensitive workers, often with a craft background, for whom modern industrial jobs were a torment. A miner spoke of his need for work in 'conditions worthy of men,'8 while textile workers in Monchen-Gladbach told an observer how mechanization and the piece rate system had driven all interest from their jobs.9 Adolf Levenstein's surveys among socialist workers produced the more anguished laments. Metal workers told of their frustrated desire to be creative. One wanted a profession 'which occupies mind and body together,' while several wanted artistic work, often dreaming of this on the job: 'Forms and pictures pour from my mind's eye, O that I could paint them all. 0 that I were free.'1 ° Max Lotz, the unusually articulate Ruhr miner, wrote in detail of his mental suffering. His work terrified him, though his 'inner pride' prevented him from admitting this to his fellows; he feared for his life from the moment he entered the elevator. And the work was becoming increasingly brutal, so that no wage could compensate for it. For Lotz and for many of his fellows, work deadened the mind and was endured only as a vile necessity.
But the most sensitive workers were definitely not typical; they said so themselves. Lotz found his fellows slow-witted and dull; he knew they did not suffer as he did. Robert Tressell, the Hastings construction worker, knew the same of his workmates, as did Alfred Williams in the Swindon locomotive plant. Apathy, then, more than explicit torment characterized the factories. Levenstein's workers got through the day by thinking of something else. 'The only good thing about machines is that one can at least ponder other things.11 Several miners, noting
their lack of pleasure in the work itself, found matters of geological interest in the pits. Only 24 percent of the miners thought about their work while they were doing it; 17 percent thought about pay, 5 percent about family, another 5 percent about social and political questions, and 43 percent were 'indifferent.' Among textile workers: 15 percent thought about the work, 11 percent about pay, 11 percent about their families, 18 percent about politics, 15 percent indifferent; and among metal workers, 28 percent pay, 25 percent work, 3 percent family, 13 percent politics, and 13 percent indifferent. One, thinking about socialism, said 'I build a new world while I work.' Others talked more in terms of alternation, devoting attention to the job "when it was interesting and turning to the union or the party or their h atred of th_eir employers otherwise. Still another metal worker put the alternation of interest somewhat differently. Whenever he took a new job, in a new spot, 'the mind finds at least some excitement at first' — but it lasted only a few weeks, after which 'wild longings' tormented him.12
All this suggests a five-fold division among workers., with many workers capable of passing from one to another depending on mood. At one extreme, those who took positive pleasure, at the other, those who felt tormented. In the middle workers who turned from boredom to thoughts of social reform; these could shade off from the tormented group, for Max Lotz finally declared that only socialist fervor kept h_im alive. But also those who got through the day by thinking about their earnings; most textile workers in Mônchen-Gladbach, concluded a careful observer, just wanted to earn their money.13 A German miner, no great socialist and upwardly mobile, conveyed something of the same attitude: mine work, at least in a tough vein, was 'hell on earth, and it is endurable for the miners only if he earns good money and isn't unnecessarily criticized by the foreman.'14 And finally the apathetic. Another German worker-autobiographer told of how the indifference of workers — especially those of rural or small-town origin, and the less skilled — blocked any effort to attack bad working conditions. Paul Gôhre, in a Leipzig engineering plant, found his mates divided between those who liked their jobs when they paid well, not caring much what they did otherwise, and those who claimed that no one could work for pleasure.15 The sense of goallessness was widespread in Germany. A textile worker: 'I have very many wishes but what use are empty wishes to me.' Bourgeois sociologists who asked what should be changed to make work better found most workers incapable of answering, for the question had no meaning. Some articulated the sentiment, talking vaguely of coming out all right 'at the end' or finishing up 'where the
wind blows me.' Again, the idea of pleasure on the job was foreign; work was a necessity and modern work was no better or worse than anticipated; as an automobile worker put it, 'things would be fine if they stayed as they are.'16 Tressell found much the same sentiment in his craft: 'The majority desire nothing but to be allowed to work, and as for their children, why "what was good enough for themselves oughter be good enough for the kids."'17
A five-fold division may seem scant advance, after a lengthy consideration of the specific job issues that caused most concern in the decades before World War I. We can add the obvious, that divisions retarded efforts to remedy problems on the job and help explain that phenomenon far too neglected by students of the labor movement: the workers who did not join or consistently support union or political organizations. For both the apathetic worker and the worker who found great pleasure on the job might easily be repelled by the idea of organization for combat; through intimidation or positive inclination they might indeed belong to a group specifically opposed to any form of class struggle, but more commonly they would join nothing. Less formally, workers of this sort could proudly ignore strikes, boasting of keeping their jobs while others could not support their families. The struggles between workers and strikers cannot be dismissed as a fight between conscious and unconscious alone, nor can it be explained only by intimidation — and when, as in France, 16 percent of all strikes commanded support from less than 50 percent of the relevant work group, and the average strike only 65 percent, the numbers involved were considerable as well. Hear the comments of workers during a procession of striking ditch-diggers in Paris: 'What a bunch of loafers: they'd do better to work instead of walking around.'18
The more subtle differences in reaction to work would also cause debate over protest tactics among organized workers. Some labor leaders and their constituents were prone, under stress, to urge bad work as a method of agitation. The construction union in France recommended shoddy production as an attack on subcontractors: 'For bad pay, bad work.'19 This recommendation could strike a responsive chord when only a slow-up was involved, for it was fair to control the pace of work; but poor production was normally resisted as a general tactic, because most workers continued to have more pride in their work. Literal sabotage against the product seems to have been most uncommon; else employers, so quick to comment on slow-ups, would have attacked the practice. In fact unions that advised poor work usually had to back down.20 It was workers who accused their
employers of a poor job, not the reverse; a German machine worker, for example, told of how it hurt him to see a screw going in wrong, though he lacked time to correct it.21
Indeed it was the very fact that so many workers believed their jobs could have value, even if far from satisfied with what the jobs actually were, that accounts for the level of concern over working conditions in the period. Few workers abandoned themselves to the depths of despair or even waited for a social revolution to improve their lot. They still believed that they knew what was appropriate to their job and its skill and what was not, and they were prepared to act on this belief. South Wales miners knew what a fair wage was for abnormally difficult pit faces. Skilled British workers generally knew what their job involved and who was qualified to undertake it. We are dealing, overall, with something less than total alienation, in which most workers believed that their work was hell and lived only for external rewards.22
We cannot pretend to break down the categories of worker reaction into a precise numerical statement. Adolf Levenstein's figures, though exaggerating the amount of job dissatisfaction because of the focus on a committed socialist constituency, allow some suggestions.23 Textile workers were far less likely to express pleasure in their work than other groups (7 percent compared to 17 percent of the metal workers and 15 percent of the miners). This accurately suggests that the most extensive dissatisfaction at work was not a function of the most rapid changes in technology, business organization, or pace. Diversity, an ongoing sense of skill, plus relatively higher pay levels and (possibly) a more exclusive sense of masculinity of the job were more important. Skilled workers, though seemingly under attack by many of the developments on the job, surely found more satisfaction than the unskilled — and again the pecking order could apply to some improbable trades. Grain dockers, for example, felt a craft-like superiority to day laborers; coal loaders took pride in their strength.24 Age factors are more confusing. Older workers labored more steadily than the young; so if assiduity meant that some satisfactions were found, then older workers had learned to adapt better than their younger colleagues. Yet some must have plodded along out of fear or apathy, disillusioned by the changes that had already challenged their work habits.25
Let us go beyond this vague effort to flesh out the labels concerning reactions to work. It seems probable that British workers were less antagonized by their work than were many Germans — and not, as we have seen, because at this point the pace was lighter. There were no work pollsters in Britain, and there were plenty of individual workers
ready to talk about how things were getting worse on the job. But the sense that work was hell does not emerge strongly. And from this, a more important speculation. It seems probable that the ability to find some satisfactions on the job was increasing with advancing industrialization. This, rather than a special national character, accounts for the differences in impressions between Britain and Germany. It relates to the differences between German textiles and metals — for textiles, a more stagnant industry, reproduced older complaints more than new ones and drew a decreasing percentage of the workforce anyway. If we give any credence to admittedly diverse polls, evidence from Germany confirms the suggestion that satisfaction with work rose with advancing industrialization. Against Levenstein's depressing picture of majority dissatisfaction, a survey in 1928 suggested that 65 percent of all skilled workers and 44 percent of the unskilled felt more pleasure than distaste for their work.26
Why might maturing industrialization have produced more job satisfaction? Parental guidance and job choice prepared a new worker for what was coming. Changes in the pre-war period allow further suggestions. Advancing technology fascinated some workers and relieved physical burdens for some others. Business rationalization could reduce the sense of personal dependence and arbitrariness on the job. Piece work, once its threat proved exaggerated, could maintain, if not increase, a worker's personal control of his work. While nervous tension undoubtedly increased, the continuing addiction to overtime — due allowance made for employer pressure — suggests that it did not undermine the combination of traditional and novel justifications for work. But factors on the work site alone cannot account for the surprising ability of the labor force, as industrialization advanced, to find reasons for pleasure on the job. Some developments indeed were endured, rather than welcomed, because of changes in the working-class culture in other areas. The growing unacceptability of unemployment had its obvious counterpart in attachment to work. Job choices, even if parentally guided, must often have been disappointed. How many workers, for example, went into engineering in the belief that it was almost a craft, only to find a decade later that it was on the way towards mass production? Yet job choice could also produce a sense of commitment, a willingness to ride a tide of change; and the tone of the working class was still being set by younger entrants in any event. Those without an urban manufacturing background had been less likely to discern a choice in their job and less likely to find or create some satisfactions on it. The labor movement itself would play a vital role in
the adaptive process; we have seen that important categories of workers, including some of those most likely to be offended by technological and business development — had this hit them without the buffer of their own organizations — were able to mount significant defense.
Yet this was a period of tension. Ability to find some job satisfactions should not be confused with contentment. Workers in many industries, as in engineering and the crafts, had reason to feel insecure.27 That rationalization or technological change did not drive most of them to despair was obviously important; had they despaired they could not have reacted cogently to specific changes on the job. But their satisfactions depended not only on traditional criteria, even as these might be newly translatable by piece rates or bonuses. The place of the job in life was being gradually redefined. We cannot find the working class suddenly or unanimously deciding to view the job only as an instrument, to be endured for as short a time as possible and only in so far as it paid for other things. To complete the picture, without pretending a total sketch of working-class life, we must turn to other aspects of behavior that related closely to the job — whether to supplement it, to protest against it, or to compensate for it.
Notes
1. Adolf Levenstein, Die Arbeiterfrage (Munich, 1913), 5 4.
2. Alan Fox, A History of the National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives (Oxford, 1958), 356.
3. Robert Wilbrandt, Die Weber in der Gegenwart (Jena, 1906), 126.
4. Gerhard Adelman, Quellensammlung zur Geschichte der sozialen Betriebsverfassung: Ruhrindustrie under besonderer Beriicksichtigung des Industrie und Handelskammerbezirks Essen (Bonn, 1960), I, 247.
5. Miners' Federation of Great Britain, Executive Committee Meetings, 1909; Arthur Shadwell, Industrial Efficiency (London, 1906), I, passim.
6. Alfred Williams, Life in a Railway Factory (London, 1915), 294.
7. Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, 54, 62, and passim; see also Heinridh Herkner, Problème der Arbeiterpsychologie (Leipzig, 1912).
8. Jakob Bâcher, Memorandum zur Bergarbeiterstreik irn Saarrevier (Neunkirchen, 1913), 16; see also Ernst Bernhard, 'Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft,' Jahrbuch fur Gesetzgebung, Ver-waltung, und Volkswirtschaft im Deutschen Reich (1911), 1399-1432.
9. Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, passim.
10. Adolf Levenstein, Aus der Tiefe, Arbeiterbriefe (Berlin, 1908), 24 ff.
11. Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, 127.
12. Ibid., 50 and passim; J. Zitzlaff, Arbeitsgleiderung in Maschinenbau-Unternehmungen (Jena, 1913).
13. Marie Bernays, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in geschlosene Grossindustrie (Leipzig, 1910), 171 ff.
14. Georg Werner, Ein Kumpel: Erzdhlung aus den Leben der Bergarbeiter (Berlin, 1930), 171 ff.
15. Moritz Bromme, Lebensgeschichte einer modernen Fabrikarbeiter (Leipzig, 1905); Paul Gohre, Drei Monate Fabrikarbeiter (Leipzig, 1913), 114.
16. Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, 23 and passim; Clemens Heiss, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiter in der Berliner Feinmechanik (Berlin, 1909), 223; Fritz Schuman, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Automobilindustrie (Leipzig, 1911), 118.
17. Robert Tressell, The Ragged Trousered Philanthropists (London, 1955), 424; see also Williams, Life, 306: 'It would take an earthquake to rouse many of the men; out of their apathy and indifference.'
18. Bataille syndicaliste, 10 January 1913;: see also Action syndicale (du Pas-de-Calais), 22 April 1906 and Peter N. Stearns, Revolutionary Syndicalism and French Labor' (New Brunswick, 1971), 123,, 125.
19. Fédération nationale des syndicats ouvriers du bâtiment, 2me Congrès (Puteau, 1904), 20.
20. Fédération nationale des travailleurs de l'industrie du bâtiment, Procès verbaux sténographiques des [réunions des délégations ouvrières et patronales (Paris, 1909), 190.
21. Bernhard,'Auslese,'1422.
22. Gohre, Fabrikarbeiter, passim; E.W. Evans, The Miners of South Wales (Cardiff, 1961), 204.
23. See Introduction; Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, 54 ff.
24. James Sexton, Sir James Sexton, Agitator (London, 1936), 199 ff.
25. Bernhard, 'Auslese,' 1426.
26. He de Man, Joy in Work (1928); Eric Hobsbawm, 'Custom, Wages and Work Load,' in Labouring Men (New York, 1964), 408.
27. E. H. Phelps Brown, Growth of British Industrial Relations (London, 1959), 216.
PART III REACTIONS AND COMPENSATIONS
INTRODUCTION
One of the most intriguing generalizations about pre-industrial labor, widely held at least for England, posits that work provided its own recreation and that a formal concept of leisure, distinct from the job, was largely unnecessary.1 The life spent on the job was thus not filled with labor in the modern sense, for not only a slower pace but also a variety of convivial social practices differentiated it. Workers sang and drank on the job. Some would add a qualification, that major festivals, which involved no work, were important as well, without however attacking the notion of the integrity of work and recreation. We have seen important holdovers from this tradition in the regrets workers expressed at their inability to sing or talk, once machine noise was introduced. The corollary of the generalization has naturally been that modern work becomes so intense and difficult that a separate period of leisure is essential.
This pattern was taking shape in many respects around the turn of the century. Some workers resisted the notion of more life outside the job, for their traditions had not been thoroughly disrupted; this was particularly true of small-town and rural producers. Others, craving relief from work, nevertheless found it difficult to develop new recreational habits. We can deal with a certain progression towards the modern work-leisure division that organizes many of the diversities within the working class. Within the most modern sector we can also suggest a tentative division between workers who adopted essentially bourgeois compensations for a life of work and those who developed a more purely proletarian culture.
But this evolution, while real and important, should not be construed as complete confirmation of the pre-industrial-industrial dichotomy. For the characterization of pre-industrial work never fully fitted urban labor. Urban workers had long sought explicit periods, apart from festivals, away from the job — the artisanal 'holy Monday' being the most obvious. Some of these had been eroded earlier in the industrial revolution; others were newly attacked around 1900. For many workers, then, the clear effort to defend more time off the job was in large measure a redefinition of older habits. Holy Monday was gone, so Saturday afternoon off was sought. Traditional festivals were
fading, so the idea of formal annual vacations gained some currency. The transition was not automatic. Employers, bent on rationalization, resisted demands to shorten the workday, though they found it easier to accept a predictable curtailment than the more random practices of the past. And workers themselves, though aware of the loss of tradition, might again find it difficult to develop a sense of alternatives. A payless holy Monday might make more sense than a new, and equally payless, half day off. And what would one do with an extra half hour each day or a free Saturday afternoon? We are only on the threshold of new recreational and family patterns which were partly novel but partly replacements of older activities.
All of this complicates what was otherwise a facile judgement on work. The effort to gain new forms of release from work does not automatically prove a deterioration of work itself; for urban manufacturing workers had always sought some release. We cannot even prove that important categories of workers — younger males, most notably — were working less in 1914 than in 1890 or 1850. The rhythm had changed and become more regular. Recreation was taking new forms, though some workers were caught uncomfortably between the disappearance of older outlets and an inability to devise appropriate new ones. Was the compensation adequate for changes at the workplace? Did workers turn from their job to their leisure or did most continue to strike a balance between the two?
Recreation, broadly construed, relates closely to workers' protest. There was a tendency for protest to bifurcate between efforts to attack problems on the job and efforts to improve life off the job. This is a simplification of course, and political protest, whose purposes have yet to be fully fathomed from the standpoint of social history, might attempt both. Nevertheless the difficulty of striking a balance between preserving quality on the job and improving opportunities outside was more apparent in protest than in daily life, though ultimately the two would have to interact.
Note
1. E. P. Thompson, 'Patriarchal Society, Plebian Culture,' Journal of Social History (1974), passim; Michael Marrus, The Rise of Leisure in Industrial Society (St. Louis, 1974); Keith Thomas, 'Work and Leisure in Pre-Industrial Society,' Past and Present (1964), 50 ff.
CHAPTER 7 REDUCING WORK TIME
The number of traditional leisure periods that persisted to 1900, particularly in the crafts but in many factories as well, reminds us of how gradual the evolution toward a modern rhythm of work was du ring the industrial revolution and, relatedly, how exaggerated some judgements of the disturbance caused by initial industrialization have been. The crafts naturally preserved more traces than factory industry. In Germany, manufacturers of toys, paper products, and jewels continued to receive days off around Christmas and other holidays, and at the confirmation of their children. Miners in all countries had customary breaks during the year. In France they took up to two weeks off, frequently after intensive overtime efforts, at the festival of Sainte-Barbe. British miners — particularly those in South Wales — maintained the tradition of 'playing' at some point during the week — particularly Saturday afternoons.1 In the Belgian mines holy Monday was preserved. 'I rest Mondays when I'm too tired.' 'I often take Mondays off because Sunday is not enough to have a little fun or take care of one's affairs.'2 The testimony came at a governmental inquiry leading to an eight-hours law, so the delegates were at special pains to stress that the main reason for their Monday holidays was fatigue from work. But other factors were involved, in an interesting mixture of tradition and novelty: Mondays were needed for shopping or for recovering from hangovers; they helped the worker recover from a tiring railroad trip on Sunday and they gave time to participate in customary village festivals.
Without pretending to offer a comprehensive survey o f practices of this sort, it is clear that many workers kept alive a rhythm of work that could be punctuated by a variety of interruptions. Absenteeism was another vital response to the pressures of work; we can see in it the physical burdens of work, as laborers needed time off for illness or fatigue, but also an effort to assert some personal control over the work pace — the analogue of the many individual and collective efforts at control which developed on the job. Absenteeism was common in a variety of settings. British metallurgical workers, on the piece rate, earned enough not to work a full week; here is one explanation for the widespread endurance of twelve-hour shifts amid intensive heat.
Older workers in particular took days off, though in Germany, with seniority less protected, regularity increased with age. At another extreme immigrant workers — who also earned more than their expectations demanded — were notoriously unpredictable. Italian laborers in the mines and metallurgical plants of France and Germany often would not bother to show up in bad weather. In French Lorraine many workers came in only 232 days a year, because they could earn enough on this schedule. Absenteeism was obviously common in the mines. In one Liège pit, workers did 4.5 percent worth of overtime during one week in 1907, in comparison to their regularly assigned hours, but took 6.2 percent of the hours off. Here again -was the personal factor: to some extent workers who were particularly vigorous, ambitious, or needy found the means for extra effort, while a greater number compensated for a strenuous pace with some informal holidays. A larger survey found winter absenteeism ranging from 4 to 9 percent during the winter, and 6 to 12 percent during the summer. Absenteeism in the Ruhr mines was about 6 percent — mainly on holidays and after paydays; in some pits the level rose to 17 percent. British rates were comparable, again varying greatly with the region: 11 percent in North Wales down to 4.6 percent in Northumberland. And whereas most of the informal breaks from work declined during the period, absenteeism may have risen with the advent of new workers; in Durham, rates of about 8 percent during the mid-'nineties had soared to 12 percent a few years later. Where irregular work was still more enshrined absenteeism loomed larger. Dockers from Liverpool to Hamburg proved quite resistant to efforts to regularize work during the week; despite massive unemployment and the listing of far more workers than were needed, the docks could on a given busy day find a shortage of available hands. Generally, the more strenuous the endeavor the more time was taken off; absenteeism was thus less common in most factories and the crafts. And there can be no neat correspondence "between those workers who needed time off and those who could afford to take it. Still, where up to a tenth of the labor force took a break each week, absenteeism was a powerful antidote to the routine of work.3
Frequent changes of jobs constituted another widely-used weapon. The practice was amazingly common, providing some insight into the hordes of wandering workers discovered by American students of mobility. We can go beyond the bald statement of frequent job-changing to some assessment of its causes and its incidence among key groups of workers — both important in relation to reactions to work. Most of the information comes from Germany, but a comparative
assessment is possible. The function of job-changing in providing a break from work was primary everywhere. Workers typically took a week or two between jobs, providing the kind of vacation most under their own control - with the obvious proviso that they had to have the means to survive their holiday and the ability to win another job.4
In German heavy industry turnover ran close to 100 percent per year; that is, as many workers took or abandoned jobs as held them, in the industry or the company, when the year began. In the Ruhr mines, for example, turnover ran 84 percent in 1895, 120 percent in 1900;it slowed during crisis — to 58 percent in 1903 and 35 percent in 1908 — but showed no signs of secular decrease. In 1913 it hit a whopping 147 percent. This partly reflects the large number of new jobs, of course. In 1907 there were 218,951 new jobs and only 173,093 departures, and so in all fast-growing industries turnover exaggerated the impression of job instability, for only about a third of the labor force was involved in annual switching. Yet even this is a massive figure, duplicated in the metal trades. Metal firms in the Dusseldorf area ran upwards of 86 percent turnover, machine building 98 percent, and metallurgy 90 percent with special branches such as blast furnace work hitting 163 percent. Turnover in most light industries was lower, though again the absence of growth makes the actual figures less distinctive. Textiles and leather ran 35—50 percent; about a third of all railway laborers quit during the year.5 The problem of turnover roused intense concern among employers, who tried at one point to blacklist workers who quit without notice. Individual companies were more successful in meeting the problem, for once again paternalism worked. Krupp, with its massive benefit programs plus a unwavering rule that no worker would be hired more than twice, had less than half the turnover rate of firms in the area.6
Workers quit for a variety of reasons. Almost all the turnover was at worker initiative; only 30 percent at most was involuntary in. the companies studied. Immigrants from East Germany or Italy, lacking roots in the new area, wandered from one competing firm to ano ther, or simply went home; seasonal fluctuations were considerable and many workers were following their initial plan of returning to the soil rather than reacting to manufacturing work directly. A direct search for higher pay was normally not the greatest cause of movement. In the Daimler plant, dissatisfaction with wages was the greatest single cause of any previous job-changing, followed by dismissal or lack of work, military service, or bad treatment. But this seems to have been unusual. Generally, the highest paying companies had most job-changing. In
Berlin engineering, problems of pay ranked third as a cause of movement. The desire for self-improvement came first — the search for a better job or more training — followed by lack of work, then pay, then differences with foremen, poor working conditions, and wanderlust. A survey in Rhineland metal-working had treatment in the plant, and particularly relations with foremen, the leading cause, followed by disagreements over setting the piece rate, wages, and poor conditions in the plant which made the job difficult.7 In other words, job-changing was a response to many of the problems workers faced in their day-to-day operations. The Rhineland workers, for example, stressed that their quitting was not directly against the piece rate system but rather against unfair limits to total earnings, given growing intensity of work — a precise reproduction of the general sentiments of most factory workers. But precise reasoning cannot convey the motives behind job changing. Workers trained in the crafts, in a small shop, often quit big companies because they disliked contact with the unskilled and the general atmosphere of the plant. 'I didn't feel really at home in the big hall,' one engineering worker noted in explaining why he returned to the small shop where he was trained.8 Other machine workers, more modernized, sought equipment they could be comfortable with. And, though disputes over pay rates might trigger departures, workers often recognized that they would lose money through job-changing but claimed they could not deny their wanderlust. For beyond all specific explanations was an urge toward freedom. Another Dusseldorf metal worker, asked by his employer why he quit, replied: 'Thirty factories stand open to me; you have only one.'9
Two general groupings of workers were most involved in job-changing. Workers trained in the crafts were following an old tradition. No precise records are available for job-changing in the crafts per se, but it surely remained extensive. Charles Booth talked with a carpenter who had worked for 79 employers during his 32 years. Rarely unemployed, he typically took a few weeks' holiday whenever he changed jobs; his other motive was a desire to know several foremen. The average Berlin printer had held four jobs if married, four and a half if single. The more specific custom of the wandering artisan still operated on the Continent. Skilled construction workers in France often practiced a modified tour de France; many German craftsmen discussed their tours, some of which could take them to neighboring countries. This craft tradition, brought into contact with the factories, helped account for the fact that more skilled workers than unskilled switched their jobs in the German metal and engineering shops studied. Many observers noted
the stability of workers of rural origin, who were grateful for regular employment; those promoted to semi-skilled machine work were particularly stable. Workers from the small towns — the craft-trained — were least likely to remain in one spot, specifically objecting to conditions in cities and factories but obviously following an older impulse as well. Within this framework specific factors on the job dictated considerable variation from one skill category to the next. In engineering, smiths, whose piece rates changed little, were far more stable than turners. And one cannot neglect the role of personal factors, which might relate to the choice of profession in the first place. The job-changers were typically repeaters and the vast majority of all switching occurred during the first year of employment. Craft traditions, specific reactions to new job conditions, and an indefinable, personal itch to move on combined to produce the surprising instability of skilled workers in the first generations of factory industry.10
Important groups of unskilled workers were job-changers as well, even if lower wage levels and lesser bargaining power held them back. High turnovers of new arrivals to the mines, not the skilled miners, suggest this pattern. In textiles, if the unskilled were slightly less likely to change jobs than the skilled they were much more likely to switch professions, and many semi-skilled textile workers in Germany had been employed in several industries. Spinners were more prone to this than weavers, for the familial structure of weaving was greater, gui ding job choice. Correspondingly women were more likely to switch jobs than men within any given industry. The unskilled were workers without a particular professional interest or pride. If some from rural backgrounds clung to their jobs, others, as we have seen, wanted to move back to the countryside.11 And the unskilled from the cities themselves were eager to find better conditions.12
Job-changing was thus a vital outlet for many types of workers. It had one inherent limitation: it was confined to the younger. Up to three-quarters of all job-changing — and almost all of the voluntary changing — came from workers under thirty. Unmarried men and women, in their prime period of vigor and skill, could play the game. Older workers had to stick to their jobs, no matter what conditions prevailed.
And job-changing as a permanent if individual solution to problems at work and the need for time off had a limited future, even for many of the young. There was no sign of decrease in Germany before World War I, because of the vast inpouring of young workers.13 But countries with a more experienced, older labor force undoubtedly had passed the
peak of this reaction to work. Skilled workers in particular settled down. Craft traditions faded and, though work conditions changed, often unpleasantly, movement was no longer seen as a viable response. Changes among the unskilled are harder to chart, particularly because of the continued recruitment of workers new to industry, but here too a trend toward greater stability can be suggested. Even in Germany the exceptional stability found among the semi-skilled — those unskilled workers promoted to work on the machines — suggested a reduction in the reasons for movement, as better conditions could be found within a given company.
In France and Britain reports of massive job-changing came only from those situations in which unskilled workers entered industrial employment for the first time. Lorraine metallurgy, with its mass of Italian immigrants, was a case in point. Some mines, such as Firminy, with a rapidly growing labor force, faced 50 percent turnover each year. Newcomers to the mines of South Wales, leaving their families at home, moved around every few months, after a quarrel with their foreman, in search of higher pay, or out of restlessness.14 But here the bulk of the miners definitely stayed put, and this was the general impression in British industry. A statistical offering: in. the prosperous years of 1888—90, 3.1 percent of the unionized ironfounders were on travel; between 1898 and 1900 the figure was 2.3 percent. The same decline prevailed in slumps: 1885—87, 8.9 percent; 1892—94, 7.6 percent; and 1903—5, 6.7 percent. In contrast to Ruhr miners early in the twentieth century, few British miners switched professions even temporarily. Even unskilled workers, in construction, seemed less migratory than before, though precise figures are lacking. Nor is there more than impressionistic evidence for the crafts; but the traditional 'tramp' after apprenticeship had disappeared in Britain.15 In France it survived only in construction and there it was declining. Unskilled construction workers were also settling down in Paris, after a long tradition of seasonal migration. Important groups of workers, such as Carmaux glass workers, were now largely co-opting from their own progeny, instead of recruiting from distant provinces, until the temporary disruption of new machines. Mechanical linen weaving in Armentières, though only two generations old, was similarly drawing heavily from existing textile families. Thus, in marked contrast to Germany, most workers had had only one profession and 63 percent of all workers over twenty-five had been with their company over ten years. This does not preclude the possibility of a minority of constantly mobile individuals, but it would have been a small one: most Armentières workers employed in their
company less than three years were under eighteen.16
Declining rates of growth in the labor force obviously accounted for part of the decrease in job-changing. It is hard to determine whether workers stopped traveling in response to diminishing job opportunities or for other reasons. The growth of larger firms in the crafts, for example, surely reduced the chance to exchange employers. An older labor force would naturally move less; this would soon be true in Germany and already affected individual firms such as Krupp. But one must conclude that part of the movement away from job-changjng related to an important transformation within the working class. The increased sense of job choice, particularly as it touched unskilled workers, played a role here. So did new decisions on family formation and the basic purpose of work. Employers obviously strove to limit instability; this was the key motive behind paternalism, and it could have some effect — though not to the extent, in Germany, that most paternalistic of countries, of heading off the inherent instability of a new and young labor force. Labor organizations had to oppose job instability and most of the related forms of individual resistance to regular work. They fought absenteeism, even for traditional purposes such as holy Monday, wanting a diligent constituency as a base for constructive bargaining with employers. And they obviously opposed job-changing. For the same impulse that took workers from one employer to the next would take them in and out of unions. German miners, French and German metallurgical workers were notoriously hard to keep organized, often showing the same 100 percent turnover annually that so afflicted their employers.17 More generally a solid labor movement developed only when workers settled down, not only for the obvious reasons of ease of contact and communication but also because the settled worker had to find new channels for discontent and new protections against excessive labor.
Everything, including their own changing habits, conspired to bring workers toward greater regularity of work, though clearly we cannot see a complete transformation even by 1914. Quite apart from the uncertain trends regarding absenteeism, the decline of job-changing would produce a significant diminution of controlled leisure time. This, plus rising intensity of work, helped induce more structured, collective efforts to provide greater freedom from the job. And as more formal leisure was obtained, the reasons for job-changing naturally diminish ed.
The most obvious means of limiting work was to reduce its hours, and this was one of the leading developments of the decades before World War I. By no means novel, collective efforts to reduce the hours
of work had rarely spread beyond the urban crafts and particularly dangerous occupations such as mining. This period saw a more general working-class interest in reduction of hours than had ever before developed, though it had distinctive bases from one group to the next; and relatedly it saw a more rapid rate of reduction in the hours of work than in earlier stages of industrialization. Particularly important was the conversion of large numbers of unskilled workers and some traditional craftsmen to an interest in cutting the work day, often by a considerable margin. Workers who had labored almost without cease when work was available, except for their individual absences, began to clamor for a general reduction. Sometimes they started small. Hamburg dockers in 1896 asked for fixed rest periods, limitations on night hours, and no more than thirty-six hours of work at a stretch. Few workers had actually put in more time, for the shift was normally twelve hours with two rest periods, but the rare excesses were resented and workers wanted more predictability, particularly so that they could let their families know what they were doing. German bakers began by simply asking for three evenings off (on Christmas, Easter, and Whitsuntide); French bakers and barbers had to struggle to win the application of the weekly day off to their trades/Parisian garbage collectors asked for a weekly day off and thirteen hours a day, down from the customary fifteen. In contrast, Berlin street car workers, on shifts of fourteen to seventeen hours, demanded a nine-hour day in 1900. French dockers asked for eight hours repeatedly, along with a guarantee of at least a half day's work any time they were hired; here was a clear desire to regularize haphazard employment. Boatmen on the Paris canals had long petitioned for a twelve-hour day, but when they summoned the courage to strike, in 1908, they asked for ten hours. So there was great variety in the exact limitation sought, but the general impulse was clear.18
Only a few groups of workers were exempt from some effort to limit hours. Organizations of railway workers often petitioned for legal limitation of hours, but outside of Britain there were few direct efforts despite the prevalence of long working days. Pressed by the rise of overtime, Scottish workers in 1891 pushed for a ten-hour limit each day, with time and a quarter for overtime ; they asked for eight hours for certain categories and regular annual holidays. The pressure of existing workloads was too much to bear, and one worker, urging an illegal strike without notice, professed to welcome jail where he would at least 'be sure of our hours.'19 Renewed railway agitation in Britain around 1910 brought demands for the eight-hour day. But Continental
railway workers, and the British, aside from these two periods, were not usually vocal. The same applies to the metallurgical industry, with its typical twelve-hour shifts. Again Britain offers an exception. The new loading machines that increased output raised a concern, backed by the union, about unemployment and work intensity, resulting in deman ds for eight-hour shifts. A few companies yielded from about 1900 onward, and workers then vigorously defended their gains. But this was neither a common pattern nor a common demand. Good pay and security from unemployment, plus in metallurgy the possibility of frequent job-changing and absenteeism, made other goals seem more important. While this was exceptional among articulate workers generally, it serves to raise the problem of the reasons for the effort to reduce hours and the question of its priority.20
For it must not be assumed that workers found a reduction in working time inevitably desirable. It went against their desire to control their own efforts on a more irregular basis, according to individual need. Reduction of hours could encounter the same reaction as the related attempt to limit overtime, though it was less sharp if only because shorter hours enhanced the possibility and the profitability of overtime for some key groups. At an extreme, small-town craftsmen and isolated factory workers attacked the whole idea of legal limitation of hours: 'Why not let us work as we wish?'21 British railway workers, testifying before a government commission, repeatedly professed contentment with long hours, which they claimed did not hurt their health. Several objected to any government interference. The union maintained that they were bribed by the companies by promises of promotion, but there were other valid reasons. More common than outright opposition was indifference, a sense that a reduction in hours was unimportant. The Union of Paper Mill Workers in Britain pressed for a reduction of work on Saturday, because of the prevalence of 64-hour weeks; but the leaders admitted that their members' enthusiasm, particularly in the less industrialized regions such as Southern England, was questionable; a vote for noon closing on Saturdays, in 1912, did not produce a majority. A similar campaign for the 'British week' in France met widespread indifference. Automobile workers, newly pressed by speed-up, embraced it with enthusiasm, but other machine workers were apathetic and few other categories showed real concern. German tailors showed more interest in longer noon breaks, because of their travel time to get home for lunch in the larger cities, but programs for more general reduction in hours gained little support. Even the great CGT campaign for agitation toward the
eight-hour day, which stirred real passion among some French workers, was greeted by widespread indifference, as noted by sympathetic observers and by the participation of only a small minority of the labor force in the 1906 general strike.22
Strikes for a reduction of hours were not unusually difficult to win, so no obvious tactical problem can explain the cases of indifference. It was true that hours strikes lasted longer than wage efforts, because they involved a more fundamental change in job conditions; and they were normally larger than the average strike, more likely to involve a number of companies rather than a single firm. It can be suggested, then, that a relatively sophisticated sense of organization normally accompanied direct efforts to reduce hours of work. Some workers, quite eager to cut their work time, may not have known exactly how to go about it. There may also have been a tendency for employers' resistance to stiffen with time; failure rates in French hours strikes rose perceptibly after about 1910. Others left the matter to the politicians. Workers in a British engineering firm discussed their preference for two breaks during the working day, but decided it was not worth the risk of a strike and should be obtained by law (an improbable prospect).23 Certainly the passage of hours legislation in most countries around 1900 (or earlier, as in England) reduced the need for explicit agitation outside the political arena for many factory workers — assuming that a ten-hour workday was acceptable. Some workers, in industries with fluctuating employment, were so pleased when they had work that the notion of reducing hours made little sense. Workers who were regularly employed in such cases might object to cutting hours because their whole sense of comparative advantage depended on working as much as possible; an hours reduction involved only a loss of pay. Those with experience of unemployment were more likely to be conscious of the desirability of cutting hours, but even here when full employment prevailed — as in summer time, for con struction workers - it was easy to forget about periods of joblessness and the related need to reduce the working day.24 More common still was the dilemma between hours and pay. Many workers wanted to cut hours, but not at risk to their wages. British metallurgical workers continued to accept twelve hours, not with eagerness but because most would campaign for the desired eight-hour shift only if their pay remained the same. In one exception, workers in the Cleveland area sacrificed their Christmas bonus to win eight hours in 1897. Railroad workers reportedly grew hostile to major reductions in hours about 1895, because they feared loss of pay and overtime opportunities. Masons in Edinburgh won an unheard-of
eight-hour day in 1897, but dropped it when they realized their pay had fallen. German construction workers told their union leader that they could endure long hours for a while and that pay was the important issue. Time after time labor organizations urged a focus on hours instead of pay, noting that a shorter working day would effect more basic and permanent changes in the worker's life, only to find their charges insisting on the reverse priority.25
So an active interest in reducing hours, though extensive and spreading, was not automatic. Changes in the nature of work might only gradually produce the realization that the workday should be formally shortened, as against a traditional willingness to spend long hours on the job and individual remedies such as absenteeism. Where campaigns for shorter hours did develop they produced a variety of justifications, not all of which flowed from a new concept of work. Craftsmen such as carpenters and printers were active in hours campaigns for two primary reasons. First, they used this method to reduce the chances of unemployment. Printers were particularly vigorous here, in response to the new technology. British shoe workers also argued for a forty-eight hour week to protect themselves against unemployment, proving more reluctant than their union to accept a 1909 compromise of 52 1/2 hours. French printers mentioned benefits of greater education and more family life in seeking a nine-hour day, but the stress was clearly on reduction of unemployment; 'it must especially procure work for the greatest number.'26 Only in Germany, where craftsmen were particularly sensitive to the threat of a new rhythm of work, were other arguments frequently mentioned. Masons, campaigning for an eight-hour day in 1909, cited their high rates of illness and accident. On the other hand, an unexpressed motive in many craft strikes for a reduction of hours was the desire for greater overtime. Leaders of the French printers' union had to admit that most of their constituents continued to work ten hours even after nine had been won, taking the extra pay instead of the greater leisure. This phenomenon was even more common in French construction.27
Shorter hours could be ardently desired in the crafts, though small-town artisans, even in construction, were slow to move against their long work days. A socialist bookbinder in England was described by a colleague as accepting the idea of an eight hour day 'much as a religious principle appeals to a devout soul.'28 Strikes for shorter hours were frequent and more than usually successful. Once won, the new workday could result in a re-evaluation of the role of work in life. But the motivation did not directly stem from work dissatisfaction, for
craftsmen had found other ways to keep this under acceptable control.
The situation was much different for factory workers and many unskilled laborers. The desire to limit unemployment loomed large. British patternmakers in 1894 stated: 'The chief object of curtailing the hours of labour is to distribute the work amongst the men.'29 The quest for overtime was not so clearly involved. French mine unions complained about their members' addiction to overtime even as they sought shorter regular workdays, but this anomaly was less common in the factories. Workers in textiles, engineering, metals and often in mining increasingly saw reduced hours as a vital response to the rising pace of work and as essential to the whole quality of life. French miners in 1900 found that nine hours simply wasted their strength, adding nothing to production.30 Crimmitschau textile workers, seeking ten hours (down from ten and three-quarters), noted: 'With the monotony and the constantly rising intensity of work, an increased noon pause becomes a necessity for the workers.'31 German shipbuilders, asking for nine hours a decade later, similarly cited work intensity, which brought increasing accidents and illness; this entered into a bitter strike without union authorization. German foundry workers, attacking a ten-hour day, claimed overstrain and exhaustion by the age of fifty.32 The theme of strain, as has already been suggested, was most common in Germany. British workers, even more eagerly seeking a reduction in hours — often explicitly in preference to a pay raise — were less close to the margins of exhaustion. But they too attempted to counter the rising pace of work. York miners sought an eight-hour day because of the danger of their jobs but also because they wanted time for more recreation and leisure.Bolton cotton workers, working up to 58 hours per week, wanted a reduction because of increasing machine speed and to have time, through a day-and-a-half weekend, for outdoor recreation, at the beach or attending sports events.33 Wool weavers in Blackburn tied their concern directly to the job: 'If we do not intend to make ourselves the slaves of machinery, the sooner we reduce our working hours the better.'34
In Britain, clearly, the hours campaigns reflected a re-evaluation of the proper balance in one's life. Continental references were more commonly wrapped up in the job itself, though the unions certainly spoke of the need for leisure to devote to family life and culture. Continental workers, speaking apart from union proclamation, might refer to family needs, as in asking (in Saint-Quentin textiles) for Saturday afternoon off to allow women to do their shopping in preparation for the Sunday holiday. British workers had gone further, if
only because of their greater industrial experience and the fact that their hours were shorter even at the beginning of the period. Metal workers, pressing for reduced hours in 1913, argued simply on grounds of 'the desire on the part of the worker for a fuller and more complete life.'35
No matter what the line of argument, a reduction of hours could produce a major change in the worker's life. There was the question of the form reduction would take. Many German workers were often inclined to argue for longer breaks, as in the Crimmitschau strike. British workers more typically sought the shortest possible day; they wanted to be done and go on to other things. This is not to say that breaks were of no concern, but they did have a lower priority; one group of workers specifically rejected a longer lunch hour if it would reduce their production, for they wanted to leave promptly in the afternoon. Reduction of the work day tended,with growing sophistication, to be associated with a desire for a sharper separation between work and the rest of one's life. Workers such as those in Crimrnitschau, though reacting similarly to changes in the pace of work, moved more slowly in this direction. They were closer to the tradition of alternating the pace of work rather than reducing its duration. With poorer housing and consumption standards, many Germans were also less bent on leaving the factory completely; their predilection for staying and washing on the spot, rather than going home to clean as was the practice in Britain, expressed the same impulse. Occasionally one sees workers caught between the two approaches. Belgian miners voted overwhelmingly for the eight-hour day, only to find that it had the effect of curtailing traditional breaks within the course of work; a somewhat more complicated version of the same problem developed in South Wales. In both cases workers had not really chosen between more regular work and a reduced duration, and they struck out vigorously, if abortively, against the need to choose.36
But the neccessity for choice was almost inevitable. Workers might seek reduced hours to curtail the intensity of work, but they almost always failed. Employers compensated by raising the pace during the hours that remained; their ability to do so was one reason that granted reductions as readily as they did. And workers, often somewhat divided on the importance of limiting hours further in the first place, had an obvious need to respond: they must keep their earnings up. Hours legislation produced a spate of strikes, as in French textiles during the years 1900—1904, to maintain pay levels by raising the rates. Craft strikes similarly sought pay raises to cover any hours cuts. But
factory workers directly requesting shorter hours — when won to the goal at all - and more impressed with their necessity than many craftsmen, could not always take this line. Increasingly they offered to hold the pay rate steady in return for the reduced day. French ceramics workers in 1913 asked for raises only for workers on time pay; piece workers could step up the pace to cover the shorter hours. Hamburg shipbuilders raised their productivity almost enough to compensate for a 9 percent decrease in hours within the first year. Berlin machine workers similarly worked harder in order to keep their pay up, satisfied with shorter hours even when they lost their breaks, because they had more time for recreation. The British engineers carefully promised to maintain production in their efforts at eight hours, even offering at one point to go back to the older schedule if the experiment failed. Workers in the companies affected welcomed the change, working much more steadily when on the job (and reducing their rates of absenteeism). Textile workers in Ghent and carriage makers in Brussels were moving in the same direction by 1910, pledging to keep up production at the established level. Here then, perhaps somewhat inadvertently at first, was a real shift: unprecedentedly hard work was accepted if it left time for play.37
A similar impulse was visible, though much less common, in the effort to obtain regular annual vacations. Information on vacations is frankly spotty, but it is obvious that the pre-war decades saw the beginnings of formal policy in several industries. In mining, agreements often formalized traditional days off and added a few new ones; a 1905 agreement in South Wales allowed twelve holidays, including all Bank holidays and May Day. British iron workers were asking for a week off in summer in several companies by 1907, while railway workers in some concerns had between three and six days a year.38 The British cotton workers' union won a four-day summer vacation in 1896, 'for the double purpose of thoroughly enjoying ourselves and recuperating our energies' — an interesting proletarian modification of the middle-class approach to leisure, which had initially stressed its importance in improving work. On the Continent vacations were less common, but many workers in state service had holidays, and in engineering and related trades the effort to win formal vacations gained considerable headway.39 Parisian electrical workers - benefiting from the links between their industry and the municipality — asked for two days' paid holiday per month, inl906, plus a ten-day paid vacation each year. Vacations were granted in a number of German metal and machine companies, sometimes through collective bargaining but more often as
part of a paternalistic program. Krupp, for example, set up a vacation fund in 1912, granting four days after ten years of service, six after fifteen.40 By 1912, 389 companies, mainly in engineering, offered a week or — more rarely — two weeks off; these companies employed 233,029 workers, but only a minority of these actually qualified for vacations. Here, even if in an embryonic stage, was another trend toward a regularized separation between work and leisure.
The incidence of direct efforts to obtain a reduction of working time is not entirely predictable from the work setting as already discussed. Craftsmen, as usual, led the way. In Britain construction workers won over a third of the hours cuts recorded through collective bargaining between 1899 and 1913; during those years over 300,000 construction workers gained an average reduction of an hour and a half per week — obviously a sizeable fraction of the total number employed in the industry. Craftsmen played a disproportionate role in the CGT's eight-hours strike of 1906; along with printers and metal and carriage workers — themselves mainly in a craft environment, construction workers led the way among the 202,507 workers who struck. And printers and a few groups in the building trades were the only French workers to win nine-hour days in the period. A similar situation prevailed in Germany, where 15 percent of all collective bargaining agreements were for nine-hour days — almost all of them in the big-city crafts. German printers were winning annual vacations through bargaining in over 100 companies per year, by 1906, while skilled brewers, seeking to regularize their work and compensate for its decline in seasonality, began seeking vacations before 1902, suggesting a probable craft lead in this category as well.41
Among other workers, miners showed the most consistent concern for hours reductions, particularly outside of Britain. This was their direct response to the growing difficulty of work. Belgian miners, for example, frequently gave highest priority in a strike to a reduction in work time, deliberately setting aside other demands. French miners sought a reduction in hours more often than most other groups. The goal was typically an eight- or a nine-hour day. In this industry, of course, legislative efforts proved far more important than direct action; 559,629 British miners won a reduction of hours through the 1909 law alone — more than direct bargaining could produce for the entire labor force in a whole decade.42
The achievements of unskilled workers are harder to document. French barbers and bakers had a difficult time even winning a day off per week. Dockers and merchant seamen made some gains, but well
below their sporadic demands for a work -day similar to that of other workers. In Germany, city street cleaners and other municipal laborers had generally pushed their day from twelve hours to ten by 1900 and began moving toward nine hours. Between 1907 and 1914 over 20,000 of these workers won hours cuts averaging almost three hours a week. So great strides could be made, particularly for workers in special contact with the government. But most laborers, by 1914, remained on a day of twelve hours or more, called to work irregularly.43
Factory workers present a similarly ambiguous picture. They did benefit from legislation in those industries where women and children were employed; all countries imposed new limitations in this area before the war, even Britain knocking an hour off on Saturday in addition to its already favorable regulations. These gains help account for the relatively low levels of strike demands and actual collective bargaining gains in most factory categories. It was not easy to formulate hours demands in the factories, where workers lacked the traditional cohesion of miners or artisans or the obvious spur of work shifts consuming over half the day, as among many laborers. It was certainly difficult to win a reduction of hours. Even with unusual sophistication in trade unionism and relatively tolerant employers, British factory workers made little headway outside of legislation. Overall, between 1899 and 1913, roughly 729,000 workers won a reduction of hours through collective bargaining. At least half of these were craftsmen, as we have seen. Of the identifiable factory categories, engineering and shipbuilding workers comprised less than a tenth of the total. The hours gains were substantial, averaging over two per week, but the number of factory beneficiaries was surprisingly small. In Germany, the overall picture was brighter, but this primarily reflected the fact that craftsmen were awakening to the desirability of a snorter work-day, of the kind most of their English counterparts had already won. Between 1905 and 1907, for example, almost 400,000 workers won hours reductions through collective bargaining, averaging am impressive four hours per week. Over a seventh of these were in transportation, and here the average gain was almost six hours. Almost all the other beneficiaries were in the smaller or medium-sized shops in printing, metals, wood products, or construction. In the factories workers remained more traditionally tied to their work or sought individual alleviations through job-changing, and employers made strikes far more difficult.44
Everywhere there were signs of growing interest in hours reductions in the years immediately before the war. -The average annual numbers of workers winning a reduction through collective bargaining doubled
in Britain. Rising concern among engineering and automobile workers has already been discussed.
Nevertheless, one is left with an ambiguous picture. The most reasoned demands for a shorter work-day came from the factories. The issue roused widespread concern among most categories of workers. And, through bargaining or legislation, many workers did win reductions. The picture of a working class with more time off the job is not inaccurate. Yet,impressionistically, a gap remains between the anguish expressed over the pace of work and the achievement of gains or even collective efforts to achieve such gains. This is confirmed, as we will see, by the pattern of strike demands and particularly their movement over time. Too many workers did not find a reduction of hours a top priority issue; there was real division in the perception of this issue. Too many relied on individual remedies still. Outside of the mines, there was no correlation between frequency of efforts to obtain an hours cut and the extent of changes in the nature of work. Craftsmen were disproportionately involved because of their superior organization and their constructive response to unemployment more than anything else. More rapid changes in work may have been driving factory labor t o a greater and more widely-shared effort, but it remained unclear how successful this would be, against the opposition of employers to a work-day significantly under ten hours. In the meantime, workers had to make their judgements about work in a situation where concern about change was not matched by a limitation of the time spent on the job.
Even greater ambiguity characterized the issue of ending work with advancing age. Workers rarely raised the question of retirement in this period, and here craftsmen were no more advanced than their colleagues. In Britain many unions provided small pensions but few workers retired, some through disability. On the Continent, workers in industries traditionally linked to the state had traditions or programs that could be translated into a plan for retirement with pension. In France, railroad workers, miners, merchant seamen and tobacco and match workers alone developed coherent retirement proposals before World War I. Miners could refer to a decree from Henry IV promising pensions; their union began agitating for an effective system in 1853, and a general pension law was passed in 1894. Merchant seamen pointed to Colbert's pension scheme for them, and by the 1890s they were negotiating directly with the government for improvements. Railway unions and public utilities workers dealt with private concerns for the most part, but they could refer to conditions on the state line or
to public responsibility where monopolies had been granted; the railway workers came directly under legislation. Match workers offer a similarly interesting case, for they had no special claim to, or apparent concern for, pensions until their companies were nationalized in 1890. Immediately they came under a state pension system, and their union busily negotiated for improvements and handled individual complaints where pensions did not correspond to expectations. In all these industries workers pressed for a lowering of the retirement age (to 45 in mining, to 55 in match manufacture) and for higher benefits, even before 1900.45 Yet in all other industries workers remained silent. Even discussions of state pension proposals remained desultory until 1910. The glass workers' union in 1903, for example, discussed with real feeling the dilemma of older workers, who were often used up by their mid-forties and were demoted or even fired. The obvious conclusion was that an early retirement age was essential and that current state proposals, which involved retirement at 65, were irrelevant. But having said this, the delegates went on to admit that they had nothing to propose themselves and would welcome someone else's initiative. Fernand Pelloutier put the case in more ideological terms: 'It is not up to the workers to indicate the means of assuring their old age; the obligation is incumbent upon capitalist society.'46 This position long received little challenge from the constituency of the labor movement. Even where companies had private pension schemes, as in metallurgy, workers did not raise demands toward improving their provisions. At most they asked for publicity on the use of worker contributions, or objected to the contributions as reducing the wage — sensible enough demands, but not addressed to the relationship between work and age.
Younger workers clearly did not think much about aging, and their job shifts limited their concern for any one company's program (except to object to dues whose administration they did not control). Pension plans were costly and remote, and many di d not really expect to live to retirement; at the peak of their strength and skill, it was important to make the most of the moment. Hence once a voluntary pension plan was established in France, in 1910, young workers rarely signed up. The small number of unions with an ongoing concern for pensions often noted that their members were 'too careless' to seek what they needed for their old age.47
Yet older workers became extremely anxious. Inquiries in Germany reported worry about provision for old age as the leading problem among the workers interviewed — 'a carefree old age' as one worker put
it — and with good reason. Yet there was little sense of what to do. Workers at Daimler discussed the desirability of some improvements in state accident and disability schemes — oddly, they did not directly mention the pension law — but spoke mainly of leaving their old age up to fate or God. To a questionnaire asking where they planned to live in their old age, few workers could respond because they had not thought about the matter and, lacking savings, could not afford to — the problem was awesome.48 Most older workers in fact, once unable to continue, had to depend on their families for support, yet this was often a real burden and may often not have been feasible at all ; the alternative was the charity hospitals or other meager aid. Particularly in this period, when the birth rate was falling as longevity increased, workers must have begun to wonder if they had enough children to provide for them. And in fact most workers labored until they dropped, except in the few industries with more than nominal pension programs; state plans as in Germany after 1900, Britain and France had not yet lasted long enough to have much effect on the older group and provided inadequate benefits anyway — 'too little to live on, too much to die on' was the phrase that gained currency in France. And there was no overall change in the age at which those workers who had to or could retire did so; this was not to come until the Depression forced older elements off the job.49
Without a culture that prepared them for aging, usually without specific pension plans and always lacking more than a modest stipend, old workers had to stay on if they could. The absence of any general retirement notion emerges clearly from a juxtaposition of the 1901 and 1906 French censuses. The procedure is inherently inexact, but it produces interesting results. We first add less than half of the 55—64 year old cohort from the 1901 data (reduced to allow for the group still under 60) to the 65 plus, among active manufacturing workers; deduct from this 10 percent which is meant to exaggerate the number of workers likely to die in the five year interval; and then apply this to the over-65s still working in 1906. Reduction of the first figure by onLy 60 percent is perhaps too generous, for still more of the group may have been under 60. The ten percent mortality figure is derived from the fact that adult males, in 1900, aged 55—64 had an annual death rate of .98 percent, those 65—70 1.33 percent and so on; this figure has arbtrarily been doubled to allow for the probability of higher worker levels. Some might want still more, for the impression lingers that certain kinds of work killed or maimed everybody by 45; the figures deny this, for overall some 3 percent of all male and female
maufacturing workers were over 65, as did the rush for pensions by workers in their fifties when these finally became available. But that the measurement is extremely rough cannot be denied. By 1906 only 20 percent of all probably surviving French transportation workers (mainly on the railroads) who were 60 or over in 1901, continued in the work force. Here a real pension plan, and related pressure to retire, existed; even earlier, in the later 1890s, 10 percent of all transportation workers were retired in France. This does not mean they did not work, for many went on in part-time employment as auxiliaries or, lost in the anonymous census figures, entered some other job. But we can assume that a good portion did retire, often remaining in a small town, where they might previously have worked as signalmen, or migrating to the countryside. But where pensions were lacking or were too new to have effect — the study in the late 1890s recorded only 116,000 workers and employees retired under formal pension schemes in private industry other than transport and mining, and these predominantly in metallurgy — the behavior pattern was quite different. Applying the same formula to mining, 54 percent of the older labor force remained in 1906. In manufacturing overall, 65 percent of men and 69 percent of all women persisted (which means that those women who could not marry out of industry had to remain even longer than men). Domestic manufacturing workers persisted at a 74 percent rate. Within shops and factories the trades that had so many advantages in other respects lagged in retirement: printing with 59 percent showed some possible lead, although also, conceivably, the price of lead poisoning and skill displacement. Metals stood at 65 percent, construction at 63 percent, textiles at 67 percent, wood at 68 percent. Only metallurgy, like mining, showed some possible impact of the combination of unusually hard labor and pension schemes, for here only 54 percent of all workers persisted.
All of this tends to confirm the idea that regular retirement was impossible and conceivably, by some, unwanted. One worked until death or disability, and the disparity between the above figures and one hundred percent undoubtedly reflects above all those who simply could not go on. Individuals may have voluntarily retired, on the basis of savings, a small contribution to a pension plan, and support by children; the bulk of workers could not and did not. But they suffered in seeking to remain in the labor force. A disproportionate number were unemployed. Illness and displacement had long been more common among this group, but the problems increased. By .1906 the unemployment rates of males over 60 stood a full 100 percent above the average.
Both causing and resulting from this pressure, still more people entered the ranks of the unskilled in their later years. Again, census figures catch this movement only in a gross sense. But in 1911 only 1 percent of all French printers were over 65, only 2 percent of all male metal workers. Juxtaposed with the persistent figures cited above this meant that many workers abandoned such trades before they were 55. Textiles were a bit more generous, to men and women alike, for here the percentage stood above the overall industrial average, at 3.7 percent. But the concentration of old people was disproportionately among the unskilled, with 59 percent of all general laborers (and therefore 29 percent of all employed males in manufacturing and transport) recording ages over 65. Old people had to work, for the potentially cheerful fact that many workers survived into late age was not recognized any more by contemporaries than it has been by those historians who delight in seeing the old killed off by capitalism in their prime. Capitalism was not so murderous, but it was not kind. With decent health an old man might retain pride in his ability to carry on, but even if he stayed in his customary trade his earnings and employment period would sink. Retirement, by no means the best solution to this dilemma, would nonetheless be caused by it, if only because the old cluttered the employment opportunities of the young; but even this partial resolution was still for the future.50
Yet workers wanted to retire. Their whole culture and experience taught them that work deteriorated rapidly after a certain age, and the rising pace characteristic of the turn of the century only enhanced this notion. Work should stop with old age, and retirement should provide peace and rest; the image of 'a little rest' crops up constantly in trade union discussions of retirement. Old age was a time of exhaustion, and it began at 45 or 50. 'Once a man has reached fifty years of age he's reached such a state of exhaustion that he should profit from the work he's produced during his entire life.' 'An immutable principle is that at fifty years a man, and especially a worker, is exhausted; it's at this moment that society should assist him.'51 French railway workers who had to work beyond the sixty-year retirement age because of inadequate pension support were described as 'broken by age and fatigue.'52 Here was a stark association of work and misery.
Yet nothing like a general campaign for adequate pensions developed, which would translate this sense of the necessity to end work definitively at a certain age into reality. Workers involved in a retirement plan appreciated it. A gas worker told a hostile CGT convention, opposed to state pension proposals on ideological grounds,
how he welcomed his company's plan that promised a stipend at 60: 'I'm not sure of reaching this age, but I can say this, that I'm quite content to have the withholding taken because I'm calm about my future.'53 And it was really pressure from below that forced the CGT to adopt a mellower stance on pensions after 1910, for both this confederation and the socialist party came to realize that middle-aged workers would turn away from any organization that did not accept even a weak pension system, some law being better than none. After the 1910 law passed, the textile federation was assailed by members who believed that a more flexible approach would have produced an improved system; within half a year over three million people had signed up for the plan and some locals were even asking for higher withholdings.54
Even here, worker interest depended heavily on initiatives from outside the working class, from parliamentary liberals and government bureaucrats. This dependence obviously distinguished those unions which worked for pension improvements, because of their association with the state, from the general run. Workers did not, overall, find pensions a high priority issue. Far more than with hours of work, other concerns — including maintaining wages against new dues, for younger workers — took pride of place. There were too many younger workers in the labor force and their voice was too loud for the fears of older workers to find full expression. Furthermore most workers, even of more mature years, did not expect to live to the age that most pension schemes provided for retirement. A union delegate blasted the notion of retirement at sixty: 'to be able to profit from it one would have to be on the verge of kicking the bucket, and as you know not everyone reaches this age.' As for 65: 'at that age the least infirmities with which they run the risk of being afflicted are paralysis or decay.'55 Workers involved in a pension plan often commented that they did not expect to profit from their pensions; they thought more in terms of providing for their families after death. This was the actual purpose of most of the union plans in Britain. Similarly French merchant seamen viewed pensions as 'the only means permitting them to provide for burial and the needs of their families' once they died.56
Here then was a tragic irony. The association of work with exhaustion and disability, after a rather young age, made any conceivable pension plan unrealistic, though workers in the first flush of enthusiasm, upon hearing that a plan was in prospect, might rush in with proposals to retire at 45. There was no adequate pension plan, in the workers' terms, to be got out of capitalist society at this point;
indeed even a major redistribution of wealth would not have produced the needed amount. Workers were demonstrably wrong in their most pessimistic perceptions. Increasing numbers were likely to live to 65 — in France about 30 percent of the working class, once it reached the age of employment, would live to 65, according to calculations in 1900.57 But the perceptions had great reality for the workers involved. They obviously heightened the dilemma of those workers who did live into old age, for against their hopes they almost always had to continue working.
The confusion surrounding the notion of retirement, with its sour implications for the whole notion of work, cannot be taken as typical of the general work experience. The relevant class culture was age-specific, which is one reason older workers were so often ignored. Yet as an extreme example it does reflect on the larger problems of the working class in this period. A desire to mark off portions of time from work — each day, part of each year, even part of each life — was growing. It was not easy to articulate, because it partially conflicted with a traditional culture of work. Changes in work, correspondingly, were often not great or rapid enough to force a concentration on this kind of goal. And to an incalculable extent, more customary forms of relief from work continued to limit the pressure on many individuals. There were, furthermore, steady gains for many workers, as demands for released time did take shape. Older workers aside, we cannot see the pre-war period as a time of great new tragedy for workers, caught between changing jobs and the impossibility of finding compensatory leisure. What tragedy there was stemmed partly from the tradition of manufacturing work; had its novelty been more marked, workers would have responded more directly. Yet the sense of ambiguity remained. Not only were more problems expressed about work than solved; more were suggested than some workers could even imagine being solved. To resistance from above and divisions within much of the working class must be added another factor: it was not always clear what could be done with time off the job. Workers were moving into new patterns of recreation and family life — again, there should be no question that change was occurring. But, for many, ways to compensate for pressures on the job by pleasures outside, even when some leisure time was available, did not develop apace.
Notes
1. Walter Troeltsch, Das Problem der Arbeitslôsigkeit (Marburg, 1907); Miners' Federation of Great Britain, Special Conferences, 1912 (Manchester, 1912), 13.
2. Commission d'enquête sur la durée du travail dans les mines de houille, Enquête orale: dépositions des témoins (Brussels, 1907), I, 6, 40 and passim.
3. A. L. Bowley and A. R. Burnett-Hurst, Livelihood and Poverty (London, 1915), 83 ff.; F. Hecht, Die Stôrungen in deutschen Wirtschaftsleben (Leipzig, 1903); II, passim; E. W. Evans, The Miners of South Wales (Cardiff, 1961), 169; Commission d'enquête sur la durée du travail dans les mines de houille, Le Marché charbonnier belge (Brussels, 1908), 33, 152, 212; B. McCormick and J. W. Williams, 'The Miners and the Eight-Hour Day, 1863-1910,' The Economic History Review (1959), 238; A. J. Taylor, 'Labour Productivity and Technology: Innovation in the British Coal Industry,' The Economic History Review (1961), 56; Heinrich Miinz, Die Lage der Bergarbeiter im Ruhrrevier (Essen, 1909); D. L. Burns, The Economic History of Steelmaking, 1867-1939 (Cambridge, 1940), 136 ; Frederick Keeling,'Solution of the Casual Labour Problem,' The Economic Journal (1913), 1 — 18; Maurice Vignes, 'Le Bassin de Briey et la politique de ses entreprises sidérurgiques ou minières,' Revue socialiste (1913), 685.
4. Friedrich Syrup, 'Studien ùber den industriellen Arbeitswechsel,' Thùnen-Archiv (1913), 261-303.
5. Ibid.; Troeltsch, Problem ; Hecht, Stôrungen, II; Paul Osthold, Die Geschichte des Zechenverbandes (Berlin, 1934); Walter Abelsdorff, Beitrdge zur Sozialstatistik der deutschen Buchdrucker (Tubingen, 1900): Eugen Fraenkel, 'Die Lage der Arbeiter in den Werkstâtten der bayerischen Staatsbahne,' Archiv fur Sozial-wissenschaft und Socialpolitik (1913), 808 ff.; Otto Jeidels, Die Methoden der Arbeiterentlôhnung in der rheinisch-westfâlischen Eisenindustrie (Berlin, 1907); Marie Bernays, 'Berufswahl und Berufsschicksal des modernen Industriearbeiters,' Archiv fur Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik (1912), 123 ff.; Josef Neumann, Die deutschen Schiffbauindustrie (Leipzig, 1910); Max Metzner, Die soziale Fùrsorge im Bergbau (Jena, 1911); Richard Ehrenberg, 'Schwàche und Starkung neuzeitlicher Arbeitsgemein-schaften,' Thùnen-Archiv (1911), 401 ff.
6. H. G. Kirchoff, Die staatliche Sozialpolitik im Ruhrbergbau 1871-1914 (Cologne, 1955).
7. Fritz Schumann, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Automobilindustrie (Leipzig, 1911); Jeidels, Methoden, 231 ff.; Gerhard Adelmann, Quellensammlung zur Geschichte der sozialen Betriebsverfassung: Ruhrindustrie unter besonderer Beruck-sichtigung des Industrie und Handelskammerbezirks Essen (Bonn,
1960), I, 275 ff. ; Clemens Heiss, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiter in der Berliner Feinmechanik (Leipzig, 1910), 136 ff.
8. Ehrenberg, 'Schwache,' 514, 517, and passim.
9. Jeidels, Methoden, 236.
10. Charles Booth, Life and Labour of the People of London (London, 1895), V, 112; Abelsdorff, Beitrâge; von Bienkowski et al., Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Elektro-industrie, Buchdruckerei, Feinmechanik, und Maschinenindustrie (Leipzig, 1910), 19; Waldemar Jolko, Untersuchnngen iiber die Entlôhnungsmethoden in der Berliner Metallindustrie (Berlin, 1911); Henry Steele, The Working Classes in France, a social study (London, 1904), 114.
11. Differential patterns for the unskilled are suggested by a recent study of Bochum. Between 1880 and 1901 65% of all traceable day laborers had switched professions, within the unskilled-semiskilled category (as against 4% of the skilled workers within their own category). But 66% of the traceable unskilled factory laborers were at the same job. Obviously factory conditions, or at least factory pay, suited the unskilled, plus the fact that they were older than average, which limited opportunities for change: David Crew, 'Definitions of Modernity: Social Mobility in a German Town, 1880-1901/ Journal of Social History (1973), 51-74.
12. Josef Joos, Der Berufsgedanken und die industrielle Lohnarbeiterschaft (Mônchen-Gladbach, 1922); Bernays, 'Berufswahl;' Osthold, Geschichte; Neuman, Schiffbauindustrie; Heinrich Herkner, Problème der Arbeiterpsychologie (Leipzig, 1912).
13. Heinrich Reichelt, Die Arbeitsverhàltnisse in einem Berliner Grossbetrieb der Mas chinenindustrie (Berlin, 1906).
14. H. Stanley Jevons, The British Coal Trade (London, 1915); Archives de la Compagnie des Mines de Firminy, Rapports généraux du directeur 1911 — 1914.
15. William H. Beveridge, Unemployment, a Problem of Industry (London, 1931), 244; Jevons, Coal, 123; Norman Dearie, Problems of Unemployment in the London Building Trades (London, 1908), 163; E. H. Phelps Brown, Growth of British Industrial Relations (London, 1959), 5 ff.; Eric Hobsbawm, 'The Tramping Artisan,' in Labouring Men (New York, 1964), 134—64.
16. Joan Scott,' The Glassworkers of Carmaux,' in S. Thernstrom and R. Sennett, Nineteenth-Century Cities (New Haven, 1969), 3—44; William M. Reddy, 'Family and Factory; French Linen Weavers in the Belle Epoque,' Journal of Social History (1974), passim.
17. Deutscher Metallarbeiter-Verband, Jahr- und Handbuch, 1912.
18. E. Francke, 'Die Arbeitsverhàltnisse im Hafen zu Hamburg, Jahrbuch fur Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung, und Volkswirtschaft im deutschen Reich (1898), 944; Zentralverband der Backer, Konditoren u. verwandten Berufsgenossen Deutschlands, Protokoll der ordentl. Generalversammlung, 1899; Archives de la Préfecture
de police de la Seine, B/a 1359; André Sayous, Les Grèves de Marseilles en 1904 (Paris, 1904); Generalkommission der Gewerkschaften Deutschlands, Correspondenzblatt 9 April 1900.
19. James Mavor, The Scottish Railway Strike, 1891 (Edinburgh, 1891), 9, 13.
20. G. C. Haberson, The Development of Labour Relations on the British Railways since 1860 (Ph.D. Thesis, University of London, 1962); Arthur Pugh, Men of Steel (London, 1951), 110; J. K. Carr and W. Taylor, History of the British Steel Industry (Oxford, 1962), 145-6.
21. Henri Lorin, 'L'Industrie rurale en pays basque,' Musée social (1906), 371.
22. W. Alcock, Fifty Years of Railway Trade-Unionism (London, 1922), 246; Clement Bundock, The Story of the National Union of Printing, Bookbindery and Paper Workers (Oxford, 1959), 401; Alphonse Loyau, 'La Semaine anglaise en France,' Vie ouvrière (1912), 379; Archives nationales (France) F7 13595; A. and Z., 'Pour la réduction des heures du travail,' Revue socialiste (1906), passim; Verband der Schneider, Schneiderinnen und Wàsche-arbeiter Deutschlands, Bericht des Vorstandes ùber die Ge-schàftsperioden 1912-1914 (Berlin, 1917).
23. Peter N. Stearns, Revolutionary Syndicalism and French Labor (New Brunswick, 1971), 121—30; Friendly Society of Iron-founders, Monthly Journal, 1906.
24. Bulletin de la Chambre syndicale des ouvriers peintres en bâtiment de la Seine, May 1909.
25. Carr and Taylor, Steel, 145; Labour Gazette, November 1895; Raymond Postgate, The Builders' History (London, n.d.), 350; Fritz Paeplow, Bauarbeit, Bauarbeiter, und Bauarbeiter-organisationen (Berlin, 1930); Jack Owen, Ironmen (Middlesbrough, n.d.), 21; Amalgamated Association of Tramway and Vehicle Workers, Quarterly Reports, 1898.
26. Fédération française des travailleurs du livre, Compte-rendu du neuvième Congrès national (Paris, 1905), 209; see also Alan Fox, A History of the National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives (Oxford, 1958), 319.
27. Zentralverband der Maurer Deutschlands, Der Kampf um die Arbeitsbedingungen (Hamburg, 1909); Archives de la Préfecture de police de la Seine B/a 1377, report on the 1906 strike.
28. Frederick Rogers, Labour, Life and Literature (London, 1913), 184.
29. United Patternmakers' Association, A nnual Report, 1894, 10.
30. 'La Grève des mineurs de la Loire et l'arbitrage,' Musée social (1900), 50.
31. Central-Verband deutschen Textilarbeiter, Crimmitschau unter Belagerungszustand (Berlin, 1903), 8.
32. Hans Thiele, 'Der Werftarbeiter-Streik von Jahre 1910,' Jahrbuch fur Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung, und Volkswirtschaft im Deutschen
Reich (1912), 751 ff.; Heinrich Reichelt, Die Arbeitsverhàltnisse in einem Berliner Grossbetrieb der Maschinenindustrie (Berlin, 1906).
33. J. E. Williams, The Derbyshire Miner (London, 1962), 363 ff.; George Howell, Trade Unionism New and Old (London, 1891), 178; Bolton Operative Cotton Spinners' Association, Annual Report, 1896.
34. Blackburn and District Power Loom Weavers' Association, Annual Report, (1895), 6.
35. Archibald T. Kidd, History of the Tin-Plate Workers and Sheet Metal Workers and Braziers Societies (London, 1949), 183.
36. Revue du travail, April 1910, 489 ff.
37. Fédération nationale de la céramique, Compte rendu du Xe congrès national (Limoges, 1913), 29; Otto Leuche, 'Ùber einigen Bestimmungsgrùnde der Lohnverdienste,' Thùnen-Archiv (1911), 579 ff.; Dora Lande, Die Arbeits- und Lohnverhàltnisse in der Berliner Maschinenindustrie zu Beginn des 20. Jahrhunderts (Leipzig, 1910); William Mather, The Forty-Eight Hours' Week (Manchester, 1894); 'La Conciliation et l'arbitrage en Belgique,' Revue du travail (1910), 364 ff.
38. Ness Edwards, History of the South Wales Miners' Federation (London, 1938), 22; The Ironworkers' Journal, September 1904; Norman McKillop, The Lighted Flame; A History of the Associated Society of Locomotive Engineers and Firemen (London, 1950), 82.
39. Bolton Operative Cotton Spinners' Association, Report, 1896; Deutscher Metallarbeiter-Verband, Arbeiterferien (Stuttgart, 1913).
40. Archives de la Préfecture de police de la Seine, report of June, 1903 ; Adelman, Quellensammlung II, passim.
41. By 1914 876 brewery agreements, covering 1666 companies and 57,920 workers, provided for paid vacations; E. Backert, Geschichte der Brauarbeiterbewegung (Berlin, 1916). Board of Trade, Seventeenth Abstract of Labour Statistics (London, 1915, Cd. 7733); A. and Z., 'Réduction', passim; Adolf Brauns, Die Tarifvertràge und die deutsche Gewerkschaften (Stuttgart, 1 908).
42. Board of Trade, Abstract, passim; Revue du travail, 1908 ff.
43. Alexander Knoll, Geschichte der Strasse und ihren Arbeiter (Leipzig, 1924).
44. Board of Trade, Abstract; Korrespondent fur Deutschlands Buchdrucker und Schriftsgiesser, 1908.
45. Fédération nationale des travailleurs du sous-soL, 35e Congrès national (Paris, 1921), 66; Fédération nationale de l'industrie des mines, minières, et carrières, Congrès national {Saint-Etienne, 1891); Fédération nationale des travailleurs réunis de la Marine de l'Etatt, 2me Congrès (Toulon, 1905), 15, 57; Syndicat national des travailleurs des chemins de fer, Commentaire des principales revendications (Paris, 1896), 14; Fédération nationale de
l'éclairage et des forces motrices, Rapports moral et financier (Versailles, 1924), 13, 14; Fédération nationale des ouvriers et ouvrières des manufactures des tabacs en France, 3me Congrès (Paris, 1894), 48; Fédération nationale des ouvriers et ouvrières des manufactures d'allumettes en France, 3me Congrès national (Marseilles, 1896), 72.
46. Confédération générale du travail, Xe Congrès corporatif (Rennes, 1898), 268; see also Fédération française des travailleurs du verre, Congrès national (Lyons, 1903), 57.
47. Fédération nationale des syndicats maritimes, Dixième congrès (Marseilles, 1902), 53.
48. Fritz Schuman, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Automobilindustrie (Leipzig, 1911), passim; Heinrich Herkner, Problème der Arbeiterpsychologie (Leipzig, 1912); Elise Herrmann, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Wollhutsindustrie (Munich, 1912).
49. Michael Anderson, 'Family, Household and the Industrial Revolution,' in Peter Laslett, éd., Household and Family in Past Time (Cambridge; 1972).
50. In addition to the census material, see Ministère du commerce, Office du travail, Les Caisse patronals de retraites (Paris, 1898).
51. Fédération nationale des syndicats d'ouvriers coiffeurs, 12e Congrès national (Paris, 1924), 7 3. Confédération générale du travail, Xlle Congrès national (Lyons, 1901), 143.
52. Syndicat national des travailleurs des chemins de fer, Commentaires, 9.
53. Confédération général du travail, XVHe Congrès national corporatif (Toulouse, 1911), 265.
54. Parti socialist français (SFIO), 7e Congrès national (Paris, 1910), 170 ff., 314; Compte-rendu du XHme Congrès national des ouvriers de l'industrie textile (Lille, 1912), 73 ff.
55. Confédération générale du travail, TXe Congrès national corporatif (Toulouse, 1897), 175; Fédération nationale des ouvriers et ouvrières des manufactures des tabacs, 2me Congrès (Paris, 1892), 99.
56. Fédération nationale des syndicats maritimes, Dixième congrès (Marseilles, 1902), 47.
57. Parti socialiste, Congrès, passim.
CHAPTER 8 OFF THE JOB: FAMILY AND CONSUMPTION PATTERNS
For both artisans and factory workers, the family normally served as an important economic unit at the turn of the century. This was not new, though many workers had had to re-establish the family's productive role after the first shock of migration to the city, a process still visible in France and Germany.1 Wives rarely worked, but served to keep their husbands fit and productive, to the extent of denying themselves food and other necessities. 'If there's anything extra to buy, such as a pair of boots for me or the children, me and the children goes without dinner — or mebbe only 'as a cup o' tea and a bit o' bread, but Jim oilers takes 'is dinner to work, and I never tell 'im.'2 We have seen the family at work in the placement of children, in both factory industry and the crafts, and there is no need to rehearse this further. Even daughters employed for a few years before marriage contributed to the family economy. In England they paid board and room to their parents, keeping some earnings back for spending money; on the Continent they turned their wages over directly. Clearly, despite both contemporary and subsequent comment on collapse of the working-class family, some rather traditional economic functions were developed within a short time after the advent of industrialization.
What concerns us here is not the family as an economic unit but a unit of affection and recreation. Conclusive evidence is difficult to obtain in this area. The leading study of the nineteenth-century working-class family plays down its affectionate functions in favor of a rather manipulative economic approach. It is possible to argue, in contrast, that the family took on new emotional importance as workers faced an industrial environment.3 The decline of arranged courtships and the tendency for marriage age to drop and marriage: rates to rise would make sense in this context. Or, its economic functions aside, was the family rather a traditional reflex, more widespread than in pre-industrial society as the lower classes had spending money earlier in life and were freed from the necessity of waiting for inheritance of property, but not really different in emotional content? No definitive answer is possible yet, even for mid-nineteenth century England where the most serious study has been undertaken.
But what of the later industrial period? Again, solid information is
hard to come by, but it seems logical to assume that the importance of the family was increasing as workers had more free time. Indeed the need for time to spend with the family was consistently used in justifying a reduction of hours, as workers grew weary of returning home too late to see their children or too grumpy to deal with them as they wished. To be sure, increased commuting time played a role in this situation; dockers who cited their long journeys to the job site were not necessarily asking for more time with their families, but simply a restoration of what they had lost. The same applies to miners' objections to multiple shifts, backed vigorously by wives who resented preparing meals for husbands and sons at different times of the day; tradition, not new emotional content, governed the miner's family even in its relationship to protest.4 But for other workers commuting itself might indicate a new family sense, as the movement to the suburbs resulted from a desire to raise the children in better surroundings. In the most traditional crafts, one of the key motives for seeking new independence from the artisan master was to be able to form a family earlier. Again the motive may have been more the realization that the traditional opportunity to wait for the master's retirement and take over his business, and often his daughter, had become more remote, but the result could be a new family focus. The whole process of settling down, which is so obvious in comparing British workers to German, meant increasing family ties, less disrupted by seasonal and other migrations. From this it is but a step to suggest that workers learned to use their family interests to make up for monotonous work and developed their compensatory, off-the-job culture in a familial framework. If this transition was only beginning in the pre-war period, it would ultimately reverse traditional priorities, as the family, not the job, became the center of life. By the mid-twentieth century, instead of the family absorbing problems encountered at work, the performance on the job would depend on satisfaction at home.5
It is not possible to claim, without much more detailed study, a definite response to this hypothesis for the pre-war period. It accurately suggests certain probabilities that would in turn help explain why workers absorbed some damaging deterioration on the job itself. But while we can sketch aspects of the transition, we must also suggest that it was fraught with great difficulty and proceeded at different rates, if not indeed in rather different directions, among key groups of workers.
The hypothesis best fits the urban craftsmen, perhaps because they were not in fact subjected to the most extreme tensions on the job. The family-focused public culture that has recently been described for
London was not a general proletarian culture but rather one open mainly to artisans and shared with many lower middle-class elements.6 In fact this association was becoming increasingly important, as craftsmen took on many of the bourgeois family values to give new focus to their lives. Marriage age was late by proletarian standards. This of course reflected artisanal tradition, in which skill had to be established before the family was formed, but it was adaptable to new purposes in this period. British artisans married at an average o f 25.3 years of age, a full three years above miners and most factory workers. In Germany less than 3 percent of all printers were married before they were 24; half were married by 29, and 7/8 by age 39: the average age was about 27. A large number of journeymen in the more traditional crafts did not marry at all, reflecting the customs of pre-industrial society; in one study only 21 percent of the bakers were married. But marriage rates were rising in this group as the habit of boarding with the master declined.7 Once married, the artisan was likely to keep his wife at home. In Germany printers who worked on machines achieved this goal more often than hand compositors, who sometimes needed the extra money, but work outside the home was uncommon for wives in any craft group. In Hamburg, for example, few wives of carpenters were employed, though they often sub-let rooms to boarders. Even the wedding arrangements reflected a desire for respectability defined in rather traditional terms. A British worker described the substantial dowry that a Parisian carpenter might pay to his daughter's husband, and the church marriage that the women insisted upon.8
Within this traditional setting, two or three distinctive features were being accentuated. The artisan family had few children. This followed in part from late marriage, but was being carried much further around the turn of the century. Construction workers were a partial exception, as some had quite large families — more like other laborers who used great physical strength on the job than the artisanal group. German printers in 1900 averaged 2.03 children per marriage, or 2.49 if all childless marriages were excluded. The more urban the setting, the smaller the family; hence Berlin printers averaged only 1.74. In France in 1911 bakers averaged 1.8, locksmiths 1.71 printers 1.5, tailors 1.6, cabinet-makers 1.9. Carpenters and skilled metal workers averaged 2.1, factory workers 2.2—2.3, and miners 2.5, in contrast. In Britain, at about the same time, workers in food processing, precious metals, and printing had unusually small families, with about 2.8 children on the average; builders had 3.1, as did metal workers. Here we can get a more distinct picture of the change that had occurred during the period, for
in Charles Booth's study of London printers and other craftsmen were not notably below the general proletarian average, with about 4.5 children per family. Unusually well educated, artisans were more quickly aware of new birth control methods than their fellows in other industries. And they cherished their children. Evidence on emotional relationships has yet to be developed, save through citation of the family-oriented popular culture which artisans were coming to value. But there is reason to believe that rapid limitation of birth follows from and enhances an increased emotional attachment to each child, and this would fit the artisanal case. Certainly the interest in proper and respectable placement of the child was intense. Daughters were put into clerical jobs wherever possible, while sons were sent into the father's trade or pushed toward higher status still.9
Finally the artisans worked toward a family-dominated life style off the job. They headed the movement toward the suburbs within the working class. Sometimes their interest was due less to more respectable housing than simply to low rents, for with the decline of board and room arrangements there was something of a housing crisis; this was the case, for example, around Vienna.10 But generally thoughts of the family were prominent. Brussels construction workers who commuted from outlying villages cited the 'better air' as well as lower rents. One noted that commuting tired him out and raised his costs to big-city levels, but still praised the setting as one in which wives could garden and raise animals and children could play in the streets.11 Here the suburban impulse smacks obviously of nostalgia for the countryside, just as it often did for the middle class. But artisans picked up newer consumption habits for the family as well. In Britain they might buy second-hand pianos for their wives and daughters, and there was great interest in attractive furnishings generally.12
In all probability, then, the combination of custom and innovation manifested by artisanal families did provide an increasingly important compensation for work. Even without an assessment of the affectionate relationships provided by the family, it is clear that establishing the family gave a goal to work for while dressing the family for a joint outing on Sunday or furnishing the apartment to allow some entertaining helped organize leisure time.
Unquestionably the family provided a sense of purpose to many factory workers and laborers as well. Workers a generation or two removed from the countryside could justly be proud of their ability to establish and provide for a family at all.13 Many Hamburg dockers, for example, endured their irregular, demanding work because of the
relative well-being they earned for their families. We can indeed see hints of an increasing interest in family life among sailors and dockers in many ports, abandoning a tradition of late marriage, or no marriage at all. In 1900 only 36 percent of all sailors in Bremen were married But with greater regulation of hours of work and with some improvement in earnings, opportunities for forming a family steadily
rose.
In the factories family concerns ran high, but were less clearly novel. The workers married early — unlike many laborers, who could not afford to. Ruhr miners married before they were twenty-five, with their wives often under twenty. Ninety-four per cent of the Saar miners were married by age 24 in 1900. Similarly, around 1890 women in British miners' families married at the average age of 22.7, compared to 23.7 for the daughters of both artisans and laborers. This pattern raised its own problems, for neither partner was necessarily ready for marriage emotionally or economically. Many Ruhr miners had to borrow to set up their household and their wives, lacking experience, proved bad housekeepers. In other words, the need for a family environment could be counterproductive; certainly early marriage limited the chances for adaptation to a new environment later on. Working-class culture stressed the joys of courtship, but saw marriage in harsher light. Women demanded marriage, which gave them purpose, even though they were severely restricted by it and often found it joyless.15 Furthermore, most factory workers saw the family as a producer of children, and in some quantity. Particularly in Germany older traditions, in which children were an economic asset and their mortality rate was high, had not been shaken off. In over 50 percent of the marriages of workers in the Daimler factory (close, it will be recalled, to the rural background) the wife was pregnant before marriage or had already given birth. Workers wanted to make sure they were not 'buying a pig in a poke' ('kein Katze im Sack').16 Even British laborers were often oblivious to the ultimate cost of children, for they came from big families and were used to living on little.17 But increasingly realization arrived, only too late. A factory laborer in Germany described his wife's anger, after six children had come, at perennially inadequate resources. Often she beat the children; often she kept him awake at night bemoaning the fact that none of the children died.18
Problems of this sort, by no means new, did not preclude a sense of worried pride in the family. German miners and metal workers listed a desire to spend more time with their families as their second use of any increased leisure (after improved education) in Levenstein's poll; only
in textiles was the priority slightly lower. On the job, thoughts about the family were recorded less often than other matters, but the concern could be great. One worker described the goals that kept his mind busy: 'Will I have the good fortune to secure a carefree life for my family?'19 And placement of children was a major preoccupation, as we have seen. Most often the desire was to put children in one's own job and factory, but circumstances might prod still greater ambition. Skilled workers at Daimler, even with their peasant-like concern for premarital conception, carefully placed their children in jobs better than their own.20 Yet one cannot escape the impression that the worker's family was not fully under control during this period and that its capacity to absorb new emotional shocks was limited. And shocks were inevitable, quite apart from the work situation, as halting efforts to improve the family's adaptability created new tensions. Three problem areas can be noted. First, the birth rate began declining rapidly. Here factory workers followed the artisanal pattern - but at some distance. Textile workers were quicker than most, because of the tradition of wives at work; this was true in Germany as in England. But miners and metal workers lagged. Their wages were superior, but children could be a considerable burden nevertheless, and these families were still producing clos'e to four children on the average (except in France) by 1914. There was no question, even in France, that average housing and diet were markedly superior in the smaller families, yet compared to artisans the response was rather sluggish.21 The traditional interest in children as an economic asset died hard. A British worker noted: 'If a railwayman has no children to work for him, he can only live decently by taking a lodger.'22 Though economically inaccurate, the logic remained compelling, and concern about provision for old age would legitimately enhance it. There was a great deal of outright ignorance. German factory workers were not sure of how to go about birth limitation. Most felt coitus interruptus was best, though knowledge of condoms (called Parisian articles) spread slowly. Much of the thought given to families while at work consisted of wony that the wife was late with her menstrual period, for there was a gap between the desire for fewer children and the implementation. The worker who said that his chief hope was 'that we have no more children' was speaking for many of his fellows.23 But one may wonder if this sentiment was always wholehearted on the part of a young male worker. Factory workers liked stability in their family, from home furnishings to their wife's behaviour. Dependent on physical strength, theirs was a male culture, in which fatherhood could be a sign of status. Where the work itself was
deteriorating, raising some challenge to the image of masculinity, a reduction of birth rate could itself be upsetting. Small wonder that some workers, particularly among the older generation, found birth control 'unnatural and wicked.'24
The birth rate did fall. Yet among factory workers its drop may not have been sufficient to relieve personal as well as economic tensions in the family, and it may have caused real anxieties on the part of both husbands and wives.
The labor movement could also disrupt the family. Miners' families often shared the concerns that would lead to a strike, but elsewhere wives could be firmly opposed to the risks of labor agitation. Their concern was regular income. Their culture, more religious than that of their husbands, was often deferential; many, for example, had learned as domestic servants, before marriage, to respect their betters. Small wonder that many labor leaders would agree that 'the most direct enemy of the strike is the housewife.'25
A final area of change constitutes another case in which adaptation to new expectations put pressure on traditional roles in the family. Factory workers, like artisans, typically did not like their wives to work outside the home. In the 1890s rates of employment among married working-class women varied mainly with the extent of domestic manufacture. Hence French and Belgian families depended more heavily on wives' income than German, and German than English.26 Within each national working class, wives worked in inverse proportion to the husbands' income. Hence in Germany wives provided 3.5 percent of the income in the families of skilled workers, 7.7 percent for the unskilled. Textiles formed a partial exception, with over a third of married women working. Even here, need was the primary reason. In one German factory in 1900, 50 percent claimed they worked because their husband earned too little, 17 percent to be able to afford a better life, 18 percent because of widowhood, and less than 10 peicent because they did not like housework. In British textiles the tradition of work was stronger and many women professed to be bored without it. Overall, the disapproval of wives working remained strong, and husbands pulled them off the job whenever their income sufficed for subsistence — at twenty marks a week in Germany, for example. Hence among Berlin metal workers, 17 percent of the wives of skilled workers held a job, and only 23 percent even in the unskilled category; in Britain, where incomes were higher, the percentage of women at work rose over 10 only in the textile centers. Other women did earning jobs at home or kept boarders, though this latter could create significant
tension in the family - to the point of breaking up some marriages.27 Around 1900 a number of factors combined to make outside employment more attractive to married women. Rising educational levels and employment experience before marriage, plus a declining birth rate, set the framework. The reduction of opportunities for work at home, except in France, was another important factor. Inflation put pressure on workers' budgets. Expectations rose. Skilled Berlin engineers, departing from tradition more rapidly than the unskilled, began having their wives work until their own income hit 1500 marks a year. The reason: they wanted better clothes and above all more spacious housing and more protection for illness and old age. Hence their wives worked almost as frequently as among the unskilled, despite the substantial gap in income; for the unskilled continued to pull their wives out when they could afford the subsistence income of 1000 marks a year.28 This was the basis, in Germany, for the rapid increase of married women working, notable between the two census years of 1895 and 1907 and gaining still more ground after 1910.29 The percentage of women workers who were married, in manufacturing and transport, rose from 17 percent to 21 percent between the two census years, a gain of 38 percent overall, considerably higher than their increase in the population. At this point we can only speculate about the impact of this change.30 Women could provide great relief to the family budget, which it was typically their responsibility to balance. In the long run, work helped equalize the roles and smooth the relationships of men and women in the working-class family. But at this point of transition the anxiety produced, among women as well as men, may have been considerable. What had been a sign of the husband's failure was now becoming commonplace.
This trend was avoided in Britain, where the increase of married women at work barely matched their gains in the population, but at a cost. With fewer children and higher expectations,, women were increasingly bored, and this could redound on their working husband. Sloppy housekeeping and slovenly appearance were two widely-noted symptoms.31 And amid mounting inflation the absence of new earnings created its own tensions. One of Robert Tressell's characters started an argument that must have raged in many working-class homes, as wives - held to a fixed household budget — failed to make ends meet: 'I never interfere about anything, because I think it's your part to attend to the house, but it seems to me you don't manage things properly.'32
The working-class family remained vigorous. Adaptation already
could produce favorable results. The skilled engineering workers in Berlin who let their wives work were interested in affording a second bedroom, so that they could sleep apart from their children. This suggests a new concern for privacy with one's wife, quite possibly a greater sexual intimacy, along with a greater appreciation of the children as human beings. The workers who sought greater leisure to improve their relations with their children implied a similar pattern. But factory workers were not yet free enough from severe pressure s on the job to expend the emotional energy on the family that they may well have wished. The fuller transition to a new family focus would depend on a far more favorable, or at least far more limited, work experience.33 The image of the authoritarian husband and father, taking out work frustrations on his family, remains pervasive before World War I, if only because the family could not adapt fast enough to compensate for a changing work situation. And again the relationship could be reciprocal. On the Continent, traditional family goals only slowly gave way, but this was oddly compatible with great tension. While we must sympathize with the wives who could bear the brunt of a masculine culture now challenged, they could offer some retaliation. A German worker described the domestic wrangling that could characterize working-class life in a crowded apartment. The husband came home tired, ready to curse at his children even against his intention. His wife, exhausted by more children than she wanted to care for, had the battles of the day to recount, often spoiling the dinner by tales of her wrangling with neighboring housewives. Britain in contrast seemed to this observer a haven, where more spacious housing created greater peace. But the same worker noted how sloppy the British housewife was. And in Britain even more than on the Continent, as workers developed new recreation patterns they tended to try to escape the family setting as much as they compensated for problems at work.34 The family, durable still and highly valued among life's purposes, was undergoing its own new stresses just as the work situation posed novel problems.
This conundrum helps explain another incomplete transition. Because of tensions, new and old, in the family situation, many workers were held back from an all-out campaign for greater leisure or even a-level of earnings that would compensate for new difficulties on the job. The restraints on the quest for leisure time have been discussed; they include the problem of what would be pleasurable off the job. The goal of higher earnings was in most respects more obvious, but it created a similar dilemma: given still-limited means, how hard should the worker
press for more money and how much would any foreseeable gains change the balance between job and non-job in his life? When the family had been the most obvious justification for work, its tensions, including the reduction in birth rate, could complicate the development of new consumption patterns. More commonly, the very persistence of the family as a traditional focus limited expectations.
Obviously workers wanted to earn more money. Their sense of justice on the job called for higher pay when the work became tougher.35 At an extreme, workers would be willing to take any job according to the wage it offered, and there was some impression that younger workers were choosing on this basis increasingly. It is not difficult to produce evidence of large categories of workers who sought to relate pay to changes in their work situation. English workers, with their greater experience, were especially articulate on this subject. Shipbuilders, agitating for a raise in 1898, cited the prosperity of their trade but added, 'the wages of our members are not in proportion to the arduous nature of their work, nor to the rates of pay of skilled workmen.'36 Miners in 1896 claimed that, since their work was harder and more dangerous than that of lawyers, they should earn at least as much. Iron workers in one company in 1910 appealed for a raise because of the introduction of a new roller engine; here quite clearly, change justified more money.37 Shoe workers based wage demands on the vibration and general discomfort caused by their new machines.38 Bradford dyers stated the principle most widely, claiming 'the right of the workmen to increased wages when contributing to increased output, or subjected to increased physical strain.'39
Similar instances can be found elsewhere. Le Havre dockers unloading saltpeter in 1910 suddenly struck because the work was too hard, and demanded a 25 percent raise. French textile workers often agitated when they received bad materials, because the work became more difficult. Carpenters working on the Paris Exposition, in 1899, asked for a raise on ground of the difficulties and dangers of their work.40 Bakers in the Seine-et-Oise summed up the sentiment: 'You'll admit that for work of twelve to fifteen hours a day, in an oven, with gas lighting and vitiated, germ-filled air, five francs a day is a derisory salary.'4 * And in all countries the many workers who sought a pay rise, even without precise justification in terms of the nature of the work, were following this general principle, particularly when they explicitly pursued wage gains in preference to direct improvements in the conditions of work.42 The very predominance of wage demands in strikes, over all other issues, indicates a willingness, if sometimes
reluctant, to see pay compensate for problems on the job. In 1908 typographers in Mont-de-Marson struck primarily against unemployment. They asked that all women be replaced and that the companies hire local unemployed typographers in preference to all others. They also demanded overtime pay and a cessation of fines, and a committee of employers and workers to resolve future differences. Yet they quickly saw that all they could win was a raise, and they settled for this. Wage gains became something of a panacea, and unquestionably served to divert grievances from the work itself.
Yet the correlation between changes in work and compensatory wage demands is far from complete, even in Britain. Too many workers preferred to try to control their work still, even if individually through absenteeism, rather than maximize their pay. Liverpool dockers in 1912 were cited as often preferring to stop work when they reached fifteen shillings a week, a bare subsistence, and examples of this could be multiplied. In a different case, British miners, though alert to protest deteriorations in their pay because of more difficult work and though unusually active in strikes of all sorts, did not. quickly turn to a formula associating work with their wage. The famous sliding scale linked wages to the price of coal and therefore, fairly directly, to the prosperity of the industry; but market conditions could easily dictate a stagnant or reduced wage even as work became more difficult. By the late 1890s miners in various areas began to question the sliding scale on this basis, but a full-scale rebellion occurred only after 1909, and then in favor of a minimum wage rather than direct association of wage with work.43 And in the Belgian mines, even the sliding scale formula gained acceptance only a few years before World War I, hailed as a major step forward just as it was being abandoned in Britain.
Obviously, problems in associating work and wage owed much to employer resistance. Furthermore, the spread of the piece rate helped individual workers make what they regarded as an appropriate linkage, through which they could tailor effort to earnings. And much of the concern about pay after 1900 stemmed from the growing difficulty of maintaining the real wage in the face of unprecedented inflation. In Germany, for example, prices rose 30 percent between 1885 and 1913. Money wages rose still faster, producing a healthy bonus, but there were many problems of adjustment and workers could feel cheated even when their real pay held steady. In France and even more in England, real wages advanced slowly if at all, deteriorating massively in England after 1910. Clearly, this was a difficult period in which to associate wage gains with work changes, and in fact many worke rs lost
ground. Even in Germany the relative share of the working class in total industrial income fell, as wages did not keep pace with productivity gains. Similarly in France profits considerably outstripped pay. So we can see many workers wanting to improve their wages to react to work changes but unable to do so because of resistance from above and more general economic trends.44
Yet, while not denying the ability of many workers to translate work into wage and the growing trend in this direction, several complications must be added for the pre-war years. Much working-class protest tradition responded to consumption changes, not changes at work, and while agitation in this period was developing new forms it had not broken with tradition completely; bread riots in France in 1910 were a definite throwback to the older response. Even in England the crest of direct-action protest after 1909 came not in response to changes at work but as a result of the heightened inflation. Correspondingly many workers troubled by innovations on the job would still answer directly, like the French auto workers after 1910 who sought to limit work time. Only gradually, often after the direct effort was frustrated, would they move to other kinds of demands. For large groups of workers, not only changes on the job but also changes in consumption expectations were essential to produce a new balance between work and earnings — and this returns us to the difficult problem of what life off the job was supposed to be like.45
Workers en masse were not yet fully modern economic men, a fact by no means to their discredit. Expectations could lag for a variety of reasons. Some workers, quite capable of formulating what they wanted from life, simply did not believe that serious gains were possible. 'I have very many wishes but what use are wishes to me,' said a German textile worker who then listed the better clothing, furniture, and provision for his children that he would like but would never have. Many workers, particularly of course in the newer industrial areas such as Germany, were so concerned about making sure they could survive with their families that the idea of tailoring expectations to work made no sense. Others explicitly renounced the notion that wages could ever compensate for their horrible work.46 Still others gave every appearance of being satisfied with their pay, even when their job conditions were changing. This was true in the French automobile industry, until the massive application of Taylorization. It was true of many settings in which manufacturing was still associated with rural life, particularly for unskilled workers. Tracklayers on the French railroads, though poor, kept contact with village traditions and village food supplies, and so
were hostile to any collective effort to improve their wages. Belgian workers, unusually close to the countryside, long preserved rural clothing, wearing wooden shoes at work and often underdressed for the winter; their diet was similarly traditional. Immigrant workers obviously fell into this pattern. Many accepted miserable conditions in the hopes of saving money to send home, but their wages were so good, in light of their rural expectations, that notions of change came hard. Some Polish workers in the Ruhr could return home as grandees, with their urban dress. While on the job their diets were good, again by their traditional standards, and they long combined village foods with what they could buy on the market — to the despair of landlords who tried to ban the smoking of sausages in the rooms. Additions to the diet allowed hard work, which meant more money saved and more time off when the work became too arduous — a pattern similar to that of Italian workers who crowded six to a room in the tenements of mining towns in the Lorraine.47 And while this satisfaction with pay— obviously not the same thing as satisfaction with work — was most characteristic of workers from the countryside, it could affect other groups as well. A number of experienced factory workers told Adolf Levenstein that they were content with their wages, which made them feel that they were human beings, not slaves. Clearly, variations in personality would play a great role, for others, in the same objective conditions, directly associated their wage level with their resentment against degradation and dependence. More generally French studies of worker consumption habits shortly before World War I noted that while workers vigorously opposed any reduction in their standard of living, it took time for them to accustom themselves to new earnings. English textile workers were caught in a similar pattern. Founding their families when their earnings were low, often before they had become full-fledged spinners or weavers, they attained higher wages only when their living style was rather set.48 All of this, while definitely not so firm as to prevent important adjustments in consumption patterns, inhibited a major effort to use better wages to meet alterations in the work setting.
The same conclusion emerges from a study of the budgets developed, admittedly by outside observers, for working-class families in the period. Available information concerns the Continental countries; England may well have offered a different pattern, as will be discussed. And the budgets are at best approximate; with few exceptions they omit details on important areas of spending such as drink and cover only a single year or two, rather than behavior over
time. Nevertheless, the materials suggest clearly that, within any large category of workers, spending habits did not change greatly with income. Variations of up to 100 percent in earnings produced no comparable distinctions in the percentage of the budget devoted to major items. More was spent on each item, of course. In a Munich study, workers earning 1200 marks a year spent 628 marks on food; those earning 1800 marks spent 788; so a difference of 50 percent in income caused on a 25 percent improvement in food expenditures. But if restaurant and liquor expenses are included, the general category of food and drink actually increased its hold on the budget, for the wealthier workers devoted 68 percent more in toto. We can assume that they improved their diet, ate out instead of taking their meals to work or returning home, and drank more. Would this kind of improvement in consumption motivate harder work or compensate for changes at work? The better-paid worker had to work harder and so had to eat more. It was not a totally senseless calculation to take lower pay, work less, and have to eat less. In so far as harder work might impel heavier drinking, the attractions again might be ambiguous, for wives would certainly look askance at this use of earnings. What the better-paid workers did not do was proportionately increase their spending on housing; almost invariably they reduced the percentage of budget allocated to this purpose, leaving only a slightly larger absolute amount for rent. In the Munich study, the 1200-mark workers spent 206 marks a year on rent, or 15 percent of their budget; those at 1800 marks spent 227 marks, or 12 percent. They might of course be burdened with fewer children, as skilled categories generally reduced their birth rates first, but even this was not always clear. It does seem probable that a major improvement in housing was so costly, and the need for a better diet to support higher earnings so pressing in a protein-poor environment, that higher earnings did not clearly provide a better life. Workers could cut their percentage allocation to food somewhat. They therefore improved their percentage allocations to clothing and to relatively minor areas such as union dues, recreation, and heat and light; but generally the change involved less than 10 percent of the total budget. Skilled workers in another German study spent 1.4 percent of their income on health, 4.3 percent on intellectual and social expenditures (dues, school, recreation), compared to 1.3 percent and 3.5 percent respectively among the unskilled. In Breslau, workers earning 1200—1700 marks compared to those with incomes of 1900—2350 marks as follows: 51 percent of the budget as against 47 percent on food; 10.5 percent as against 11 percent on clothes — a slight gain; 17 percent as against 15
percent on rent. In Numberg 1200-mark workers spent the same percentage on rent (at 14 percent) as those earning 1800 marks; 57 percent as against 55 percent on food; 5 percent as against 7 percent on clothing.49
Sketchier figures from Belgium show much the same pattern, for the standard of living here was even lower. The poorest workers spent 66 percent of their income on food, 13 percent on rent. The wealthiest category decreased their spending in both categories, but not substantially (65 percent on food, 9 percent on rent). And over time, with rising earnings, the Belgian working class as a whole actually increased its allocation to food: from 55—61 percent in 1891 to 57—66 percent in 1908. Rising prices may have played some role here, but the need for more protein, particularly from meat, simply to tolerate greater strain at work loomed still larger.50
French workers were better off on the average, and income differentials here produced a greater departure from purely subsistence spending. A study right before the war compared workers with incomes of 1000—1500 francs annually with those earning 2500 francs. The budget percentage devoted to food dropped from 85 percent to 70 percent. Rent dropped as well, from 10 percent to 8 percent. Hence about 15 percent of total income remained for reallocation to clothing, union dues, heat and light, and so on. Still, the greatest change in absolute expenditure came in the purchase of meat.51
All of this is not to belittle the importance of income differentials or the significant improvements in diet and clothing that they could produce. But the budgets suggest that many workers were still close enough to subsistence that a wage raise might not seem an obvious compensation for harder or more boring work. A small raise would not propel a worker into a different pattern of spending. Large items of expenditure, of the sort that required planning ahead, were not really within range. Housing, for example, was not a prime concern. Unquestionably workers wanted better housing. German workers mentioned this frequently, as well they might given the fact that, in the larger cities, a near-majority had only a single room.52 But until one could afford a real gain in space, like the skilled engineering workers who sent their wives to work so that they could afford a separate bedroom, a small increment to the rental money meant little, which is why so many workers reduced their rent percentage when their earnings did go up. Many workers could not, furthermore, really believe in a long-term increase in pay; hence the familiar tendency of the class to spend extra earnings on present needs rather than to evolve a new and
durable life style.
A host of impressions confirm the idea of limited consumer expectations on the part of many workers; we need not rely on an admittedly speculative interpretation of budget materials alone. While workers were open to changes in diet, the hand of tradition could slow new expectations. Some immigrants from East Germany to the Ruhr were reluctant to pick up a taste for meat, regretting the herring they had grown up on. Bourgeois nutritionists from England to Germany lamented the reluctance of the working class to buy fruits and vegetables which would improve diet without raising costs; again, customs of older peasants and workers seemed responsible, for housewives had no experience in using n-ew foods. A Belgian worker in a backward section of the country described limited expectations still more vividly: 'During my entire youth I found it usual to eat dry bread.' He acquired a taste for butter — but only in 1919. Belgians in more industrialized areas had the urge for butter, spending a much higher percentage of their food budget on this item than their counterparts in other countries, but lagged in the quest for meat, which kept their protein consumption down. Obviously this suggests a vicious circle, in which workers could only slowly supplement traditional fare, but it remains probable that many Belgian workers thought in terms of modest additions to their diet, if they could afford such thought at all.53 In both Belgium and Germany, enough workers were close to the borderline of subsistence that survival, not improvement, seemed the main task. 'We want no more starvation,' proclaimed some German miners, while metallurgical workers noted: 'The year 1908 was a year of hunger.'54 Improvement in standards would be welcome, but expectations were tied to the process of consumption itself, and were limited, instead of relating closely to the work experience.
Clothing was definitely a flexible interest, though again with limitations. The Belgian workers who preserved peasant garb have already been mentioned. Unskilled factory laborers in Germany were cited as accepting, as part of a natural hierarchy, the fact that their skilled colleagues wore overcoats in winter while they did not. Even in Lancashire, factory girls only slowly abandoned their traditional evening shawls and clogs, dressing more like London shopgirls — to the horror of their parents in many cases. Some women who were clearly interested in better clothing refrained from pushing too hard, lest they discontent their husbands; in Britain some stayed at home, as a result, rather than display their shabbiness — again a case of hopes that seemed too remote from reality. A desire for brighter, more varied clothing
undoubtedly spread widely, for this was a source of pleasure and status in the working-class world, particularly among the young. Even Polish immigrants to the Ruhr picked up the desire for some big-city clothes, mixing them with traditional attire. Again, however, one emerges with a picture of something less than open-ended acquisitiveness, particularly outside the largest cities.55
Housing was less often discussed, and we can only surmise that improvements were desired but often regarded as remote. Many among the urban poor, as at the London docks, preferred to remain in familiar neighborhoods than to step up to 'better' housing units; this -was an impulse that increased with age. German workers were held back from an active search for larger units, save where income clearly warranted, because of a traditional and understandable concern for warmth. Silesian miners often ignored the living room provided in company housing because they could not heat it properly; not only cold weather but also poor diets contributed to this behavior. In the Ruhr, in contrast, miners more routinely expected a three-room unit.56 Another potential goal for increased earnings made even more limited sense in the working-class context. Acutely aware of the dangers of illness and old age, workers still lacked a culture of saving. They would accept insurance schemes that took out a small percentage from salary each week, but the idea of using rising earnings to provide on one's own for future contingencies came hard. Even workers with wages above the average found their lives too full of risks, their day-to-day needs too pressing, to think of saving. A turner in a German engineering plant, interviewed in a prosperous year: 'in the current bad conditions of life I cannot save the slightest amount.' A colleague: 'In these bad times it is not possible for my family to save in order to live in our old age, so we must hope for something better.'57 Again, there was no lack of a sense of what might be done if..., but active realization seemed too remote.
It is easy to be middle-class in judgements of this sort, noting that workers differed from clerks in not using extra earnings on savings or housing. As a partial antidote, one might note that in Munich, working-class percentage expenditure on drink was matched by the much wealthier categories of university professors and upper bureaucrats.58 There is no reason to dismiss interest in clothing, say, as less worthy than interest in housing, particularly given its greater accessibility to a still-poor class. Yet the consumption traditions and expectations of a substantial segment of the working class suggest serious difficulty in adapting work to a new style of life off the job. Changes in work could induce a desire for compensation. Other factors,
such as inflation, might also encourage a demand for steadily rising earnings. But the desire was not entirely natural in terms of working-class culture. The pre-war years, for the working class as a whole, unquestionably brought greater changes in work than in earning; for many workers the alteration of work also outstripped the development of a definite sense of how, even in theory, material existence could be made to compensate off the job.
This was not, however, true for all workers. As usual, every major generalization about the class must be qualified. The greater the experience with industrial life and above-subsistence earnings, the greater the openness to changes in life style. British workers, taken collectively, differed decisively from those on the Continent in seeking improved housing. They had better housing, on the average, and they wanted more; hence with higher earnings they maintained or even slightly increased the percentage of budget devoted to rent.59 And even on the Continent key groups of workers stood out in the precision of their thinking about how new income might be used. They were among the higher paid and, usually, more urbanized categories, but other traditions could support their thinking as well.
Urban artisans knew how they would spend more money if they could get it! This, in close relationship to a belief that changes in work could appropriately be compensated by higher wages, dictated a persistent effort to improve pay scales through strikes and negotiation. With smaller families, artisans could reduce their budgetary commitment to food as their incomes rose, without suffering. In Belgium, for example, printers spent 57 percent of their earnings on food while miners, whose pay was higher, but who had more children, spent 65 percent. This left room for two or three clear interests. Housing was one, and artisans regularly devoted a significant portion of their incomes to this purpose — 14 percent in the Belgian case, as against a class average of 10 percent. Educational and recreational uses took a higher share as well —3.4 percent in Belgium, compared to the class average of 1.2 percent.60 Urban artisans had come to expect a steadily rising standard of living. Belgian printers said as much in 1909: 'Not only has the rise in prices been enormous for the main necessities of life, but also the necessities have become more numerous.'61 The same pattern emerges clearly in Germany. Frankfurt artisans devoted up to 20 percent less of their earnings to food, and over 10 percent more on rent, than other workers in the city (skilled construction workers fell roughly in the middle, as in the matter of birth rate limitation). And again, where artisanal earnings rose housing immediately gained a
greater share. Machine workers in printing and skilled woodwork spent up to 5 percent more of their higher incomes on housing than their colleagues in manual jobs. They also raised their savings, in some cases putting 19 percent aside in an average year. Artisans had a tradition of saving, from the days when a journeyman could hope to buy into the business of his master. They now applied it to protection against bad times or illness; to home ownership — in a city like Bochum between 30 and 61 percent of all artisans owned their homes in 1901, as against 12 percent of the leading factory group; and to provision for their children. Children were to be educated and given dowries.62 This was a concern which only artisans found it realistic to mention in a strike, like the printers in Brussels who asked for a raise to assure 'the upkeep and education of our children.'63
Many urban artisans were thus working toward a life style not very different from that of the lower middle class. Their rates of home ownership might indeed be higher than those of the lower middle class. They evidenced a similar concern for family respectability and placement of children. They developed new recreational interests as well, patronizing the plush bars that were springing up all over Paris or the music halls of London. While not abandoning careful defense of standards on the job, the artisans were diversifying their lives.
For their part, factory workers were not a homogeneous category. Different traditional levels of earnings and different contacts with urban life styles caused important distinctions. Metal workers came closest to artisanal patterns, because of their professional backgrounds and concentration in the larger cities. Their allocations to housing were greater, although obviously the higher rent levels of the cities accounted for some of this. Notably, a German study indicated that in contrast to most factory workers, the skilled metal group increased its percentage expenditure on rent with higher wages — from 12 percent at 1200 marks to 15 percent at 2000 marks. Workers in the metal industries also saw housing in status terms, ready to live in better neighborhoods away from the unskilled. In a rather different sense, miners also were drawn to housing, often owning their homes, though their budget allocation was low on the average because of the availability of company units. Actual variations in budget patterns were slight (though they mask huge differences from one worker to the next within each industrial group, depending on family size and personal taste) — certainly not comparable to the worker-artisan gap. Nevertheless metal workers do seem closer than textile workers to regular expectations of improving standards of living. Thus the metal workers interviewed by Adolf
Levenstein listed higher pay as their first hope for the future, while textile workers opted for the advent of socialism.64
It is probable nevertheless that, particularly outside of Britain, large numbers of factory workers, and many small-town artisans as well, were not able quickly to counter changes on the job with the development of new pleasures off the job. New kinds of spending purposes did not arise rapidly. Correspondingly, many workers were slow to develop new recreational interests. This confirms the impression already given by the budget studies: given very modest, if not subsistence, earnings there was little to spare for recreation, while workers did not move rapidly to free a higher percentage of their earnings for new leisure activities. They depended at most on higher overall pay, which would enhance the value of the traditional recreation allotment. But many did not have the kind of recreational interests that would cost much money anyway.
The argument, as with overall consumption standards, must be stated carefully. Workers were by no means lacking in things to do after work, though their traditional leisure patterns included much non-activity whose pleasurable qualities are hard to assess. The point is that much of what they liked to do cost nothing and was hard to embellish in response to new leisure time or a new need for compensatory enjoyments off the job. It is the slowness of change for many workers, not the absence of some life off the job, that deserves comment in the pre-war years.
A third of all workers at Daimler, asked about their recreation, stressed 'rest and sleep' as their main interest: 'Smoking tobacco and reading the newspaper on the sofa;' 'going for a walk and afterwards having a couple of beers.'65 German workers greatly preferred taking a walk or gardening to all other activities on a Sunday, along with a bit of helping with the housework and playing with the children. Foreign observers commented on their serious reading habits, but this was in fact confined to a few; light reading was preferred. Interestingly there was little difference between small-town and big city workers in leisure preferences, a clear reflection of the traditional base. At most one can note a greater desire for rest and less tendency to do extra paid work on a Sunday. Big city workers walked about more on Sunday - here the interest in stylish clothing was relevant; the better-paid also enjoyed restaurants. Predictably food drew the attention of many workers with a bit extra at the end of the week, as they bought a cheese or a ham with their surplus. But it was big-city workers who were more articulate in their desire to maintain contact with nature, and while they were less likely to have gardens than miners or small-town workers they
expressed great interest in this as well.66 It was a Berlin mechanic who said, 'I believe that every city resident, as soon as time permits, should go to the countryside, go to nature and fill his lungs with pure, unspoiled air.'67 Add an occasional dance, at a religious or socialist gathering, and, for some, participation in a singing group or in music at home, and one has a picture of huge numbers of German workers off the job.
The same holds true, more impressionistically, for many Belgian workers, with the more common addition of a cheap railioad trip to the countryside on Sunday. Walking was a well-established pastime in France. Even in Britain Alfred Williams describes workmates who had no leisure activity other than sleeping and smoking. For many, clearly, more demanding jobs would simply exacerbate the temptation to do nothing with leisure time, for want of energy; and this would delay any constructive reaction to the changes at work.
For workers with a bit more money than they were used to and a bit more leisure time, the bar was the typical first attraction. Drinking was a well-established tradition that could now be increasingly indulged. A German locksmith, earning good money on the piece rate and fond of his family, invariably took Monday off to get drunk, spending a goodly sum in the process. A fifth of the German miners polled by Levenstein said that drinking was indispensable, even though they came to work unhappy on Monday because they had drunk too much on Sunday. Textile and metal workers were less addicted, or less frank, but many of them drank heavily as well. Among German printers, Bavarians spent a full 8 percent of their budget on drink, while Northerners, spending 2 percent, had much more interest in Sunday trips to the country and other activities. But heavy drinking was visible in every manufacturing area, tending to rise with wages particularly among unskilled group s and immigrants. Drinking was still more pervasive in Belgium, which had more bars per capita — one per thirty-five people — than any other country in the world, although there were reports that drinking was declining and that a proletarian culture boastful of the alcohol consumed was giving way to greater moderation. In France the 1890s saw a peak of alcohol consumption, particularly with the rise of the apéritif; and while the per capita data are not class-specific, the working class obviously took a prominent role. Bars in working-class sections became fancier in their decor as well as in the liquor served.68
It is important not to take the simplistic view of these developments common among bourgeois moralists and labor leaders alike, as recent studies of working-class drinking remind us.69 Drinking could be
pleasurable, particularly as surroundings improved, a first step to a sense of a life outside the job. It was not necessarily a sign of alienation or an effort to kill the misery which work caused. It is important to recall also that large segments of the middle class, some at least happy in their work and successful at it, drank more heavily than many workers; the fancy working-class bars in Paris, for example, were copied from those patronized by clerks and professional people on the grands boulevards. Yet without adopting the conventional moralistic approach, which bemoans drinking whether blaming it on workers themselves or on capitalist society, it is relevant to note some of the limitations of the practice as a recreational activity. It was, first of all, not thoroughly separated from work. Many workers drank to get through their job as well as drinking to use up their leisure time. Drinking at work remained an important custom in metallurgy, construction, and dock work, and for individuals in virtually every industry. German button makers, tired by their work, often took some schnapps : 'It makes me feel like I just got to work,' said one.70 Off the job, heavy drinking, far from compensating for work, made work once resumed more difficult. And while workers might well seek more pay in order to buy more liquor, increased drinking would not be readily compatible with a higher pace at work. Nbr did it conduce to a general increase in expectations. It could easily limit other interests, in alternate recreation and in other consumption items. Many workers drank, for example, to escape their miserable housing; but this would only make a realistic interest in improving one's housing more difficult.
Many workers were thus caught in a rather traditional leisure pattern as the nature of their work changed. Resting and some attention to the family remained vital, but it was hard to see that their quality as leisure activities improved greatly. Drinking habits, for some, were changing more visibly, but they involved serious limitations as part of a new life style. They conflicted with the family interest, when carried to an extreme, and they inhibited newer recreational forms. It was the workers who kept drinking expenses down, like the North German printers, or whose drinking declined — as among many Belgian workers and certainly the British working class71 — who developed a genuinely novel approach to leisure, without of course eliminating drink as an outlet.
Signs of new interests abound, with British workers predictably leading the way. Scottish printers by 1894 had picked up an interest in photography, which they indulged on Saturdays. They also liked music, played soccer football, and had golf matches on weekends and summer
evenings. As drinking declined among miners, they took to football and betting on games, along with a traditional interest in religion or, among younger miners, a new fascination with socialist discussions and literature. 'Rabbit-coursing' was widely popular, with bets placed; it consisted of dogs chasing rabbits in a confined area and was first introduced in the 1890s. Annual company vacations loomed large as well, reminiscent in some ways of periodic festivals, in drawing workers' interest for months in advance. Billiard parlors, roller skating rinks, as well as movie houses and music halls spread in industrial towns, along with fancier pubs. Bicycles became widely popular among younger workers by the 1890s, and served as a focus for savings. A German worker was astounded at the contrast with his compatriots, in the 1890s, noting that British workers used Sundays for play, not for drinking, and so returned to work refreshed. Better fed and stronger, they could also be active during the week, the younger workers playing games such as football at the lunch hour and after work.72
Without minimizing the variety involved in these recreational interests, several general types predominated. Sports certainly took pride of place. Many younger workers spent all their free time playing football or going to local games, sometimes skipping meals to have enough for the Saturday match. Here was a clear carry-over from a work culture, in which males could demonstrate their strength and skill with energy which once had to be given to the job alone. Related to sports was the passion for betting, but in this women participated too, if separately, as bookmakers went door to door. Here was a means of adding a bit of excitement to life, and maybe a way to simplify the problem of making ends meet: 'But that £5 we won at the new year, it did fetch us up wonderful.'73 Or the dour comment of the German observer: 'As lotteries are forbidden in England, people resort to betting in order to get rid of their money.'74 Another recreational category was the excursion, by bicycle or rail, sometimes involving a picnic in the country or a visit to the shore. And a spectator culture was developing as well, most obviously in the London music halls but also in the movie houses, in which the problems of working-class life c ould be laughed at or forgotten in fantasy.
Recreation among Continental workers followed with only a slight lag. Belgian miners had a passion for pigeon racing, but also particip ated in various ball games; bets on both activities were common. An interest in bicycling spread widely; 90,000 young Germans were reported belonging to bicycle clubs. As suggested, gambling on the Continent focused on the lotteries, though less money was available than in British
betting; in Germany tobacco shops in working-class neighborhoods sold tickets. Summer excursions, sponsored by companies or labor organizations, were common. By 1900 sports were winning attention in Germany. Half of the workers at Daimler participated in some sports, particularly gymnastics and football but also bicycling, swimming, and bowling. The interest in swimming — a number of German workers belonged to swimming clubs — predated the ability of urban workers in Britain or France to swim at all, perhaps a function of the recency of rural origins.75
This was, on the whole, an escapist culture, which is quite possibly what a leisure culture ought to be. Interest in theater and reading did exist. It can be traced among some young Welsh miners. One observer claimed that engineering workers in Britain were more 'serious' than other groups. The sober cultural interests of German workers were often cited, but membership in socialist drama groups and the like was traceable in the hundreds, not the thousands of the recreational organizations that abounded in the cities. Interest in escapist fiction, always predominant in the trade union libraries, increased in the years before the war. In one union library books borrowed on economic and social problems dropped from 12 percent of the total in 1907 to 5 percent in 1911.76 Relatedly, there was little question that the rising leisure interests drew many workers away from regular participation in the activities of organized labor.
From the standpoint of developments on the job, however, the new leisure interests were only to be expected. Even organized labor activities related to recreation in many ways. Union halls served as social centers in the Welsh mines. The socialist Maisons du peuple in Belgium provided game rooms, gymnasiums, libraries, and restaurants — even advice to the lovelorn. Strikes could take on a festive air, particularly in their early stages, as workers sought release from their labor. And the more elaborate efforts often brought picnics and other formal recreational activities to keep spirits up. There was serious purpose to all this as well, but the play element should not be denied. Workers were increasingly learning new forms of play. Some were coming to judge life in terms largely apart from work. A Sheffield cutler in 1903 recalled progress since his childhood: then there was meager clothing, much drinking, now stylish clothes that made one feel good on a Sunday, education and sobriety, and the local football team.77 One might be excused for neglecting what was happening on the job, however unfortunate this neglect might prove.
Yet some of the limitations of the workers' leisure ethic must be
noted as well. The gradualness of the acceptance of new recreational activities needs no further emphasis. Many workers needed funds, free time, even improvements in diet before they could afford some of the new interests, yet without these interests they could still be inhibited from asking for gains of this sort. There was some conflict between the new leisure activities and the workers' family focus. The most important interests were masculine, in fact if not of necessity. This is why they compensated for some waning satisfactions on the job, in a class that had long defined itself in assertively masculine terms. Yet real conflicts could develop when the breadwinner expropriated earnings above a traditional subsistence budget for his own Leisure, as was happening with growing frequency in Britain. That married women had far fewer recreational outlets is obvious, yet some of their frustrations could affect their husbands as well. Too much stress on the leading new recreational interests thus could limit family satisfactions, thereby weakening one major aspect of life off the job as another was being strengthened. To an extent this was an inevitable dilemma in the development of a new life style, but to an extent it also mirrored the specific problems on the job for which leisure was meant to compensate: the physical tensions, the challenges to a masculine sense of purpose.78
There was another, related limitation. For women as well as men the leading new recreational activities were designed for the young. They perpetuated that element in working-class culture that stressed youth and physical strength. It was the young men that went off to games, the young women who went on picnics, the courting couple that went to the music halls. Not only limits of physical strength but also the problem of money prevented the full transfer of comparable interest to married workers. The married artisan family, living in London, could afford the music hall at most twice a year, without sacrificing other important interests. Working-class women were in the ironic position of pressing for a marriage that would greatly reduce their recreational outlets; here was a dilemma that has yet to be fully resolved. Working-class men were caught in a culture that punished them in leisure as in work when their strength declined, or when they thought it declined. Small wonder that workers constantly looked back on their youth with fondness, even praising military service as a high point in their lives because it had broken the routine. There were of course hints of ongoing leisure interests, in the rise of spectator activities — the movies — and occasional mention of hobbies such as photography and insect collections, which would ultimately increase in importance.79
For the moment, however, the most obvious new interests, apart from work, had direct impact only on certain groups and certain stages in life. They might give other workers something to talk about, and the pubs and bars increasingly buzzed with news of sports events, but their function in enhancing life might be limited. For most married workers, one is thrown back to the family and rather traditional consumption patterns, a life style that might not change as rapidly as work itself and that was subject to its own new stresses.
Notes
1. Michael Anderson, Family Structure in Nineteenth-Century Lancashire (Cambridge, 1971).
2. R. Seebohm Rowntree, Poverty, a Study of Town Life (London, 1951), 55; see also Peter N. Stearns, 'Working-Class Women in Britain, 1890-1914,' in M. Vicinus, éd., Suffer and Be Still (Bloomington, 1972), 100-120.
3. Michael Katz, review of Anderson, Family, in Journal of Social History (1973), 86—92. For more general considerations on this topic, see Edward Shorter, 'Female Emancipation, Birth Control, and Fertility in European History,' American Historical Review (1973/, 605 ff. and Michael Phayer, 'Lower-Class Morality; the Case of Bavaria,' Journal of Social History (1974).
4. Miners' Federation of Great Britain, Minutes of the Proceedings of the Board (Manchester, 1913), 4.
5. Gareth Stedman Jones, 'Working-Class Culture and Working-Class Politics in London, 1870—1900; Notes on the Remaking of a Working Class,' Journal of Social History (1974); Ferdynand Zweig, The Worker in an Affluent Society (London, 1962), passim.
6. Stedman Jones, 'Culture.'
7. Walter T. Layton, The Relation of Capital and Labour (London, n.d.), 77; Walter Abelsdorff, Beitràge zur Sozialstatistik der deutschen Buchdrucker (Tubingen, 1900); Konrad Frick, 'Zur Lage der Backereiarbeiter/Di'e Neue Zeit (1904—5), 624—6.
8. Hans Hinke, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiter im Buch-druckgewerbe (Berlin, 1910); Der Zimmerer, 16 October 1909; Henry Steele, The Working Classes in France, a Social Study (London, 1904), 51-3.
9. Abelsdorff, Beitràge; Ministère du travail, Statistique des familles et des habitations en 1911 (Paris, 1918), 60—61 ; Stewart Johnson, 'Large Families and Poverty,' Journal of the Royal Statistical Society (1912), 545; Charles Booth, Life and Labour of the People of London (London, 1897), X, 39; Franz Kempel, Die 'christliche' und die 'neutrale' Gewerkvereinbewegung (Mainz,
1901), 138 ff.
10. Frederic Deters, The Role of the Suburbs in the Modernization of Vienna (Ph.D. dissertation, University of Chicago, 1974).
11. Emile Vandervelde, L'Exode rural et le retour aux champs (Paris, 1908), 146-8.
12. M. Loane, Next Street But One (London, 1907); Sidney Pollard, A History of Labour in Sheffield (Liverpool, 1959), 123.
13. This is a theme interestingly developed for immigrants to a factory town in New York State, in Daniel Walkowitz, 'Working-Class Women in the Gilded Age: Factory, Community and Family Life Among New York Cotton Workers,' Journal of Social History (1972), 464-90.
14. Paul de Rousiers, Hambourg et l'Allemagne contemporaine (Paris, 1902), 249 ff.; M. Pappenheim et al., Die Lage der in der Seeschiffahrt beschaftigen Arbeiter (Leipzig, 1902).
15. Wilhelm Brepohl, Der Aufbau des Ruhrvolkes im Zuge der Ost-West Wanderung (Recklinghausen, 1948), 205 ff.; Stedman Jones, 'Culture;' Max Eichhorst, Die Lage der Bergarbeiter im Saarbegiet (Eisleben, 1901); Stearns, 'Women.'
16. Fritz Schumann, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Automobilindustrie (Leipzig, 1911), 106. For a comparable, if slightly more recognizably modem situation in Britain, see Stearns, 'Women,' 112; here a construction worker was in 'no hurry' to marry until his girl became pregnant and he could not honorably delay.
17. M. S. Pember Reeves, Round About a Pound a Week (London, 1913), 152.
18. Moritz Bromme, Lebensgeschichte eines modernen Fabrikarbeiters (Leipzig, 1905), 90 ff.
19. Adolf Levenstein, Die Arbeiterfrage (Munich, 1913), 107 and passim; see also Mrs. Hugh Bell, At the Works (London, 1907); Goetz Briefs et ai., Das Bild des Arbeiters in der katholische Sozialbewegung (Cologne, 1960).
20. Schumann, Auslese.
21. Franx Hitze, Geburtenrùckgang und Sozialreform (Mônchen-Gladbach, 1917); Stearns, 'Women;' M. L. Dugé de Bernonville, 'Enquête sur les conditions de la vie ouvrière et rurale en France en 1913 — 14,' Bulletin de la Statistique générale de la France (1917), 196,313.
22. Rowland Kenney, Men and Rails (London, 1949), 73.
23. Bromme, Lebensgeschichte ; Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage.
24. Stearns, 'Women,' 107 and passim.
25. Fédération corporative des mouleurs en métaux de France, Compte rendu officiel du Ve Congrès (Paris, 1906), 106; see also H. Leduc, 'A Villeneuve-Saint-Georges,' Vie ouvrière (1912), 658 ff.
26. Cari von Tyszka, Lohne und Lebenskosten im Westeuropa im 19. Jahrhundert (Munich, 1914), 47; French wives provided 11.7*% of
the total family pay in 1907; Maurice Halbwachs, 'Revenus et dépenses de ménages des travailleurs: Une enquête officielle d'avant-guerre,' Revue d'économie politique (1921), 52; B. Seebohm Rowntree, Land and Labour: Lessons from Belgium (London, 1911), 72 ff.
27. 'Trend of Wages in Germany 1898-1907,' Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor (Washington, 1910), 795 ff.; Henriette Fùrth, Die Fabrikarbeit verheirateten Frauen (Leipzig, 1910); Stearns, 'Women;' Dora Lande, Die Arbeits- und Lohnverhàltnisse in der Berliner Maschinenindustrie zw Beginn des 20. Jahrhunderts (Leipzig, 1910); Adolf Levenstein, Aus der Tiefe, Arbeiterbriefe (Berlin, 1908), 34.
28. Lande, Arbeitsverhàltnisse.
29. Arthur Feiler, Die Konjunktur-Periode 1907—1913 in Deutschland (Jena, 1914); see Chapter I, Table IV.
30. Zweig, Worker, passim.
31. Stearns,'Women.'
32. Robert Tressell, 772e Ragged-Trousered Philanthropists (London, 1955), 58.
33. Zweig, Worker, passim.
34. Ernst Duckerstoff, How an English Workman Lives (London, 1899), 40 ff.; Stearns, 'Women.'
35. Ben Tillett, History of the London Transport Workers' Strike (London, 1911), 8.
36. NatioAal Amalgamated Union of Labour, Quarterly Report, 1898.
37. Miners' Federation of Great Britain, Annual Conference (1896), 21; Ironworkers' Journal, 1912.
38. National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives, Monthly Reports, 1896-99.
39. Labour Gazette, February 1907.
40. Peter N. Stearns, Revolutionary Syndicalism and French Labor (New Brunswick, 1971), passim.
41. Archives départmentales de Seine-et-Oise, Series M, report of 1906.
42. W. Mosses, The History of the United Pattern Makers' Association 1872-1922 (London, 1922), 135.
43. S. Woolf, 'An Experiment in Decasualization: The Liverpool Dock Scheme,' The Economic Journal (1914), 314 ff.; J. E. Williams, The Derbyshire Miner (London, 1962), 305 ff.
44. A. L. Bowley, The Change in the Distribution of the National Income 1880-1913 (Oxford, 1920); Ashok V. Desai, Real Wages in Germany 1871-1913 (Oxford, 1968), 30; Stearns, Syndicalism, 113 ff.; Jean Bouvier, François Furet and Marcel Gillet, Le Mouvement du profit en France au XIXe siècle (Paris, 1965).
45. E. H. Phelps Brown, The Growth of British Industrial Relations (London, 1959); James Laux, 'Travail et travailleurs dans l'industrie automobile jusqu'en 1917,' Mouvement social (1972), 9-26.
46. Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, passim.
47. H. Leduc, 'Villeneuve,' 651 ff.; Rowntree, Land, 391 ff.; Wachowiak Stanislav, Die Polen in Rheinland-Westfdlen (Leipzig, 1916); F. Hecht, Die Storgungen in deutschen Wirtschaftsleben (Leipzig, 1903), II.
48. S. J. Chapman, 'Some Policies of the Cotton Spinners' Trade Unions,' The Economic Journal (1900), 470; Maurice Halbwachs, La Classe ouvrière et les niveaux de vie (Paris, 1913), 443; Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, passim.
49. Else Conrad, Lebensfùhrung von 22 Arbeiterfamilien in Miinchen (Munich, 1909), II; 'Trend of Wages,' passim; Statistisches Amt der Stadt Breslau, Breslauer Haushaltungsrechnungen (Breslau, 1912); Haushaltungsrechnungen Nurnberger Arbeiter (Nuremberg, 1901).
50. Carl von Tyszka, Die Lebenshaltungen der arbeitenden Klassen (Jena, 1910), 531; Hans Gehrig and Heinrich Waentig, eds., Belgiens Volkswirtschaft (Leipzig, 1918), 221.
51. Board of Trade, Report of an Enquiry into Working Class Rents, Housing, and Prices. . . in the Principal Industrial Towns of France (London, 1909, Cd. 4512); Dugé de Bern on. ville, 'Enquête,' 90; Halbwachs, 'Revenus,' 57.
52. Tyszka, Lebenshaltungen. A\% of all Berliners lived in one room, and 34% in two, in 1905; in London the figures were 6.7% and 15%.
53. J. C. Drummond and Anne Wilbraham, The Englishman's Food (London, 1957); Robert Victor, Histoire du mouvement ouvrier dans le Naumourois (Brussels, 1957); Rowntree, Land; Josef B. Siebert, Die Lage der Arbeiterschaft in der rheinischen Braun-kohlenindustrie (Bonn, 1910).
54. Deutscher Metallarbeiter-Verband, 320 Haushaltsre chnungen von Metallarbeitern (Stuttgart, 1909); Otto Krille, Aus engen Gassen (Munich, n.d.), 41.
55. Schumann, Auslese; Paul Gôhre, Drei Monate Fabrikarbeiter (Leipzig, 1913); Charles Watney and James A. Little, The Workers' Daily Round (London, n.d.), 279; Kempel, 'Christliche.'
56. Loane, Next Street; Seidel, Das Arbeiterwohnungswesen in der Oberschlesischen Montanindustrie (Kattowitz, 1913), 21 ff.
57. Clemens Heiss, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiter in der Berliner Feinmechanik (Leipzig, 1910), 225; for more recent evidence of a similar culture, J. H. Goldthorpe et al., Affluent Worker in the Class Structure (Cambridge, 1969), passim.
58. Halbwachs, Classe; Conrad, Lebensfùhrung, II.
59. Board of Trade, Report of an Enquiry into Working Class Rents, Housing, and Retail Prices (London, 1908, Cd. 3864); Bell, Works, 68, also testifies to the interest in improving housing as income rose.
60. Max Gottsehalk, 'Le Pouvoir d'achat et la consommation des ouvriers belges à différentes époques,' Revue internationale du
travail (1932), 832; the figures are from 1891.
61. Gustav Conrady, Historié de la Federation locale (Brussels, 1921), 253.
62. August Busch, Preisbewegungen und Kosten der Lebenshaltung im Frankfurt am Main (Munich, 1914); Erich Ackerman, Uber typische Haushaltungsbudgets deutschen Arbeiterfamilien (Barmen, 1900); David Crew, 'Definitions of Modernity: Social Mobility in a German Town,'Journal ofSocial History (1973), 51 ff. ; Abelsdorff, Beitràge.
63. Conrady, Histoire, 406.
64. Gottschalk, 'Pouvoir,' 832; Deutscher Metallarbeiter-Verband, Haushaltungsrechnungen; E. Waxweiler, Quelques questions de la vie ouvrière (Brussels, 1905), 12; Jungst, Arbeitslohn und Unternehmergewinn im rheinisch-westfàlischen Steinkohlenberg-bau (Essen, n.d.); Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, passim.
65. Schumann, Auslese, 196.
66. Heinrich Herkner, Problème der Arbeiterpsychologie (Leipzig, 1912); Else Hermann, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Wollhutsindustrie (Munich, 1912); W.H. Dawson, Evolution of Modern Germany (London, 1908), 149 ff. ; Karl Keck, Arbeits- und Kulturmilieu der Arbeiterschaft in einem badischen Steinzeugwarenfabrik (Leipzig, 1911); J. Windolph, Z)er deutsche Protestantismus und die christlichen Gewerkschaften (Bonn, 1909), 128; Bromme, Lebensgang.
67. Heiss, Auslese,222.
68. Bromme, Lebensgang, 246; Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, 235 ff.; Abelsdorff, Beitràge; Arthur Shadwell, Industrial Efficiency (London, 1906), II; Rowntree, Land, 41149; Michael Marrus, 'Social Drinking in the Belle Epoque,' Journal of Social History (1973), 115-41.
69. Marrus, 'Drinking;' A. F. Dingle, 'Drink and Working Class Living Standards in Britain, 1870—1914,' Economic History Review (1972), 608 ff.
70. Bromme, Lebensgang, 112.
71. On declining drinking in Britain, Dingle, 'Drink;' Alan Fox, History of the National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives (Oxford, 1958).
72. Typographical Circular, 1 January 1894; H. Stanley Jevons, The British Coal Trade (London, 1915), 623 ff.; Williams, Derbyshire, 452 ff.; Bell, Works, 246; Williams, Life, 294 and passim; Royal Commission on Labour, Minutes of the Evidence, Group 'C (Textile, Clothing, Chemical, Building, and Miscellaneous Trades) (London, 1893, C 6894), III, 305; Stedman Jones, 'Culture,' passim.
73. Bell, Works, 246.
74. Duckerstoff, English, 67.
75. Jules Lekeu, A Travers le Centre: Croquis et moeurs: enquête ouvrière et industrielle (Brussels, 1907), 92; Dawson, Evolution,
149 ff.; Herkner, Problème; Schuman, Auslese, 106 ff.
76. Bell, Works; Watney and Little, Daily Round; Adolf Weber, Die Lohnbewegungen der Gewerkschaftsdemokratie (Bonn, 1914); Dawson, Evolution.
77. Harold Cox, éd., British Industry under Free Trade (London, 1903), 63.
78. Stearns, 'Women,' passim; Bell, Works. 19. Herkner, Problème; Zweig, Worker.
CHAPTER 9 PROTEST
Substantial changes in work plus the limitations in developing compensations off the job explain much of the tide of protest that developed after 1890, a protest that had important precedents in earlier decades but which assumed massive and regular proportions in this period. The protest did not necessarily stem from rising discontent. Earlier, more sporadic efforts such as Chartism were more far-reaching in their implications. The protest of this period resulted partly from the availability of regular leadership and organization; workers in earlier stages of industrialization might have done as much or more, had these been at hand, just as their counterparts in Russia and Italy were attempting in these very years. But protest in western Europe had much to do with the changing work experience, and without surveying protest movements in great detail we must ask what the links were.
Unfortunately, protest did- not develop in a predictably close relationship to problems on the job. While recognizing the extensive unrest of the period and the deep roots that protest organizations were taking within the working class, we must emerge with an impression of its tangential bearing on the work question. Put simply, protest did not directly convey the most basic complaints workers had about their jobs or the anguish that some of them felt at work. There were good reasons for this, which we will explore, but the gap between what might have been sought and what was sought remained potentially tragic.
To be sure, we know too little about the collective action most directly related to work, the effort to keep production down in order to protect both jobs and an appropriate rhythm on the job. This was not necessarily protest at all, in that it followed from a widely-shared view that there were appropriate limits to stress and to output. British craft unions, and more briefly the engineers, placed formal limits on output, persuading some foreman to ease the pace and fining certain members for speed-ups. Lancashire cotton workers on the piece rate worked under their capacity except before holidays, and as we have seen this was general in the mines. Parisian construction workers made a concerted effort to cut productivity by 25 percent during their peak years of agitation, between 1906 and 1908; by working according to all the rules of their craft they managed to waste a great deal of time.
Masons walked around ostensibly looking for aides to hire, while painters retouched every crack.1 Here was a way to protest modernity in a manner obviously appealing to the craftsman: one worker noted that with more skill and taste he would be 'like the artisan of former days,' while his employer lost money.2 German masons in the larger cities had secret agreements to limit production under the quotas accepted by their union; hence in Bremen workers actually laid 400 stones a day, though pledged in principle to 600. In general it is clear that, once again, artisans had the greatest success with this tactic. Workers in light industry came second, as from Germany even more than England came consistent reports from the shoe and textile factories of working under the optimal speed of the equipment available.3 Here, however, lack of energy, given poor diets, may have played as great a role as any conscious limitation.4 And workers in many branches of industry must have had some success with a voluntary or involuntary slow-down, for the reduction of hours of work alone cannot account for the hesitant rise in per capita productivity during the period.
But in most factory industry, and sometimes in the crafts, the slow-down had distinct limitations. Workers on piece rate might plan to restrict effort, but an adjustment in the rate could set them back, and those who wanted to improve their living standard might shun the tactic in the first place. In Germany workers of rural origin were also mentioned, somewhat questionably, as disliking to limit their work; urban workers were held to be less productive in the Monchen-Gladbach textile industry, for example, but this may have reflected the influx of skilled workers from smaller towns and an anti-urban bias among observers who thought that the city-born must be less fit. Workers with urban expectations were more likely to defy limitations, though rural workers might do so to accumulate funds for days they could take off altogether. Tighter methods of supervision obviously made a slow-down hazardous. And even the labor movement might get into the act. The Northumberland miners' union consistently warned its members that it was wrong to cut production, for successful collective bargaining with manufacturers in heavy industry depended on a pledge of regular output.5
Hence the slow-down approach, while widely accepted, often degenerated into individual challenges or small-group protest. In February 1914, an unauthorized strike occurred in Peterborough when a worker was dismissed for refusing to speed up his lathe. Nothing fancy, for the strike was lost and the union roundly criticized the
effort.6 But this situation occurred many times, in all factory industries and in all countries, producing a small strike only in a minority of cases. We move on the one hand toward a reminder of the individuals who left their jobs because they found the conditions unfair, and on the other toward outright protest. And concerning protest the general proposition once more : it was extremely difficult to mount direct attacks on some of the leading grievances on the job site.
It can readily be agreed that strikes and some trade union activities constituted the most direct means of protest against job grievances. There is evidence in France as well as Britain that many workers turned to political remedies in this period only when prevented from striking or taught that strikes were ineffective.7 While a comparable situation did not prevail widely in Belgium or Germany, given the chronological precedence of a mass socialist movement, here too strikes offer the most direct insight into the relationship between protest and Work.
We touch, obviously, on a vast problem. Working-class protest had many sources beyond the work situation and, in focusing on the narrower relationship to the job, we do not pretend a complete assessment. Strikes alone offer a host of problems of interpretation. Their goals, which constitute our principal concern, are difficult to interpret. Many strikes began on an intensely personal note, only to convert to a general issue such as wages, at which point the government or union statistician duly recorded the effort. The smaller strikes, particularly, could reflect an even more complicated link with the job. Hastily-called strikes not infrequently conveyed a mixture of anger and pleasure, because they followed from the irregular work patterns which many workers sought to perpetuate. A textile strike in Ghent was voted, in a tumultuous meeting, mainly by young workers who thought the walkout would be fun and wanted some free time for recreation. The effort was serious - focusing, appropriately, on a reduction of hours — but the atmosphere of celebration was important in itself. The same vacation air was noted in the massive Verviers strike and often elsewhere. Quite apart from victory or defeat, strikes might relieve tensions at work by restoring a sense of control over its rhythms — and thus inhibit more far-reaching goals and efforts.8
The statistical problems in the assessment of strikes are formidable enough. As in the materials used in previous chapters comparisons across national boundaries are particularly chancy; trends within countries, over time, and inter-industry comparisons are far sounder. British records did not cover one-day strikes or movements with less than ten workers, which magnifies the average strike size reported but
lowers the total of strikers. British statisticians, scrupulously honest, often could not determine the demand involved — hence percentages per demand often add up to less than one hundred. But they did insist in identifying only one demand, whereas German records listed multiple goals. Belgian records omitted political strikes, thus missing the two main efforts on the period; the Belgian strike rate is thus artificially low. Continental governments may also have underplayed goals such as union recognition, that had political overtones; the French and Belgian records seem wanting here. Germany was more honest, for government records and those provided by unions largely coincide on this point, and the unions admitted that most organizational goals really constituted the barest effort to keep union members from being dismissed. Britain, on the other hand, seemed bent on finding union recognition an issue wherever possible, doubtless because of the Board of Trade's desire to encourage responsible unionism as. part of collective bargaining. Hence the 1911 dockers' strike is listed as concerning union recognition, which it did but as a second issue — the first being a minimum wage. German union figures suggest that governments often minimized the defensive strike rate, finding far more wage raise demands than really existed; this seems quite likely. On the other hand, the union figures, apart from underreporting the strike total given the large number of strikes that did not involve union members, probably exaggerate goals directly relating to work conditions as opposed to efforts for or against individuals on the job, though this is a fuzzy distinction to which we must quickly return. The unions also claimed that the official figures understated strike successes, which is one reason that losses, rather than distinctions between wins and compromises, deserve most attention.9
Even the judgement of overall rates is complicated. A study of French strikes has claimed, plausibly enough, that the state missed about 10 percent of all efforts. The number of strikers is of more concern here, because the interest is not in the strike as protest form or political event but as a reflection of workers' intent. Here the figures utilized probably distort in the other direction, because they convey peak numbers rather than the average through the strike. The problem of lockouts is thorny. The word is ominous, but lockouts were often little different from strikes, in terms of issues involved; many strikes, for their part, were actually triggered by employers. German figures show that lockouts were artisanal more than industrial, though important in machine building. If included they would raise the average striker rate by 32 percent — making German figures more comparable
with English and French — and they would change the pattern of issues involved, particularly by heightening conflicts over pay cuts and reducing the percentage of efforts over wages and particularly hours — all in keeping with figures from the other Continental countries.1 ° Yet, apart from the obvious difficulty of assessing the numbers of workers who, though locked out, would not have wanted to strike over the issue involved, lockout figures cannot be amalgamated with those of strikes because they were not broken down in the same way by issue. This affects Belgium and Germany, where lockouts were common, more than Britain and especially France, where lockouts were more often informal or concealed. Comparison of rates across national boundaries is, finally, hampered by the different census bases. Britain, with its inflated statement of industrial groupings - the product of including management and often sales personnel — naturally emerges with an artificially low strike rate; but it is difficult to determine how much too low it is.
We cannot avoid a large dose of impressionism, though what follows is based in the first instance on the figures summarized in the appendix and summary tables. The focus on strike goals makes a feel for the purposes involved almost inevitable, but some large judgements are offered despite a shaky statistical base.
The strike data unanimously point to one vital set of conclusions: workers struck rarely over job conditions, at least in any explicit way; such strikes were comparatively unsophisticated;11 and relatedly such strikes tended to decrease with time. The first point is obvious enough. Nowhere did strikes over work conditions command more than a quarter of all strikers, and except for Belgium the figure was much lower; even in Germany, where the union statisticians disputed the government data, the rate was only 15 percent (Table I).
Normally also strikes over conditions were small (Belgium is again an exception); hence the strike rate was higher than the striker rate. As a general rule, smallstrikes suggest a lack of general support for the issue involved and are tactically unwise; strikers are intensely and intelligently aggrieved, but they are in early stages of a strike movement. This judgement, admittedly debatable, finds some confirmation in the industries most concerned with conditions in their strikes. Transport workers predominated, and the reason for the high incidence of strikes over conditions in Belgium is the large Antwerp dock strike over hiring methods and work rules. Here was the statistical reflection of concern over changes in work organization and the growing desire for more stable employment. These strikes also
Table I Demand Rate 1899-1917
% strikes per demand |
% strikers per demand |
|||||
France |
Germany |
Belgium |
Britain |
Germany |
Belgium |
|
Against Cut |
4.2 |
6.2 |
8.1 |
6.9 |
3.6 |
10.0 |
For Raise |
55.9 |
65.0 |
48.2 |
23.6 |
77.5 |
62.6 |
Total Wage |
63.0 |
71.2 |
56.3 |
58.5 |
84.1 |
72.6 |
Hours |
15.5 |
32.4 |
6.6 |
5.8 |
55.9 |
9.0 |
Personal Issues |
24.3 |
20.9 |
22.1 |
6.0 |
16.8 |
10.8 |
Conditions |
6.7 |
2.8 |
20.5 |
7.8 |
2.2 |
25.6 |
Union |
3.5 |
6.1 |
2.9 |
18.2 |
34.1 |
1.3 |
Strike Losses |
41.6 |
41.5 |
58.2 |
24.1 |
35.5 |
45.3 |
(1 |
907-1913) |
expressed the desire for dignity and freedom which impressionistic materials from dockers and sailors convey more dramatically. But in the factories and among artisans whose units of employment were becoming larger, strikes over conditions were rare. One can note concern among German printers and, according to the union figures, metal workers, that may convey tensions over larger work units and new equipment. Machine workers had relatively high rates of strikes over conditions — but only 9.2 percent of the strikers in this industry in Britain invoked such issues in their primary strike goal. Workers with relatively extensive industrial experience, in the more advanced industries, did not protest work conditions extensively.
Hence the rate of strikes over conditions tended to decline with time. Their focus might change, as in France where fines and work rules yielded in importance to protests against the introduction of the piece rate or other job problems. At any time the issue might bring new groups of workers into the strike arena, as with French automobile workers right before the War. But in France as a whole the issue peaked in 1906 and fell markedly thereafter. The same is true in Britain, where strikes over work conditions loomed much larger, even among transport workers, in the 1890s than after 1900. In the great wave of strikes that developed after 1909 the percentage of strikers invoking work conditions went down — even in engineering — though of course larger numbers were often involved. Even the most generous effort to find protests against work conditions in England, adding strikes against unskilled workers and systems of pay as well as work arrangements, finds a peak of 42 percent of all strikes in 1907 (and in the metals and machine industries of 68 percent in 1910 — and the rate of strikers was considerably lower).12 Generally strikes over conditions loomed largest in depression years, when the overall strike rate was low. Their importance is undeniable, particularly among the unskilled but also
Table II Industrial Variations in Leading Demands, 1899-1914: Percent above average national rate*
Britain Construction |
Mines |
Engineering |
Textiles |
Transport |
|
Against Pay Cut |
A B 9.9 |
6.1 |
9.9 |
||
Other Wage |
A B 9.6 |
19.0 |
|||
Hours |
A B |
||||
Work Conditions |
A B 1.8 |
2.2 |
1.4 |
5.5 |
|
Personal Issues |
A B |
5.0 |
23.3 |
||
Union |
A B |
||||
Strike Losses |
A B |
Germany Construction |
Mines |
Metals |
Machines |
Textiles |
Wood |
Printing |
||
Against Pay Cut |
A B |
2.7 |
2.7 |
2.9 |
1.0 |
|||
Other Wage |
A B |
5.4 2.5 |
9.4 16.5 |
1.6 |
||||
Hours |
A B |
37.4 35.0 |
11.6 |
|||||
Work Conditions |
A B |
.2 .8 |
.3 .2 |
.2 |
.1 .2 |
.7 2.1 |
2.5 7.0 |
|
Personal Issues |
A B |
3.1 |
7.6 2.0 |
6.7 1.6 |
4.4 16.9 |
|||
Union |
A B |
20.1 32.1 |
.2 |
.7 |
4.2 |
|||
Strike Losses |
A B |
26.5 57.6 |
5.0 |
4.4 10.6 |
13.0 5.0 |
3.5 |
||
* A Strikes B Strikers |
France Construction |
Mines |
Metals |
Textiles |
Transport |
Wood |
Paper, Print |
2.3 |
3.4 |
.1 |
||||
16.4 |
||||||
1.9 |
4.4 |
.3 |
1.5 |
20.6 |
||
6.9 |
1.0 |
.2 |
||||
6.4 |
13.5 |
5.6 |
||||
2.2 |
.7 |
2.0 |
||||
2.5 |
5.9 |
4.0 |
Belgium Construction |
Mines |
Metals |
Textiles |
Transport |
Wood |
Printing |
.5 |
2.6 |
3.0 |
||||
18.6 |
||||||
23.3 |
9.9 |
2.7 |
6.0 |
8.2 |
||
3.7 |
10.7 |
7.6 |
14.7 |
|||
17.9 |
4.3 |
2.2 |
||||
5.5 |
1.8 |
33.2 |
||||
13.1 |
6.5 |
|||||
6.3 |
22.8 |
1.3 |
||||
10.6 |
.7 |
.7 |
||||
.9 |
.1 |
5.9 |
||||
4.3 |
1.4 |
2.5 |
||||
8.2 |
||||||
5.5 |
among hard-pressed skilled groups such as the British engineers. Yet their relatively low overall incidence, their rarity in several industries where work systems were changing significantly, and their tendency to decline seem surprising in light of the problems that work seemed to be creating.
Several factors progressively deterred strikes over conditions. First, these strikes were among the hardest to win; employer resistance was much keener here than in issues of hours or wages, in almost every industry and area.13 With growing experience in the strike movement, then, workers would learn to avoid these issues in favor of wage demands. Often a transition was made during a strike itself. In 1899 the London plasterers' union struck to force foremen into their union and to limit apprenticeship. Worker sentiment ran high. But the strike simply could not be won, and the workers' insistence on some positive gain turned to a raise, which was granted.14 We can safely assume that far more strikers wanted to invoke job conditions than finally managed to do so, which is one reason that the strike movement inadequately conveyed work grievances. Yet a more permanent conversion to other kinds of issues can be traced in many cases, which accounts for the longer-term evolution of strike demands. Silesian miners often protested work conditions in the 1890s. They were just beginning to face the new production levels and impersonal management that were increasingly a part of modern industry. Their strikes lost, and after a period of readjustment in which protest of any sort was low they re-emerged with well-organized strikes for wages and hours gains right before the War.15 Relatedly, many workers were not overwhelmingly discontented with their work arrangements. The strike statistics tend to confirm the ambiguity about changes in technology and work systems that can be drawn from the direct study of work.
Yet obviously the problem does not end with this statement. The disparity between the laments of German workers about their job, which Adolf Levenstein recorded, and the low level of strikes suggests a real problem of translating grievances into strike goals, compounded obviously by the intense employer resistance. We can gain further insight into the disparity by examining another key category of strike demands, the protests for or against individuals. As we have seen, strikes against a hated foreman or director form an important part of the ongoing tensions on many job sites. Strikes against the dismissal of a worker for insufficient production were more common than protests against the work systems that sought to heighten production. The boundary line is not easy to draw, but the personal factor was
important. It reflected the small-group loyalty that remained important even in the larger factories. German workers displayed attachment to their colleagues even in their styles of dress, speaking often of Saalmoden, or styles of the workroom. Skilled workers often did not know their fellows with different skills or in other divisions of the plant, so a general issue over work conditions or employer policy would make little sense. But an affront to someone they knew might "bring them out quickly. Add the fact that some colleagues were also relatives and the persistence of the personal focus becomes still clearer, despite the fact that these strikes, too, were hard to win. Furthermore, the personal issue strike was common in most of those industries where work changes were particularly rapid. They were rare in the crafts usually, but higher in the industries making a transition to factory production and in the factory branches themselves. Hence in Germany they were common in leather and wood, as well as the factory-based machine tools and textiles industry. In Belgium they loomed largest in leather, wood, chemicals, and textiles; in France in metals, mining, and printing. British tailors, along with engineers and textile workers, fought often over personal issues.16
In Britain, to be sure, the personal issues strikes embrace a large number of demarcation disputes, which have quite properly been given considerable attention by British labor historians. Craft-like trade union organization and the existence of prior, well-defined fac tory skills can be invoked. The rising rate of personal issues strikes in textiles, for example, follows from the wide support won by an individual worker's refusal to do some cleaning of his carding machine, claiming that this was not properly the work of a grinder. The high rate of these strikes among construction workers is undeniably unusual. On the whole, however, British strikes in this category show many similarities to the Continental patterns. They were typically small, hard to win, and with the exceptions noted roughly equivalent in industrial incidence. Workers were often highly aroused over their personal relationships, sometimes to the detriment of their ability to act over more general work grievances. Perception of issues aside, the lack of sophistication of the personal strikes — reflected in their small average size and high failure rate — often blunted any general attack on job conditions.
Yet the strike goal persisted, far more steadily than strikes over work arrangements. If it declined a bit in Germany, it rose in France, Belgium and Britain. Here was a clear sign of the role this issue played in conveying tensions at work. At the same time the increased incidence was not massive. One cannot realistically translate the trends of
personal strikes into a statement of rising class consciousness, for example, quite apart from the obvious fact that these strikes were more often directed against fellow workers than anyone else. In France strikes against foremen rose slightly, but protests against other workers gained more ground. This was, on the whole, a rather steady-state issue, incapable of rousing wide support but difficult to translate into other kinds of demands. Against its utility in translating work grievances was the fact that most trade unions were increasingly hostile to the issue. The resultant strikes were too small, too spontaneous, too likely to abort, and too divisive, and except in some obvious demarcation disputes worker impulses clearly had to battle organizational imperatives.17 The result was a tenacious but numerically inadequate protest focus, another sign that rising tensions at work, where present, were finding inadequate expression in the strike movement.
If workers found it difficult to mount direct attacks on the quality of work itself, they were more successful in trying to win a reduction of work. The strike movement on the whole confirms the notion of an increasingly instrumental view of work, in which full pleasure in work was abandoned as unobtainable — at least by those workers who were aggrieved enough to strike at all - and better conditions off the job were sought in compensation. Strikes for a reduction of hours were consistently among the most highly sophisticated, as measured by their large average size and their generally good success rate. They had strong union backing, which both explains and reflects their tactical sophistication. They did not occur in some of the industries in which work tension was greatest, which raises a first warning signal about their role in alleviating job distress. They were not prominent in German textiles, for example, despite the frequent laments about overwork. Nor were they usually high in engineering. They loom large in mining generally, often in conjunction with legislation; hours strikes in British and Belgian mining around 1910 concerned more the implementation of shorter hours than the hours themselves, which explains why this was the only industry in which hours strikes clearly rose. Miners were, more than most others, concerned about limiting their work. Otherwise the groups most vigorously interested were those from a craft background, particularly printers and construction workers. This helps explain the high rate of hours strikes in Germany, for craftsmen played an unusually active role in strikes generally. Artisanal strikes reflect the new life style that was being forged, in which leisure played an important role. Artisans also had a long tradition of seeking shorter hours to counter unemployment, and this visibly continued.
Finally, workers as a whole did not show a desire, through strikes at least, to press hours down indefinitely. On the Continent strikes over hours of work peaked in 1905—6, as printers countered technological change and as construction workers, emerging from a long slump, tried to fight unemployment. Thereafter they normally declined as other issues took the fore. The pattern is clearer still in Britain, where strikes to reduce hours loomed large in the 1890s but dropped considerably thereafter. Three factors limited hours as an issue of consistent interest, despite trade union promptings in this direction: legislation could be seen as more effective than strikes, though strike success rates were good, save in Germany; the fear of loss of pay was a consistent inhibition; and after a certain level was reached, usually nine to ten hours outside the mines, the desire for further gains was limited, at least when measured against other goals and when rates of unemployment declined (an obvious factor in the waning British rate). Obviously this does not coincide with what some labor leaders said or with the fervor with which some workers embraced eight-hours campaigns; it does coincide with what most workers expressed through their strikes.
Without minimizing the importance of reduced houxs or the desire for further gains, it is clear that only two groups of workers would press heavily for a limitation of work, the artisans acting as much to protect their jobs as to reduce their job time. Some workers were not sufficiently disgruntled with their work even to think seriously about reducing hours. Others, perhaps troubled, had no clear use for more leisure time while a related group sought to maintain earnings. Protest again measures the ambiguity of reactions to the job itself.
If one adds up the strikes over work and related conditions and over hours, considering their evolution over time and their industrial incidence, it is impossible not to conclude that striking workers were generally either satisfied with their jobs per se, or convinced that direct protest was less effective or desirable than a quest for better wages, or incapable of translating the real grievances they felt into explicit strike goals. The fact that workers disagreed over such issues as the piece rate — outside the crafts — was itself a major factor in limiting the frequency and sophistication of strikes over work. Protest remained, as it had traditionally been for the lower classes, an expression of problems as consumers. Here was probably the most general reason for the apparent disparity between grievances and strikes. The form of protest had shifted, involving the work place more commonly than the merchant, but the cast of mind had not. The poverty of many workers explains the wage focus in large part, but the element of continuity
with the older protest tradition should not be minimized.18
And this frankly complicates the interpretation of the predominant strike goal. More and more workers were undoubtedly learning to compensate for tensions at work by seeking more money for use off the job, but it is doubtful that the most aggrieved workers were the leaders in the wage quest. Artisans had a consistently high incidence of wage strikes. Among woodworkers this might translate dissatisfaction with new methods and larger work units; among printers it undoubtedly served as a response to new machines; but among construction workers it was as much an expression of organizational power and the growing interest in a higher standard of living. Artisans, in sum, had only a partially instrumental view of work. They had learned to ask for higher wages, but not because they were necessarily discontented on the job. Miners, the other leader in the wage category, were more clearly expressing a sense that difficult work should be rewarded by rising pay, though more of their wage strikes in fact had a defensive element, culminating in the effort by British miners, in 1912, to establish a minimum wage floor against fluctuating conditions on the job. Factory workers were more restrained in their concern. Textile workers had an unusually high rate of defensive strikes, reflecting the fluctuating fortunes of their industry, while many of their pay rise demands were in fact conditioned by recent reductions due to crisis or poor materials. The general tendency for wage strikes to peak in the year immediately after a slump (1910 on the Continent, for example) suggests that the ability to demand positive increases was less marked than official statistics show; more often the effort was simply to regain what had been lost by a slump-induced reduction or by outright unemployment. None of this should belittle the massive importance of the wage strike. But factory workers, difficult to organize in comparison to artisans and miners, who had great advantages in protest tradition and, in the case of miners, residence, were not in large numbers able to translate work problems into wage gains. The halting development of new consumption goals (except among the artisans) fed and was fed by this limitation.
The need to use protest as consumers, rather than in specific response to the work situation, was massively heightened by the inflation after 1900. More workers were ready to embrace a rising living standard than were able to do so, once inflation hit; protest had increasingy to be reserved for defense of existing levels. Here was the main reason for the growing incidence of apparently offensive wage strikes. The great increase in German strikes by 1912—13 coincided
with a peak in wage demands (Table III). The comparable, though far more pronounced, British crest in the same years has been subject to more varied if somewhat inconclusive interpretation. Part of the attention has resulted from the shock the strike wave caused British political and business leaders, a significant topic in itself. Some analysis has suggested incipient rebellion, and has invoked rising class consciousness and challenges to traditional skill status. But causal explanations, where they can be pinned down, must rely on the inflation-caused pressure on real wages above all.19 And this is largely confirmed by actual strike demands. Wage demands were high in 1911 (particularly if the dockers' strike is given its due) and in 1913, and overwhelming in 1912. In clothing, engineering, mining, and in fact in transport offensive wage demands rose in rate as well as in the absolute number of strikers they motivated, compared to the previous decade.20 The case of France is more peculiar, for, as in Belgium if the political general strike is omitted, there is no pre-war crest in strikes. It has been argued that the stagnation is due to inflation, which workers found it difficult to combat, though there is considerable evidence that inflation peaked earlier and that its relaxation caused the stabilization of the strike rate; from a comparative standpoint this would certainly make sense.21 For workers were clearly driven by inflation, along with consumption problems they probably judged more normal — such as recurrent slumps — to an unprecedented defensive stand. Their defense was only barely successful, as real wages advanced but slightly in the period as a whole while the workers' share in national income declined markedly. What workers might have been prepared to do to defend job conditions, had this new problem not intervened, is difficult to say. The fact was that maintenance of living standards consumed most of their attention and that this fitted the long-standing protest tradition.22
The inflation did help teach new categories of workers to expect rising money wages — like the silk workers of Voiron who could, after some strikes for raises to keep pace with prices, invoke 'our normal rising wage' by 191323 — and in the long run may have encouraged an instrumental approach to problems at work, at least in orienting strike goals away from work itself. For the pre-war period, apart from the small groups of workers whose real wages did rise, the actual framework for wage strikes leaves us with the familiar dilemma. In defending their living standards workers were not clearly converting to the kind of rising expectations that would compensate for new pressures at work and were not able massively to protest these new pressures directly.
Correspondingly there is no general relationship between pressures
Table III Evolution of Strike Rate ( 1899: 100)
1899 |
1900 |
1901 |
1902 |
1903 |
1904 |
1905 |
1906 |
1907 |
1908 |
1909 |
1910 |
1911 |
1912 |
1913 |
||
France : |
Strikes |
100 |
108 |
71 |
74 |
78 |
119 |
106 |
176 |
151 |
129 |
141 |
172 |
171 |
139 |
129 |
Germany |
: Strikes |
100 |
111 |
82 |
82 |
107 |
145 |
187 |
258 |
176 |
105 |
119 |
164 |
199 |
195 |
165 |
Belgium: |
Strikes |
100 |
136 |
127 |
79 |
76 |
88 |
145 |
230 |
240 |
110 |
129 |
110 |
231 |
178 |
170 |
Britain: |
Strikers |
100 |
98 |
81 |
85 |
68 |
41 |
49 |
114 |
73 |
162 |
123 |
279 |
602 |
893 |
374 |
France: |
Strikers |
100 |
123 |
94 |
114 |
64 |
113 |
122 |
279 |
110 |
49 |
101 |
163 |
112 |
134 |
118 |
Germany |
: Strikers |
100 |
103 |
54 |
53 |
84 |
112 |
402 |
268 |
189 |
67 |
95 |
153 |
214 |
400 |
250 |
Belgium: |
Strikers |
100 |
136 |
127 |
79 |
76 |
88 |
145 |
230 |
240 |
110 |
129 |
110 |
231 |
178 |
170 |
on the job, as perceivable through complaints of individual workers or examination of work systems themselves, and the strike rate in the major industries. Miners everywhere led the way, with a slight lag in Germany because of the presence of more new workers and firmer employer resistance. The dangers they faced and the organizational advantages offered by the mining villages account for their lead more than any major change in the nature of work, though more difficult conditions at the pitface did play a role. After this statement, however, generalization becomes much more difficult (Table IV). Transport workers demonstrated considerable relative activity in France and Britain, far less in Belgium and Germany; the variation was due less to conditions of work than recency of rural origin and levels of competition for jobs, on the docks, and the constraints and attractions of state versus private service, on the rails. Construction workers were active in France and Germany, sluggish in Belgium and Britain. Again, the distinction has less to do with job situation than with the vigor of the industry, the heavy rural base of Belgian workers and the fact that British unions had gained, during the 1890s, many of the goals that their French and German counterparts were later striving for. Textile workers struck with some frequency in France and Britain, rarely in Belgium and Germany; here job conditions may have played some role, as French and particularly British firms were technologically more advanced, but nowhere were strikes particularly common. Chemical workers struck rarely, and only over wages, yet their industry was changing rapidly and variations relate mainly to pressures on pay levels (as in France where legislated hours reduction caused most of the big strikes over wages). The case of metals and machinery is more anomalous still. Nowhere did the industry offer a per capita strike rate much above the national average and generally it was far lower than this. Here workers new to the industry, with craft expectations, may have been more vigorous in their complaints, for the French and German rates are higher than those in Belgium and Britain where the industry was older and speculations about the disruptive effects of new methods more common.
Employer resistance played some role in variations in strike rates. Everywhere metal and machine workers suffered higher strike losses than most other groups, which would have deterred them from further efforts. Yet strike loss was not always such a deterrent, as in the case of German and Belgian mining or the British transport group. More important were factors of residence and tradition which have been cited already. The role of the cohesion of mining villages and their proximity
Table TV Industrial Strike Rates, 1899-1914
Britain |
France |
||||||||||
Construction |
Mines |
Engineering |
Textiles |
Transport |
Construction |
Mines |
Metals |
Textiles |
Transport |
Wood |
|
1. % of total strikers |
2.8 |
49.4 |
11.2 |
17.1 |
17.0 |
18.5 |
24.4 |
12.7 |
22.4 |
12.5 |
4.2 |
2. % in major industries last census date |
10.0 |
10.5 |
13.9 |
11.6 |
13.9 |
11.7 |
4.8 |
6.6 |
14.2 |
13.6 |
9.2 |
3. 1 / 2 |
.3 |
4.7 |
1.2 |
1.5 |
1.2 |
1.6 |
5.1 |
1.9 |
1.6 |
.9 |
.5 |
% of work force 4.striking annually (based on last census date) |
.7 |
11.8 |
1.9 |
3.7 |
3.0 |
4.0 |
13.0 |
3.0 |
4.1 |
4.1 |
1.0 |
Germany |
Belgium |
|||||||||||
Construction |
Mines |
Metals |
Machines |
Textiles |
Wood |
Construction |
Mines |
Metals |
Textiles |
Transport |
Wood |
|
1. % of total strikers |
21.6 |
26.3 |
6.6 |
10.0 |
5.2 |
6.1 |
2.3 |
51.9 |
5.3 |
14.9 |
10.5 |
1.9 |
2. % in major industries last census date |
17.8 |
7.3 |
19.1 |
9.7 |
6.4 |
10.5 |
9.0 |
7.5 |
15.4 |
10.8 |
7.9 |
|
3. 1 / 2 |
1.2 |
3.6 |
.9 |
.5 |
.9 |
.2 |
5.8 |
.7 |
1.0 |
1.0 |
.2 |
|
% of work force 4. striking annually (based on last census date) |
2.6 |
7.6 |
1.2 |
2.7 |
1.1 |
2.0 |
.4 |
11.1 |
.5 |
1.9 |
1.9 |
.1 |
Totals (category no. 4): Britain, 2.5; France, 2.7; Germany, 2.1; Belgium, 1.9.
to work has often been discussed, for miners continue to lead the list of workers with a high propensity to strike. Maritime workers were beginning to make their claim to second place. But many artisans were placed higher than they are on a contemporary list (where printers and construction workers, for example, are listed in the medium rank).24 Their position derives partly from the relative inactivity of factory workers, partly from the effort to establish new bargaining procedures to protect traditional job goals and gain new leisure and earnings for life off the job. Hence German printers had a high strike rate, though less pressed by new technology, while those in France and particularly Britain and Belgium, with collective agreements more firmly established, were already in the medium to low range. And artisanal tradition seems to have played a role in those cases where rates of striking in machine industry were high.
Collectively, factory workers fall below the concentrated urban crafts (though not, of course, more traditional sectors such as food processing) in their strike rate. They were often still new to each other and residentially scattered, but the low strike rate of many British factory workers is a warning against pressing novelty too far. To be sure, where job changing was frequent it went hand in hand with rapid fluctuations in union membership — still rising annually in the Ge rman metal workers' union in 1911, when 75 percent of all new members left the union and 44 percent of the total membership had joined only a year before.25 But even in more settled cases, such as British engineering, the strike rate remained far lower than the grievances about innovations on the job suggest. For factory workers generally, as indeed for much of the working class, strikes were not primarily weapons against changes at work. Strike patterns in most of the factory industries reflect job problems in the slightly increased incidence of strikes over conditions and, especially, personal issues, but if these were the tip of an iceberg they were too unsophisticated, too personalized, and too hard to win to bring much else to the surface. Strikes depended above all on the wage situation, and in wages many of the factory workers (in metals, though, more than in textiles) were comparatively well-off, in relation to their own past and to other groups of workers as well. Furthermore we must not minimize the extent to which factory workers had devised defenses against the worst problems on the job or found means of enduring if not enjoying innovations. When a mere 0.4 percent of all German strikes and lockouts occurred over resistance to overtime, for example, the impression that most workers either appreciated overtime or found means to avoid it grows stronger.
Overriding the issue of radically different strike rates is the fact that most workers did not strike at all in the fifteen years before World War I. Simple arithmetic shows that over 5 percent of the work-force had to strike annually, on the average, for even a bare majority to be involved. Coal miners met this criterion easily; their strike rate was higher than gross juxtaposition with census figures indicates, for the latter include other excavating workers as well. But no other group did. Big-city construction workers probably did, but not construction workers overall. It has been easy to neglect or belittle the mass of workers who did not engage in direct-action protest; they have received almost no historical attention. And their position is not related to work alone; religious interest, proximity to the land, even family problems could keep them out of action. Distinctive work situations could play a role, however. Bakers who found traditional dependence on their masters acceptable (if only because they expected to rise to the superior position themselves) or clothing workers spread out in the countryside and happy that they could avoid factory work saw no reason to strike; hence the obviously low strike rates in clothing and food processing. But it would be simplistic to pass the statistical problem off as the result of backward, if large, pockets of traditional production forms. What of the chemical workers or that 60-plus per cent of all machine builders or textile workers who did not strike?
We can advance a few descriptive categories to improve on the general statement that most workers did not strike. Regional cases abound, and not only in areas with scant industrialization. Alsation machine builders were not particularly interested in higher earnings; hence they did not produce more when the piece rate was introduced but by the same token did not resent the piece rate. Only 100 of 12,000 of them were unionized; even in Mulhouse unionization drew only 3 percent. These were unusually religious workers, but by no means atypical.26 Women workers form another identifiable category of workers reluctant to strike. For some, conditions and pay were improving as they were upgraded by the new technology, and this, along with the lack of commitment to manufacturing work as a permanent career, helps explain why many resisted even moderate trade unions. When they did strike, women responded to pay issues particularly, which helps account for the strike pattern in textiles. They were also sensitive to personal insults and nasty behavior on the part of supervisors — more than to general problems in the organization of work. Their strike activity was more volatile than men's, fluctuating almost 50 percent more from year to year; but even at their peak they
were only half as likely to strike as male workers — as in Germany where 13 percent of all strikers were women in 1910.37 Unionization rates were higher than strike rates among women, in relation to male levels, for unions could provide desired benefits other than protest support; in key industries such as shoemaking, bookbinding, and particularly tobacco and match manufacture a higher percentage of female than of male workers were organized on the Continent. But unions were often repugnant too. Even when aggrieved, many women resented the unions' reluctance to support them in their new battles for better pay or protection against new equipment. Women hat workers in Denton rejected a union organizing campaign in 1906, saying they preferred to deal with the employer and feared to 'lose our individuality' by joining the group.28 Older workers were normally more reluctant to strike than young. This was not true in the crafts, where strikes had a solid base. German union figures show that the percentage of strikers over thirty and the percentage married were actually higher than their levels in the work-force in wood, construction, and metals. But this was not the case in the mines or textiles. Indeed one of the reasons for the miners' high strike rate was the independent role that young workers, who as haulers were free from the supervision of adult workers, could take, in contrast to the more structured situation in textiles or machine building. Older workers were held back by the seniority they had acquired, their need for uninterrupted benefit programs, and their family responsibilities. Some, like the older miners in Mansfeld, were unusually resigned as well; the pessimistic culture toward aging could easily induce a feeling that nothing could change for the better.29
To explain differential strike rates and the much greater problem of non-striking, it is more useful to identify a few key types of workers, even without firm statistical precision, than to multiply fairly obvious descriptive categories. Some workers were held back from striking by repression. Others did not strike because they were satisfied, or had to strike only rarely to maintain their satisfaction. Still others might venture a strike but unsuccessfully, for they did not find organized protest relevant to their grievances at work. All of this, obviously, within a framework in which real wages, while not rising, were not falling much either and in which protest for most workers still depended on perceivable deterioration in consumption levels.
The satisfied workers were mainly skilled. They encompass many in the most traditional trades, such as the bakers already cited; neither radical (the French syndicalists) nor moderate unions could rouse many
of these workers. They include key skilled groups within the factories. Clickers in the shoe industry joined unions only reluctantly, when mechanization began to change their work conditions; but they still regarded themselves as an elite and in union meetings objected to frequent use of the word 'strike.'30 Smiths, in German metal and machine shops, were another stolid category, unusually stable and proud of their strength and skill. And while it is true that traditional sources of satisfaction were often being eroded, it would be wrong to expect quick or thorough conversion to a protest mood.
Shading off from non-protesters were groups who collectively were willing to strike but, after a period of adjustment on their part and their employers', simply did not need to very often. Here the printers and skilled construction workers serve as prime examples, but the pattern extends to brewers, many woodworkers, and to specific skill groups even in the larger factories. Generally the artisanal tradition was crucial to this pattern of adaptation. Some workers saw no need to strike at all. Small-town construction workers, like those described in Hastings by Robert Tressell, found the very notion that they should be aggrieved offensive to their dignity as men. The tenacious idea of the free-bom Englishman, could be applied against protest as well as for it. But relatively low strike rates among artisans must be explained in large part by increasingly successful collective bargaining; this is why strike rates tended to fall in this group. A strike wave might be essential to establish the principle of bargaining, as in France and Germany around 1906. But job dissatisfaction was not intense and various means apart from protest were developed to preserve key job conditions. To protect these means in turn, and to keep wages up, bargaining was more important than strikes. Between 1905 and 1910, for example, 65 percent more German wood-workers conducted peaceful movements for reduction of hours and increase in pay than went out on strike. Movements of this sort in the crafts were about four times as likely to win gains than a strike (though a few produced the lockouts that peppered the German crafts in the period). The same pattern can be seen among tailors, printers, metal workers in the smaller plants, and many others, in all the countries considered. In France increasing numbers of artisans dropped out of the strike arena because bargaining could take care of their demands. This helps explain not only the stabilized rate of strikes after 1910 but also increased strike losses and decreasing involvement of unionized workers in strikes. In Britain it was the craft workers who not only maintained but actually increased the rate of peaceful collective bargaining during the tense years of industrial strife right
before the War.31
Some traces of this adaptive pattern can be found in the factories as well. Collective bargaining existed in the French and British mines and textile plants, and in British metallurgy. But generally this was bargaining over wages and hours alone. It did not, as we have seen, have much to do with job conditions. British cotton workers' unions handled grievances over foremen and poor materials, but this was exceptional. French agreements, like the 1903 pact in Armentières, had only sketchy conciliation procedures, usually involving some remote outsider such as a city architect; conciliation involved little more than an arrangement to reconvene when an existing contract expired. Some groups complained specifically about the inadequacies of bargaining procedures applied to large industry; this was a major issue on the British rails. Others were not aware of their lack but keenly felt a powerlessness over job conditions — more, probably, than over wage levels where bargaining was more likely to be germane. We see the results of the disparity between bargaining and demands keenly in the mines, but why not, more commonly, in other industries?
There were satisfied workers in the factories too, and their impact should not be minimized. Special skills, the upgrading of many unskilled workers, the impact of paternalistic programs which sometimes included grievance procedures more effective than those won by unions in these industries — a host of factors could disincline workers from the admittedly risky and costly business of striking. Two other factors were involved as well, however, affecting many types of workers but particularly those in the larger units, which returns us to the sense that many — though by no means all — workers suffered from a gap between outlets for direct protest and grievances on the job.
Many workers could not strike because of employer repression. Despite high levels of grievance coal miners in isolated areas of southern France were blocked from striking after a few abortive efforts in the 1890s.32 Miners in Montceau-les-Mines who rebelled against the dictatorship of a company town in 1899 had to hold off from strikes thereafter, though they remained unionized and voted socialist. The thousands of French metallurgical workers blacklisted in the period were another group that might have struck again if freer from employer domination. In the countless other cases workers could never even try to strike because of employer surveillance; we can only guess at their number. But gross repression has severe limitations as a general explanation of non-striking. Coal miners who did strike faced most of the same employer barriers as metallurgists, which could, as we have
seen, lead to a high rate of strike defeat; but their protest rate was consistently elevated. We must assume that factors other than repression were operative, and this is partly confirmed by the low strike rate of metallurgists even where, as in Britain, employer resistance was modest. In a similar if less dramatic comparative case, it would be tempting to assume that far more British engineers wanted to strike than could, given their many complaints about work changes, but were blocked by the adamant resistance of employers which had already led to the successful lockout of 1897—8. But why then not develop a strike rate at least equal to that of German machine workers, whose employers were fully as hostile as the British? Repression is by no means irrelevant as an explanatory factor. It can in fact be elaborated if we turn from exclusive focus on the large manufacturers. Small masters or individual foremen could hold workers back more directly than often ineffective employer associations. Worker hierarchies played a major role as well. Older textile workers often prevented the unionization of their aides. Unskilled metallurgical workers were inhibited by job insecurity and the active hostility of the skilled group, so that low strike rates in this industry reflected a combination of employer repression, worker division and inter-group repression, and the positive satisfaction which most skilled workers gained from advancing technology and rising pay.
In addition to satisfaction and repression, the irrelevance of protest organization to many workers' grievances must be added in explaining the low strike rate. This was a theme echoed by female and male workers alike. Mechanics in the Paris region, quite ready to criticize factory conditions, refused to join the union, for they wanted no additional discipline and hoped to do as they pleased at least off the job. A British railway worker put the thought directly: unions 'take away manhood and bind us rigidly down.'33 Some workers tried to strike without unions, particularly in France where radical syndicalist rhetoric added to the fears; only 73 percent of all French strikes had any union members involved at all. A significant though smaller minority of German strikes were conducted on the same basis, and many factory workers joined unions just briefly for the strike itself; in German textiles, machines, and mining an average of 47 percent of unionized strikers had been members for less than six months (compared to 17 percent in the craft industries, for the years 1901—14).34 Predictably, however, strikes without unions were doomed to high rates of failure, so the widespread tension between the constraints of organization and many workers' protest goals more
commonly inhibited any collective action.
For the fact was that trade unions, almost regardless of ideological stripe, were forced to a number of policies that conflicted with the gut reactions of workers on the job, and this was an important element in low strike rates and the common dissociation of strikes from work conditions. For the same reason many workers stayed away from unions as well or jumped in and out as their mood dictated'. Unions were or became committed to bargaining, careful strike tactics, and to basic principles of industrial labor such as regularity of work. They inevitably came into conflict with many of the individual and small-group protest impulses of some of those who were most aggrieved about their jobs. Constantly the unions criticized the high expectations that inspired a few workers to strike: 'A frequent error is to confuse the desirable with the possible' and to 'expect complete salvation from a strike alone.'35 Many unions sought to ban strikes over dismissal of a single worker, thus opposing one of the most common reactions to job problems. Several British unions fined workers who were frequently absent, judging this the counterpart of employer willingness to bargain on wages.36 French unions were only a bit less formal in this regard, as the textile organization suggested: 'We cannot urge our comrades too strongly not to break contracts by sudden movements or individual gestures when the union's honor is involved.'37 Unions were consistently more conciliatory than workers over the adoption of new equipment. The British pattern-makers' group refused to back workers fighting the introduction of a new surfacing machine. French glass workers were told that mechanization was inevitable and not to be opposed, even though it would curtail employment. Against worker complaints the Amalgamated Society of Engineers allowed frequent exceptions to the rule 'one man, one machine.'38 Small wonder that many British industrialists preferred to hire unionized workers wherever possible, while German machine manufacturers, though more reticent in outright acceptance of any sharing of their decision-making power, increasingly discussed the impact of changes in techniques with the unions.39
What the unions did not and perhaps could not do, due to their need to avoid too-frequent strikes and win the strikes they conducted in order to retain members, was develop a serious program of demands relating to conditions on the job. They were vital to the working class, as rising membership levels attest, but mainly on the wage front. They reconciled the divisions among workers over the work experience by ignoring them as much as possible, through the universal solvent of
wage demands and related benefits. Their policies, combined with the growing bureaucratization, to which many workers were keenly sensitive, could backfire. In Germany, as in England, the rising strike rate of the pre-war years had something to do with the disparity between union efforts and job changes, though inflation was the more general trigger. The British railway union found its members increasingly hard to control, while restiveness in the Welsh mines and among German shipbuilding workers was partly directed against labor leadership.40 A German worker voiced the general complaint: 'What use is it for us to pay our dues but have nothing to say; pay and work time are set from above.'41 Yet even these criticisms veiled the real tragedy. Workers could see that many aspects of their jobs had escaped their control. They might talk, as British railway workers did, of the inadequacy of grievance procedures and certainly of the excessive centralization of unions themselves. And it is possible, as historians have noted, to see the changes in work organization and challenges to traditional factory skills as a vital backdrop to the rising crest of strikes. But as a backdrop only ; strike demands were little changed, save as they concentrated with increasing ferocity on the wage issue. British textile and railway workers produced a few unprecedentedly large strikes over personal issues, but nowhere was there a new statement, in strike demands, of solutions for job problems. Even the workers who raised questions about union policies could not avoid acceptance of slightly-revised collective bargaining procedures, while transport workers everywhere, and miners in Germany, continued to fight for acceptance of the unions just as bargaining agents for wages.42
For a variety of reasons, then, including workers' own internal divisions, the importance of other issues, employer resistance patterns, and the impulses of labor leadership, a period that could have seen the development of durable guidelines for defending job satisfaction did not do so. Efforts at qualifying the employers' decision-making power were significant, and here the unions played a vital role. The beginnings of the shop-stewards' movement revealed considerable concern in several industries.43 But this left the nature of work untouched except in individual factories, not a matter of general bargaining. One cannot escape the conclusion that workers as a whole were not sufficiently aggrieved about their jobs, at least in relation to other problems, to mount a major direct protest. This left those workers who were concerned tragically bereft of support. It deprived the labor movement of a potentially explosive issue, far more likely to rouse revolutionary ardor than wage demands or even many union recognition issues,
because it might call the principles of industrial operation into question. Just as important it set a rather durable tone for the labor movement itself, in which individual job grievances might be handled but at the wider level the nature of work largely ignored in favor of pressure over wages and benefits off the job.
Strikes and unions do not form the whole protest story, of course. The socialist movement may have had a more direct relationship to work grievances than the incidence of strikes and strike demands. Socialist voting was less constrained by repression and less qualified, because of the periodic nature of politics, by the desire of many workers to avoid further organizational control. One could be a firm individualist but still usually vote socialist come election day. Rising levels of socialist voting could easily reflect rising concern about the quality of work, though of course many other issues were involved. Very impressionistic evidence suggests that the nature of socialist voting may have varied with the quality of work plus the availability of other relevant protest outlets. We would need precise correlations of voting levels with types of workers to advance this hypothesis firmly, and these may never be obtainable. There is certainly ample evidence that workers with strong unions and an abundant strike outlet were less likely than others to vote socialist or at least to see socialism as anything but an adjunct to bargaining efforts. Hence socialism was relatively weak in the French mines and of course in many British industries, while somewhat stronger in the German mines. The majority of Belgian miners were firmly socialist — rural migrants excepted — but their vision of socialist triumph, as expressed to journalists during the 1913 general strike, often consisted mainly of higher wages and shorter hours rather than a real revamping of the social structure. Textile workers, at the other extreme, were outside of Britain likely to be particularly fervent socialists, with the obvious exception that domestic manufacturers were rarely attracted at all. Guesdist doctrine in France caught on most firmly among textile workers in factories in the Nord and other centers such as Roanne; 24 percent of the party membership consisted of textile workers, well above its share in the industrial population. German textiles provide a similar impression: more than miners or metal workers they talked to Levenstein of their hopes for a future society, which predominated over any desire to earn more money. These were workers quite likely to be discontented with their jobs, without strong unions and without a clearly instrumental view of work in which striving for higher pay might serve as a compensation. In contrast socialism among most metal workers and artisans, though quite
probably more significant numerically, was taken somewhat less serioussly as a panacea for problems on the job. Many artisans embraced socialism while hoping for their own bicycle repair shop; this ambivaalence may account, in France, for their slighter percentage role among; party membership. Metal workers talked of the desirability of socialist victory in qualifying the employers' control over job conditions:, but spoke also of the irrelevance of much socialist doctrine and the inevitability of a social hierarchy; this had something to do with their own relatively high job satisfaction and their desire and ability to command a rising wage. Straws in the wind, to be sure, but the possibility of significant correlation between the intentions behind a socialist commitment and conditions on the job remains high.44
What did a fervent socialist commitment do for the admittedly uncoumtable number of workers profoundly alienated from their jobs? In Germany the miner Max Lotz - he who found himself so different from most of his fellows — gives us one suggestion. He hated his work, finding; it increasingly degrading, and he specifically renounced the notion that any wage could compensate for its horrors. 'Therefore I depend with all my being on the courage and idealism of socialism.'4 5 A metal worker expressed a similar sentiment, when he said that socialism 'made a man' of him, sustaining him whenever he felt sad.46 These 'were people who thought of socialism on the job and oriented their whole lives around the movement. Here, then, from a prosaic standpoint, was another way of getting through life. Yet again, without challenging the vital importance of socialism, we can ask about the implications for work. These were people whose commitment actually turned them away from specific suggestions about the job; they really gave up any hope of pleasure in work for the present. It diverted them also from instrumental demands, where job grievances could be translated into wage goals, and this may explain yet another group of workerss unlikely to strike in several industries and countries. The point was to wait for the future. From a larger vantage point it has already been noted for German socialism, and could be for Belgian as well, that the network of socialist organizations, by filling the spare time of the most fervent socialists, distracted from direct-action protest, and particularly from protest relating to work. Finally, for those who were deeply involved in socialist activities, the socialist impulse, like the union impulse, directed attention to the virtues of good work, discipline, and sobriety and may thus have contributed to the creation of a more assiduous work force.4 7
The labor movement in most of its aspects — politics, organization,
and direct action — neither reflected nor promoted a massive, coherent demand for basic changes on the job. Had the socialist vision triumphed real reforms would have resulted; the workers' councils movements that burgeoned right after World War I showed that the desire for new controls within industry had only increased. Even before the War the significance of the labor movement for many aspects of working-class life and its profound, increasingly upsetting impact on the ruling class need no qualification here. But from the standpoint of work itself, the clearest common denominator of the working class, there was a missed opportunity. Their organizational imperatives and, often, their middle-class training left many labor leaders incapable of understanding the job reactions of many aggrieved workers, while the latter were incapable of a very clear expression on their own account. The result was not, in the pre-war period itself, a révolution manquée. Enough workers were satisfied with their jobs or capable of translating grievances into improvements in life off the job to blunt any job-based revolutionary effort. A minority was not being served, and this may have some bearing on the general minority-majority split within the labor movement that became increasingly visible as the War approached. Of more durable significance is the fact that the failure to develop a protest culture directed at work itself left a dubious legacy for the future. The labor movement was at this period in a formative stage and changes in jobs were extremely significant. For many decades the labor movement would find it difficult to raise issues relating directly to life at work, and their silence pushed their constituents toward interests in wages or even job control that could easily let the quality of work itself slide. This could weaken the response of organized labor when job dissatisfactions did find expression, a problem apparently reviving in the 1970s. Still more important, it could encourage many workers to spend almost half their waking hours as adults in an endeavour which they found joyless and, still worse, expected to remain joyless and beyond control. Even for the workers less profoundly alienated and for those to whom the gains of the labor movement brought real satisfaction, the absence of a protest culture that could deal directly with job change could prove an ongoing disability.
Notes
1. David F. Schloss, Methods of Industrial Remuneration (London, 1894), 412; Ernst Bernhard, 'Auslese und Anpassung der
Arb«iterschaft,' Jahrbuch fur Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung, und Volfawirtschaft im Deutschen Reich (1911), 1405; Musée social: Annales (1908), 239; Raymond Joran, L'Organisation syndicale dans l'industrie des bâtiments (Paris, 1914), 108—9.
2. Le Travailleur du bâtiment, July 15, 1912.
3. B. Quantz, 'Ùber die Arbeitsleistung und das Verhâltnis von Arbeitslohn und Arbeitszeit im Maurergewerbe,' Jahrbùcher fur Natïonalôkonomie (1912), 647.
4. Edrnund Grôllich, Die Baumwollweberei der sàchsichen Ober-lausitz (Leipzig, 1911), 131; 'System Ca'canny in der deutschen Schuhwarenindustrie,' Zeitschrift fur Sozialwissenschaft (1909), 555.
5. Bernhard, 'Auslese,' 1405; Miners' Federation of Great Britain, Special Conference (Manchester, 1914), III, 29.
6. Amalgamated Society of Engineers, Monthly Report, February 1914.
7. Leo Loubère, 'Coal Miners, Labor Relations, and Politics in the Lower Languedoc,' Journal of Social History (1968), passim; Harvey Mitchell and Peter N. Stearns, Workers and Protest (Itasca, 111, 1971), passim.
8. G. C. Ruther, 'A Propos d'une interpellation de M. Anseele sur la grève cotonnière gantoise,' Revue sociale catholique (1905—6), 65—8; Laurent Dechesne, L'Avènement du régime syndical à Verviers (Paris, 1908).
9. See A'ppendix: the five sources for strike statistics utilized are: 'Tabellen zur Statistik der Lohnbewegungen, Streiks, und Aus-sperrungen,' Generalkommission der deutschen Gewerkschaften, Correspondenzblatt, 1904—14; Ministère de l'industrie et du travail, Les Grèves et lock-outs en Belgique, 1899—1910, 3v. (Brussels, 1904-1912), continued in Revue du travail, 1911 — 14; Direction du travail, Statistique des grèves et recours à conciliation, 1899—1914; Board of Trade, Labour Correspondent (later Labour Department), Report of the Strikes and Lockouts, 1889-1914; Statistik des deutschen Reichs, Neue Folge 178, 259, 269; see also 278, p.27.
10. Appendix, Table X.
11. On assessing strike 'sophistication,' admittedly a risky endeavor, see Peter N. Stearns, 'Measuring the Evolution of Strike Movements,' International Review of Social History (1974), 1—27; Charles Tilly and Edward Shorter, 'The Shape of Strikes in France,' Comparative Studies in Society and History (1971), 60-86.
12. A. L. Levine, Industrial Retardation in Britain (London, 1967), passim.
13. Appendix, Tables VI, IX, XII, XVI.
14. Onlooker (A. H. Telling), Hitherto (London, 1930), 55.
15. Lawrence Schofer, 'Patterns of Worker Protest: Upper Silesea, 1865-1914,' Journal of Social History (1972), 447-63.
16. Heinrich Herkner, Problème der Arbeiterpsychologie (Leipzig, 1913), 136 ff.; Leo Uhen, Gruppenbewusstsein und informelle Gruppenbildungen bei deutschen Arbeitern im Jahrhundert der Industrialisierung (Berlin, 1963); Paul Gôhre, Drei Monate Fabrik-arbeiter (Leipzig, 1913).
17. Peter N. Stearns, Revolutionary Syndicalism and French Labor (New Brunswick, 1971), passim.
18. George Rude, The Crowd in History (New York, 1964); Stearns, 'Measuring,' passim.
19. George Dangerfield, The Strange Death of Liberal England (New York, 1961), 214 ff.; E. H. Phelps Brown, Growth of British Industrial Relations (London, 1959), passim; Standish Meacham, ' "The Sense of an Impending Clash": English Working-Class Unrest before the First World War,' American Historical Review (1972), 1343—64. Two statistical points must be added to the British conundrum. If cross-national per capita comparisons even approximate reality, the British post-1909 rate, when amalgamated with the exceptionally low 1899—1909 rate, was largely a catch-up operation. And this rate, for groups like miners and transport workers, more definitely merely heightened 1890s rates in Britain, which means that the main interpretive problem is not post-1909 but 1899-1909. All of which reduces, perhaps, the revolutionary impact of post-1909, save possibly on a nervous British government. See Appendix, Tables I, II.
20. Appendix, Tables I, III.
21. Stearns, Syndicalism, Appendix I; M. Perrot, 'Grèves, grévistes, et conjoncture; vieux problème, travaux neufs,' Mouvement social (1968), 109-24.
22. Ashok Desai, Real Wages in Germany (Oxford, 1968); A. L. Bowley, Wages and Income in the United Kingdom since I860 (Cambridge, 1937); Jean Bouvier, François Furet, and Marcel Gillet, Le Mouvement du profit en France au XIXe siècle (Paris, 1965).
23. Archives Nationales (France) F713868, report on Milhau glove workers.
24. Clark Kerr and Abraham Siegel, 'The Interindustry Propensity to Strike/ in A. Kornhaus et al., eds., Patterns of Industrial Conflict (New York, 1954), 190 ff. One recent study does claim that artisans, inside as well as outside of factories, led in pre-1914 strikes and that their strikes had a high job-issue content. French ribbon weavers thus struck a bit more intensely than cotton spinners, and invoked job issues three times as often. But the comparison does not hold overall. Even in textiles craft groups like cloth printers struck no more over job issues than spinners did; factory weavers, hardly artisans, struck more often than craft groups. The distinctions may work better in metals, where small-shop smiths and moulders outstripped less threatened groups like factory mechanics and electricians, but again, without produc-
ing a high overall rate of job-issue strikes in the industry. Work is relevant to strikes, in other words, but not decisively so. The same study finds the primary correlations with strikes up to 1914 in trends of prices, wages, and the like, so that while some conclusions differ those judgements of the present book and those of Edward Shorter and Charles Tilly that bear on specific groups of workers, especially for this pre-World War I period, might be deemed largely congruent. Edward Shorter and Charles Tilly, Strikes in France, 1830-1968 (Cambridge, 1974), passim.
25. Der Deutsche Metallarbeiter-Verband, Jahr- und Handbuch fur Verbandsmitgleider (1911) (Stuttgart, 1912).
26. Otto Bosselman, Die Entlôhnungsmethoden in der sudwest-deutschluxenburgischen Eisenindustrie (Berlin, 1906); Otto Hommer, Die Entwicklung und Tàtigkeit des deutschen Metall-arbeiterverbandes (Berlin, 1912).
27. Lilly Hanff, Die deutschen Arbeiterinnen-Organisationen (Halle, 1912), passim.
28. Barbara Drake, Women in Trade Unions (London, 193 H, 30.
29. Anon., Aus Manfelds Ehrentagen (Halle a.S., 1910), 11 ff.
30. Alan Fox, A History of the National Union of Boot and Shoe Operatives (Oxford, 1958), 136.
31. Robert Tressell, The Ragged-Trousered Philanthropists (London, 1955); Deutscher Holzarbeiter-Verband, Jahrbuch, 1906 ff.; Hommer, Entwicklung; Metallarbeiter-Zeitung, 1911; Stearns, Syndicalism, passim; K. G. J. C. Knowles, Strikes - A Study in Industrial Conflict (Oxford, 1948); Meacham, 'Sense,' 1348 ff.
32. Loubère, 'Miners,' passim.
33. G. W. Alcock, Fifty Years of Railway Trade-unionism (London, 1922), 435; see also Union corporative des ouvriers mécaniciens de la Seine, Brochure de propagande (Paris, 1908), 9.
34. 'Tabellen' in Generalkommission der deutschen Gewerkschaften, Correspondenzblatt, 1904 ff.
35. Deutscher Holzarbeiter-Verband, Handbuch fur die Ver-bandsfunktionàre (Stuttgart, 1908), 164-5.
36. United Society of Boilermakers, Monthly Report, 1890.
37. L'Ouvrier textile, March 1908.
38. W. Mosses, The History of the United Pattern Makers' Association (London, 1922); Amédée Dunois, 'Mouvement ouvrier: chez les verriers,' Pages libres (1908), 718; Harold Cox, éd., British Industry under Free Trade (London, 1903), 44.
39. Ian Sharp, Industrial Conciliation and Arbitration in Great Britain (London, 1950), 53; Dora Lande, Die Arbeits und Lohn-verhàltnisse in der Berliner Maschinenindustrie zu Beginn des 20. Jahrhunderts (Leipzig, 1910).
40. G. C. Halverson, The Development of Labour Relations in the British Railways since 1860 (Ph.D. Thesis, University of London, 1952); Jakob Heinen, 'Die Organisationsform der Gewerkschaften,' Die Neue Zeit (1913-14), 546-48.
41. Philipp A. Roller, Das Massen- und Fuhrer-Pro blem in der Freien Gewerkschaften (Tubingen, 1920), 89.
42. On the incidence of strikes over union issues see Table III and Appendix; Meacham, 'Sense,' 1348 ff.
43. Branko Pribicevic, The Shop Stewards Movement and Workers' Control (Oxford, 1959).
44. Claude Willard, Les Guesdistes (Paris, 1965), passim; Adolf Levenstein, Die Arbeiterfrage (Munich, 1913), 235 and passim; Gôhre, Fabrikarbeiter, passim; Fritz Schumann, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Automobilindustrie (Leipzig, 1911).
45. Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, 69; see also Adolf Levenstein, Aus der Tiefe, Arbeiterbriefe (Berlin, 1908), passim.
46. Levenstein, Arbeiterfrage, 317.
47. Guenther Roth, The Social Democrats in Imperial Germany (Totowa, N. J., 1963), passim.
Part IV TOWARDS THE FUTURE OF THE WORKING CLASS
CHAPTER 10 CONCLUSION
It might seem tempting to end this study with some judgements relevant to more conventional historical issues, even the themes of standard labor or period history: and thus we see why the working class so widely supported their countries' entry into World War I. Save in a negative sense, however, the study of work has little immediate political bearing. The extent and diversity of adaptations to work help explain the essential moderation of the labor movement in the period —a marked contrast to the greater radicalism of workers in earlier industrial settings such as Italy and Russia. It can be argued, too, that the boredom which many young workers felt on the job enhanced their interest in military excitement — for some German socialists reported their period of military service as the most interesting period of their lives, while many British workers had already been roused by the appeal of the Boer War.1 But for the most part the world of work and the world of great events kept some distance apart. Hence, while not advocating a Trevelyanesque definition of social history for all practitioners, the present study cannot claim to unravel many political mysteries.
It does qualify some judgements that have been made about the period. For workers as a whole the idea of a widespread collapse of skills, which has been applied particularly to England, can easily be exaggerated.2 Key groups were challenged; there was a more widespread sense of threat. But skill was still a real factor and belief in it remained common among workers themselves. Many were able to develop some direct measures of defense. In this regard it was true that a wedge was being driven within the labor aristocracy, as craft mentalities, still so successful in construction or even printing, proved inapplicable in more and more machine shops. But even in engineering skilled jobs expanded. And the intergenerational nature of change proved an important buffer for many workers. Correspondingly, new technology was not so great a shock as might be imagined. Stagnant productivity rates in several key industries suggest the success of many measures of self-defense, while important groups of workers were able to appreciate some benefits from new machines. Tension there was, but facile concepts of an overturning of the working-class status hierarchy
or a dehumanizing technology are out of place.
Other developments that might have caused massive problems did not seem to, at least on the job site. Business rationalization, most notably, whatever its role in an increasingly class-conscious politics, did not uniformly or predictably poison relationships on the job. The cushioning of the personal contact between worker and immediate supervisor, which could lead to some contentment or to a clash of personalities that distracted from larger issues; the continued success of paternalism; and the fact that some aspects of big business were actually preferable to the personal dependence characteristic of smaller industry all help explain workers' reactions. The possibility of individual relief should not be minimized either. Some workers could and did move. Job choice led some into small units in the first place, while other workers, less concerned about the personal factor and more interested in higher pay, would go into larger firms.3 How much the rise of socialism resulted from class tensions that big business exacerbated cannot be determined; we have suggested that there was no complete correlation in this period, but a relationship need not be denied. On-the-job complaints about cheating, so common in many of the piece rate industries, reflect widespread distrust, though not necessarily greater in rationalized units than in firms where personal dependence remained strong. An issue existed, without doubt, and the struggles for new forms of control, for a share in decision-making — so generally abortive outside the urban crafts — put it into sharp relief. It simply was not as consistent or overwhelming as might be expected from generalizations about the rise of big business. Thanks again to continuing diversity within industry and to the factor of inter-generational change, which overshadowed direct displacement, we can understand how some positive adaptation to new buiness forms occurred. Again we can see analogies with the contemporary working class, in which complaints against management tend to increase slightly with the size of the company, but where certain kinds of resentments, as against the status-consciousness of individual supervisors, swell in the smaller units.4
The period has often been seen as one in which workers' mobility declined.5 It certainly was more difficult to expect to rise to small proprietorship, though by no means impossible in some industries. We can see an important gap between expectations and reality in this situation. Young skilled workers in Germany talked often of wanting 'to run a small business on my own,' in the interests of independence.6 This was the most common single goal of Berlin mechanics inter-
viewed — though the majority, not thinking in terms, of life purposes, did not respond at all. But the second most common goal was to rise to become a foreman, and this remained realistic for some. Craft expectations of mobility were certainly being challenged by the stagnation of small business units, and in certain sectors there was a serious possibility of downward mobility. Nineteen percent of all skilled construction workers in Bochum traced between 1880 and 1901, for example, had fallen into the unskilled ranks, while among some of the skilled factory and craft workers, more had moved down than up (though a plurality in each case stayed at the same skill level).7 But many artisans could compensate for this pressure, and there was significant movement into white-collar ranks. Skilled Carmaux glass workers, distressed by skill displacement, almost uniformly sent their sons into clerical jobs. German printers who feared that mechanization, by increasing specialization, reduced their chances for independence often sent their sons into higher posts; in one study 22 percent of all sons of relevant age were in secondary school, while of those with jobs 40 percent were craftsmen (mostly not printers), 39 percent in retailing, and 21 percent white collar workers.8 The whole rise of the white collar labor force, so close to artisans in many values, makes too much stress on declining mobility questionable. Again, with a bit of adaptation, relevant channels were open.9
For most factory workers this kind of mobility was less important than the promotion chain within the industry itself. There was the undeniable possibility of disappointed expectations. In Germany the desire to become an artisan outstripped the possibility, as we have seen. In a Mônchen-Gladbach textile plant about half of all workers professed satisfaction with their career; of the rest about a third had hoped to enter a higher profession, while most of the rest wanted a craft job. This is a serious disparity, though we have suggested the tentativeness of such expectations in working-class culture. There were direct complaints in some industries that more modest advancement was being blocked. A key grievance on the British railroads against the rising pace of work was that promotion opportunities were being limited.10 Many workers felt cheated when foremen were brought in from the outside, which probably occurred with growing regularity as part of business rationalization. But a chain of advancement continued to exist in most factory industries. A miner, engineer, or textile or railroad worker could normally expect some movement in his own career. The chances for his sons were even better. Upward movement occurred for well over half the sons and grandsons of unskilled workers at Krupp; it had
occurred for all sons of employment age at Daimler. In Bochum 27 percent of all miners' sons had moved up in skill, while another 19 percent were non-manual workers. The possibility of advancing to semi-skilled status or even to gain real skills in new branches such as the ferroconcrete industry gave opportunities for a host of previously unskilled people.11 A clear judgement on mobility trends is not yet possible. Many workers did not want mobility in the modern sense. In Germany as in England a belief in stability was widespread; many Bochum workers wanted 'to take care that our children think just as we do and that they also in the future become loyal and diligent workers.'12 So mobility limitations were not always of great concern. But it is hard, on the basis of the impressions now available, to quarrel with the judgement of a British statistician, who claimed that aggregate wages rose between 1900 and 1910 less because of rate changes than because of the shifting of younger workers into better-paying jobs with greater skill involved.13 Certainly the idea of a great new mobility crisis, given the diverse expectations present as well as continued industrial growth, seems misplaced.
In terms of available conventional wisdom about the period's labor history, these judgements may seem surprising, even offensive, in a field where politics so often plays an important role. In fact, a study of the work experience has a number of radical implications, though they cannot be simply translated into political hopes or predictions. The specific correctives to the common impressions stem from three basic perceptions which seem to be inescapable. The expectations of many workers were limited and cannot usefully be judged according to middle-class acquisitive standards or the criteria of an abstract economic man. Workers were not powerless in mature industrial society; they could influence their lot though not control its foundation. Finally, the diversity of the whole working class, and the fact that the majority refrained from significant protest, necessitate conclusions different from those of a more selective approach that focuses on vocal elements alone.
There is a school of thought which holds that workers are ready to ask for anything any time economic and other conditions permit. Without minimizing the role of repression and serious economic limitations, including significant unemployment levels, I do not find this approach applicable to the whole working class in this period, particularly in its collective actions. Wage demands were often restrained, particularly because the individuals most concerned found their own ways to adapt earnings to work, as in using the piece rate to
increase their pay. Satisfaction with job security could have calmed some workers, as unemployment declined; this obviously played a role in the extension of collective bargaining, in lieu of frequent strikes, in the crafts. Other workers, to be sure, seized the same opportunity to develop new forms of agitation. But the theme of restraint, at least partially self-imposed, runs through the list of possible protest goads, from pensions to hours of work to mobility.
The idea that workers played an active role in adjusting to industrial life is not novel. Eric Hobsbawm's essay on the conversion to a market view of work suggests it, and a number of American studies on a slightly earlier industrial period, stressing the satisfactions some could find in property ownership or simply the preservation of the family, hit the same theme.14 But the idea has not been directly applied to mature industrial society, and in general historians too often continue to see workers as passive creatures, uninteresting save when they rebel against industrial capitalism. The American essays also frequently draw a contrast with Europe because of the greater political radicalism there — a rather dubious, certainly unexamined, compaxison when the larger working-class experience is considered, for European workers had similar adaptive possibilities in many instances. To be sure, some could do little save hope for a better order in the future, but many were trying to fulfill positive, if diverse expectations, even with regard to work itself. And while they lacked fundamental control, workers could influence the rate of mechanization and the conditions under which machines were introduced, in several key industries. They could deflect new work systems, such as the bonus payment method in Germany. Through unions and even some company committees they might gain a sense of communication with their employers. Where their influence lessened on the job, as undoubtedly occurred in many factories, they might develop new reasons for pride and identity outside the job. And their protest was designed to enhance their adaptations in many instances, for unless we regard the class as suddenly benighted there is no reason to expect them not to try to rebel had they keenly felt the need — as their brethren were doing in more repressive, early industrial situations in these very years. Adaptation was incomplete, even tragically so; but it was a process of great import for the future of the class as well as the ability of turn-of-the-century workers to get through their lives.
The theme of diversity has been sounded often enough in the preceding chapters. Its existence does not preclude generalization about the work culture that developed in this period, but it inevitably
complicates judgements that have been based only on the most articulately aggrieved segment of the working class. At an extreme, the conventional approach simply asserts that a vanguard represented the whole: a student of pre-war unrest in Britain, for example, writes that 'the majority of British workers were involved in the strikes, sympathetically if not actively.'15 This kind of statement is irresponsible without a careful effort at proof, and this in turn compels serious study of non-protesters as well as protesters. For some topics, the working class simply cannot serve as an analytical unit, yet we have too often judged the whole class by only one group. A French observer talks of workers' mobility aspirations in bourgeois terms that really fit only the artisans. German workers' family habits, including late marriage age, have been overgeneralized from the artisans' styles. On the other hand British workers in the period have been judged too often from the standpoint of engineers alone, and their tensions therefore exaggerated. And although less commonly discussed, important gaps persisted between the unskilled and the rest of the working class.16 For a variety of judgements, a more detailed breakdown commonly proves desirable. The differences between traditional and urbanized artisans, or between miners and machine workers, were considerable. The accompanying chart, which attempts a capsule summary of key distinctions, suggests the variety in reactions to work. Neither unemployment rates nor technological change nor company structure predicts alienation clearly, though each played some role. Ability to discern a job choice was most clearly related to work satisfaction, though this approaches a tautology. Reaction to work, in turn, predicts little about patterns of behavior off the job or strike goals; it may, at most, relate to socialist fervor, and that mainly on the Continent. Exposure to unemployment and/or hard physical labor undoubtedly conduced to a propensity to violence and, quite possibly, to a masculine culture that slowed the willingness to restrict the birth rate.17 This distinguished skilled construction workers from other artisans, and dockers from most factory workers. Patterns of job choice and the kind of parental guidance workers received tended to solidify behavioral distinctions even among factory workers.
The result is a variety of occupational subgroups that qualifies almost any generalization about working-class behavior. Furthermore, the desirability of distinguishing work experience by sex and age has emerged at a number of points. That formal employment played a distinctive role for most working-class women is hardly surprising, though it needs some reinforcement against a tendency of some
Table I Characteristics of Industrial Categories (H = high, M = medium, L = low)
Industrial Growth |
Job Choice |
Unemployment |
Feminization |
Security & Promotion Systems |
Adaptability to Technology |
Pressure on Work Pace |
Pressure to Reduce Hours |
Company Size |
|
Domestic Manufacturing |
L |
M |
H |
H |
L |
L |
L |
L |
L |
Traditional Artisans (bakers, etc) |
L |
H |
H |
L |
M |
M |
L |
M |
L |
Modernized Artisans (printers, urban woodworkers, etc) |
M |
H |
M |
M |
M |
M |
M |
H |
M |
Construction |
H |
M |
H |
L |
M |
L |
L |
H |
M |
Textiles, Shoes |
L |
M |
M |
H |
M |
M |
M |
M |
M |
Metals, Machines |
H |
H |
M |
M |
H |
M |
H |
M |
M |
Metallurgy |
H |
H |
L |
L |
H |
H |
H |
L |
H |
Mines |
H |
M |
L |
L |
M |
M |
M |
H |
H |
Rails |
M |
H |
L |
L |
H |
H |
M |
M |
H |
Unskilled |
M |
L |
H |
M |
L |
L |
M |
L |
M |
New Workers/rural background |
M |
L |
H |
- |
L |
L |
L |
L |
- |
Women |
M |
L |
L |
- |
L |
M |
M |
L |
- |
Probable Work Alienation |
Wage Rates |
Adaptive Consumption /Recreation Patterns |
Modernized Family Structures |
Strike Rate |
Violence |
Sophistication of Strike Goals |
Probable Socialist Fervor |
|
Domestic Manufacturing |
M? |
L |
L |
L |
L |
L |
L |
L |
Traditional Artisans (bakers, etc) |
L |
L |
L |
L |
L |
L |
M |
L |
Modernized Artisans (printers, urban woodworkers etc) |
L |
H |
H |
H |
M |
L |
H |
M |
Construction |
L |
H |
M |
M |
H |
H |
H |
M |
Textiles, Shoes |
H |
M |
M |
H |
M |
L |
M |
H |
Metals, Machines |
M |
H |
H |
M |
M |
L |
M |
M |
Metallurgy |
L |
H |
H |
L |
L |
L |
M |
L |
Mines |
M |
H |
M |
L |
H |
H |
H |
M |
Rails |
L |
M |
M |
M |
M |
M |
M |
M |
Unskilled |
H |
L |
L |
L |
M |
H |
M |
? |
New Workers/rural background |
M |
L |
L |
L |
L |
? |
L |
L |
Women |
M |
L |
M |
- |
L |
L |
M |
L |
women's historians to judge their subjects in male terms and thereby to exaggerate the importance of factory labor in the lives of working-class women. If only because of discrimination in wage and skill levels, most women were encouraged to see employment as a temporary experience, and this in turn ironically limited some key grievances on the job. Changes in employment patterns were exceedingly important during the period as women with jobs faced several major adjustments, but there was little sign that a new work culture resulted. The gradations of age within the working class are vital too, though harder to categorize. Despite the fact that workers increasingly won some protection for their later years on the job, older age remained a time of deterioration in outlook as well as physical strength. Yet older workers played a rising role in the whole working class, as longevity improved and the class slowed in growth.
Hence working-class culture, even toward work itself, was an amalgam, not a unity. Even where different categories of workers participated in unions or, as we have tentatively suggested, the socialist movement, they sought different goals from their protest. Recognition of this diversity, which encompasses workers with many good reasons not to participate in collective action at all, is the final reason for a presentation that may seem to discover more adaptations, as well as far more complexities, than some students of labor would expect.
Yet the primary purpose of the book is not to debunk. Indeed it does not thoroughly challenge any of the careful judgements of the unrest in the period, for all was far from well within the working class. What the book has captured, hopefully, is a major stage of development in industrial labor. It certainly questions any notion that industrialization's essential work had been achieved with the advent of factory machinery. The working class had not been formed. The persistence of important pre-industrial customs into the late nineteenth century, ranging from leisure patterns to low marriage rates (e.g. the German docks and traditional crafts) shows how much remained to be done.
We cannot, of course, claim that a class had been fully formed even in the mature industrial period. Off-the-job adaptations, which became increasingly important in working-class life, created new gaps of real importance — in family life, consumption patterns, and recreational styles. The utility of the working class as an analytical unit must depend on the degree of simplification desirable and the kind of behavior being discussed. In work, however, a more common culture was being forged. This will seem surprising only to those who have exaggerated the common bonds of, say, artisans and factory labor in
the earlier industrial period.18 This is not total unity. Between artisans and skilled factory workers the differential success of the craft defense opened a new rift. Artisans in the larger cities emerged with important protections for key work values, quite apart from their distinctive family and consumption adaptations.19 Indeed the whole artisanal approach, in its successful blend of pre-modern and modern values, resembles the adaptations of the older professions, such as medicine and law, to industrial society, which mark them off within the middle class. But if we speak of a work culture as a range, to he modified hy occupational group, age, and sex, we can pin down an important product of the mature industrial period; for the spread of new work tensions to the unskilled and to craftsmen brought them closer to other workers in this one aspect of their lives.
What we have called the mature period of industrialization involved several key elements. First, a regularization and intensification of work, involving new forms of supervision, a tendency toward reduction of work time, and a reduction of personal initiative on the job as well as a new round of technological change. Many workers tried to protest the new work systems, with some success in a few areas. But this was not a period of massive confrontation between industrial and anti-industrial mentalities, differing vitally in this respect from the first industrial stage. Workers were sufficiently attuned to certain kinds of change, sufficiently despairing of their ability to deflect others. Their means of adaptation included important developments off the job, even though these were often inadequate as compensations. They included a varie ty of individual options; for both new workers and old the significance of personal decisions, from initial job choice to later reactions to change, has to be stressed. Often the individual impulse warred with the collective, and one reason for the prevalence of wage protests over work protests was that wage gains left important individual freedom in terms of behavior off the job. Collective action was also colored by the commitment of most of the formal labor movement to key principles of industrial work. The period thus saw the development or extension of the industrial form of work; important adaptations on the part of workers, on the job and off; an ongoing tension between traditional values and adaptation, again off the job as well as on, which would occasionally surface in protests, even against the wishes of organized labor; but a protest pattern that, while massive, worked mainly within the system of industrial work, not against it.
The tension between adaptation and job conservatism was crucial, creating an ambiguous culture of work that was the period's main
contribution to the future. The maturation of industry involved conscious decisions about what jobs to take and what unemployment to accept; both suggested a quest for some satisfaction and stability in the work itself. Obviously conservatism was steadily challenged in the period, and workers were hampered by traditionalism as well as limited means in developing compensations off the job. But, for many, there were some escape hatches, as in new recreation outlets, while changes at work were sometimes sufficiently gradual, sometimes even partially beneficial in terms of general expectations, to be assimilated without total alienation. For a significant minority, however, job problems were felt more keenly, and off-the-job compensations were insufficient or even threatening. Protest, serving as part of the adaptation process for many, also encompassed the more bitter strand.
In broad outline, this model of limited adaptation seems applicable across regional and national boundaries. National distinctions can be largely predicted from the recency of industrialization. Some, in addition, result from the different combination of sub-groups involved; Britain a higher percentage of miners, France of domestic manufacturing workers, and so on. Britain undeniably reflected not only its greater industrial experience but also the fact that, alone of all industrial countries, it had gone through a full first industrial phase. In France, certainly in Germany, the exposure of most workers to the mature forms of industrial labor occurred without the mediating experience of less advanced structures. Most workers, in other words, came directly from craft or farm into factories that, from the standpoint of the normal British plant of even the mid-nineteenth century, were quite advanced. Here was one possible cause of the more extreme political reactions of the Continental labor force. In Britain, prior factory experience helped give workers a somewhat greater sense of values than could be reasonably defended against new forms — in the long run, perhaps, a greater on-the-job conservatism. This was particularly true in engineering, where early industrial skill patterns and team work were far harder to mesh with new incentive systems than in German industry. Belgium stands out for its rural base, which complicates generalizations based on length of industrial experience alone. The French labor force is distinguished as much by the adaptability of its artisans to new techniques and business forms as by the size of its artisanal sector - here was an area in which more productivity gains were made, as part of industrialization, than in Germany or even Britain. Differences in union organization obviously played an important role in adaptations to work; so did employer behavior, which varied
for example in the degree of paternalism involved.
Yet the general point that national differences flowed largely from stage of industrialization remains the principal conclusion. An increasingly similar industrial framework imposed a common work culture. If more visible in Britain, a craft unionism developed everywhere and manifested similar policies toward the job and its compensations. Employer behavior was not a national constant. Other standard generalizations prove not to hold. British workers were not technologically laggard, German workers not work-happy. Differences here resulted mainly from the understandable persistence of more traditional work patterns in Germany, which ranged from longer hours through a slower pace to frequent job changing. Differentials within the working class, in terms of the work experience and reaction to it, vary in degree but not in kind across national boundaries — as, for example, in patterns of family structure. German workers were less satisfied with their work than British, but this was a function of their more abrupt exposure to industrial labor and their far lower earning level. Again, an argument in terms of 'stages,' rather than nationality, makes general sense for this industrial zone of Europe.
Furthermore, it seems probable that the new, admittedly ambiguous, patterns of adaptation to work apply to other areas that reached the mature industrial level around 1900. Where the changes in work were more abrupt the overt protest rate was higher. In the United State s, for example, the per capita strike rate was twice that of the European countries studied during the same period. But the issues were similar, if predictably more radical: they consisted of a mixture of demands for a new share in industrial decisions, which was the closest Large groups of workers came to questioning the whole work system, and a desire for higher pay and shorter hours which suggested movement toward a new balance of work and leisure within the industrial system.2 °
Whether the themes of the period fit societies whose industrial maturity came later must await other studies that get beneath the surface of formal labor history. One point must be stressed: for Europe (and the United States) the pre-war decades were immensely complicated by the limitations on improvements in real wages. Here was an important restraint on a full conversion to an instrumental approach to work, in which change might be more fully accepted because of compensatory benefits. This had an enduring impact in Britain, where of all the industrial countries workers were in the best position to develop new consumption expectations and recreation patterns. These outlets did serve to limit job tensions, but their development was
stunted by the stagnation of living standards. Hence British workers, although far more attuned to a rapid pace of work than their Continental counterparts, grew increasingly suspicious, tenacious of things as they were. The result has been the kind of labor conservatism that has complicated Britain's industrial advance but which was, as the comparative approach suggests, essentially new. A country like Germany, that depended less on the efficiency of the individual worker, suffered less from a defensive mentality at work. But everywhere the anguishing clash between job pressures and consumption limitations affected the adjustment to new work systems. Unhappily it distracted, as we have seen, from the development of a clear set of goals for work itself, so that where sheer conservatism could not prevail, as was the case even in Britain despite the waning dynamism of many entre-preneuers, workers faced a serious challenge to any job satisfaction.
The development of a common work culture does not predict glowing uniformity in the future, even within the industrial zone of Europe encompassed in this study. Quite apart from new distinctions in the labor movement, and later in strikes, that opened up after World War I, we cannot assume that the newer industrial countries would evolve toward the patterns suggested by the more advanced. German workers, for example, did not quickly find the standard of living which would allow them to develop the compensatory culture that had at least been sketched in Britain. And we have already suggested that it is hard to avoid the conclusion that the British work experience was peculiarly traumatic, precisely because more advanced expectations had developed, only to be frustrated by the trend of real wages. The British working class was more fully formed by 1914; its touchiness about changes in work, the fruit of the transition that aborted for lack of compensatory wage gains, was more likely to endure.
Even for the future, however, national variations were on a single main theme. Admitting that there was much history still to come, in the decades after 1914, what emerges most strongly from the examination of work in the mature industrial period is that a durably ambiguous outlook toward work had been forged.
Certainly the correspondence between the work culture that had developed in key sectors of the working class and contemporary alienation in the factories is strong — and equally complex. This is not the horribly simple alienation described in nineteenth-century social thought, which at most captured a brief moment in the industrial work experience. What workers resent is much more prosaic; its tragedy lies not in its monumental quality but in its persistence — which the
historical perspective reveals so clearly — and the inability of workers to remedy their situation despite a century of serious agitation.
The concern that promotions within the plant go to undeserving individuals continues not only to annoy workers but to jeopardize their own sense of professional worth. The lack of knowledge of the whole production process or of workers in other units in a highly differentiated factory has been heightened by the extension of assembly line techniques, but it was noted in a Saxon engineering works in the 1890s. Complaints about meaninglessness, oversupervision, and powerlessness form another common theme. ;Most compelling is the continuity of the sense of nervousness first reported in the pre-war period. Contemporary workers, too, report a relationship between their jobs and their mental health. Many are still unable to use leisure activities to compensate for an unsatisfactory work situation, and while improvements in overall conditions have brought some relief to family life many still come home in a mood of grumpy exhaustion that is hard to shake off.21
Yet again the ambiguities, which a historical perspective helps explain. Neither at present nor before World War I was alienation complete or uniform. Most workers do not report being bored by their jobs. Many skilled workers do not even claim an instrumental outlook toward work. They expect their jobs to be interesting and believe they can create interest themselves when necessary. Semi-skilled workers expect less from work and are pleasantly surprised when it catches their fancy. But, though instrumental in assigning largely extrinsic reasons for their job satisfaction, they do not display some of the tensions one might expect. In particular they are less hostile to management than skilled workers are; as we have seen the relationship between work and class antogonisms is extremely complex in a rationalized industrial operation. Skilled workers, with more precise expectations about their supervisors' functions and their own right to independence, are at once more pleased with their jobs and more critical of management. Here, but also within a given skill category, prior ideas about work, of the sort that go into initial job choice, continue to condition reactions. As was the case earlier in the twentieth century, it is impossible to homogenize the working-class experience. Factors of skill, age, and individual personality prevent sweeping generalizations even about factory workers alone. But the kind of tension that developed with the maturation of industry remains. Workers want to choose their jobs on the basis of interesting work, still ranking this over good pay. They do not, overall, take a completely instrumental approach even when their
jobs prove disappointing — the fact that their leisure activities are not sufficiently rewarding in themselves being both cause and result of this dilemma. Hence American workers talk of continuing to work even if they were not compelled, not because of enjoyment but rather to fill time for lack of interesting alternatives; while in Europe workers approaching retirement frequently have second thoughts about cutting their ties to the job completely. A few pockets of workers can be found who take no joy in their work and expected none, having chosen on the basis of high earnings alone, but these are not typical.22 And even these workers produce no clear formulas for improving their situation and feel abandoned by the labor movement in this respect. Hence the overall impression of continuity: a desire for interesting work, a lack of thorough satisfaction in the work found — the widespread reports of a belief that another kind of work would be chosen if the worker had it to do over again echo the German polls of seventy years before — but a corresponding lack of sufficient dissatisfaction to serve as the basis for any but individual acts of disgruntlement.23
The historical perspective enhances an appreciation of the contemporary work culture in several regards, again without claiming total continuity,. Workers never benefited, or suffered, from a bourgeois devotion to work; we are not therefore witnessing a declension from some past golden age of zeal, as some contemporary detractors of the working class would have it. The traditional approach to work, which laborers brought into the period of industrial maturity, consisted of a willingness to build life around long hours of slow, often rather dull toil. Challenged by new conditions, workers replaced this with a culture incompletely integrated, but successful enough to survive for several generations at least. The culture decidedly antedates some of the conditions contemporary sociologists suppose to have caused it, most notably preceding the full advent of assembly Une operations, which exacerbated but did not change its basic dimensions. At the same time, the origins of the culture help explain ambiguities that continue to puzzle contemporary observers. Workers' unwillingness to report intense dissatisfaction with their jobs is real, and the many pollsters who dismiss it as superficial may err in their desire to measure against some genuine, 'intrinsic,' work ethic that the working class admittedly has not shared. When the inquiries attempt to go deeper, through questions about alternatives and what might have been if workers could start all over again, they risk — as they did around 1900 - triggering a middle-class but surface response, for workers have long known what jobs were held in higher esteem by their interlocutors.
But the lack of a single-minded attitude toward work shows through at many points. The 'likes of us' approach continues to explain some of the ambiguities: this is a good enough job for me but frankly I would have preferred more.24 On a more collective basis it is hard to avoid the conclusion that most workers continue to find it difficult to protest job deficiencies directly, save in very specific respects. Tempted constantly to judge work by traditional standards, workers before World War I realized that a thorough protest on this basis would be futile and, in some respects, undesirable. But the failure to develop new protest canons is one reason the ambiguous relationship to work has persisted so long.
The approach toward compensations for work is just as ambivalent, and again this reflects the durability of the industrial culture. Workers undoubtedly built more of their lives outside the job, which made alleviations such as shorter hours positively desirable. But this was not a complete conversion to instrumentality; hence few workers thought or think in terms of wages alone.25 They did not abandon the idea that work should offer some enjoyment and they did not develop an off-the-job culture that would make good a joyless job. Something of a vicious circle continues here, for problems at work still plague leisure hours, while many workers are unable to break through to earnings sufficient to develop elaborate recreational outlets. It is in this circle, rather than in work culture alone, that the working class emerged so different from their nearest neighbors in the middle class. The clerks of the lower middle class probably began with a work culture similar to that of the traditional lower class, at least in their willingness to endure long hours; while their felt relationship to management undoubtedly differed. But what endured was not a classic bourgeois work ethic but a sharply defined balance between work and family/consumption that the working class as a whole has never achieved.26 Among other things this produced a much less qualified attitude toward retirement than the working class maintains.27
For in its attitude toward aging, the enduring working-class culture has proved severely limiting, now that its causes have been partially overcome. Unpleasant work heightened the belief that age would be a time of trouble; for if work was disappointing now, what would it be when one's strength began to decline? Job frustration, even apart from the continuing dangers of manufacturing work, often made prophecy self-fulfilling, and many workers aged badly. On the job, older workers tended to grow apathetic. Generational conflict was almost built into the culture, as young workers, eager to make a sensible job choice but
commonly disappointed once the choice was made, quarreled with their elders who had become resigned to their work; this split continues to hamper any general rebellion against unsatisfactory work.28 The persistent image of exhaustion with age became increasingly dis-functional for older workers themselves. Many failed to contemplate retirement at all: 'I never thought of stopping work. I thought I'd be dead before, I was so tired,' said one disenchanted pensioner; and another: T never thought of stopping at all. I lacked foresight.'29 This outlook led many, as in France, to see retirement in terms of repose, greatly desired but often disappointing once achieved. 'While one works it is hard but one feels that one lives like other people,' said one bored French retiree recently.30 The common inability to develop entertaining leisure activities clearly persists with age. Still worse: expectations of exhaustion lead to psychosomatic problems that loom far larger among workers than among other classes, again a holdover from the formation of the new reaction toward work.31
The deep roots of the work culture are profoundly troubling. Specific strands, even with regard to protest orientation, have outlived their usefulness, for attitudes were formed whose persistence did not depend on any specific set of material conditions. Their rootedness must cause1 some skepticism over claims that some new set of work relationships — the automated factory, for example32 —will smooth out the ambiguities and create a more thorough sense of job satisfaction. With the outlook toward aging, we have clearly reached a point where image contributes to reality, even when reality itself is not bad enough; the resultant dissatisfaction, often unfocused, may not quickly dissipate.33
Yet both the historical and most of the contemporary evidence warns against dwelling on alienation alone, which is really why the work culture has persisted despite its incompleteness. Two related historical points here. Bad as the picture detailed in this study is, we cannot claim that it is worse than the lower classes experienced in pre-industrial, not to mention early industrial, decades. We know little about pre-industrial levels of job satisfaction. It seems logical to assume them relatively high among artisans, though the problems of personal dependence, which persisted so far into the twentieth century, should not be minimized. Assumptions of joy in rural, particularly agricultural, labor are more dubious, calling into question any simple notion of non-alienated workers suddenly forced into the alien world of industrialization. This is not an anti-bucolic manifesto; we lack the evidence one way or another. But urbanités, including historians, have
found ways of magnifying the joys of rural life, even a postiori. Certainly once industrialization began, all the evidence points to an increasing if incomplete adaptation to manufacturing labor, well into the inter-war period if not beyond. In the present study, materials from Germany suggest that levels of dissatisfaction among workers new to industry were quite high, though some cushioned shock by maintaining essentially a traditional work pattern amid substantial signs of boredom. With time, the acceptance of modern work system increased. Parental guidance would give greater importance to factory skills; satisfaction with having regular work might increase as new attitudes toward unemployment developed. Though to an outsider they might seem self-deluding, workers came to require a sense of worth in their jobs — hence the sardine packers in Britanny who knew they were better than machines or the Welsh miners who enjoyed filling a wagon with good coal. Along with new interests in family and recreation, these attitudes made work increasingly endurable as the working class matured. Hence even in pre-war Germany job satisfaction was often highest where the industry was most fully modernized. It was almost surely higher in Britain in the same period, and it would be higher in Germany — despite the advent of the assembly line — a decade or two later.34
Other factors would intervene, of course. In claiming that the maturation of industry shaped a durable work culture "we cannot ignore the many changes that developed from World War I onward. Rising education, the changing balance among industries, the increasing feminization of manufacturing work, the improvements in education as well as the advent of the assembly line — these and many other trends need historical evaluation before the degree of continuity can be stated with any precision.
Without question, however, the basic culture toward work has persisted. Indeed, the multi-faceted work ethic that developed when sheer traditionalism no longer sufficed has been self-reinforcing. This is obviously true in the case of women's work. Women did not commit themselves to work in the male sense. They were therefore slow to resent inequalities, as in wages, abetted by the fact that many males, including labor leaders, were not particularly encouraging in this direction. Why worry too much about wages, which were better than servants' wages anyway, when work was not permanent? But in not pressing for better work conditions women left their jobs sufficiently unattractive that few would wish to retain them after marriage and most would see marriage as the logical result of their formal
employment. Another vicious circle, or at least a circle, that remained into the 1940s and is still with us in part. More generally, the failure to develop specific, widely-applicable canons of protest relating to the job — for even strikes for union recognition or other new forms of control rarely, in the factories, made it clear what changes in the nature of work would result from success — tended to perpetuate workers' partial job satisfaction. Seemingly prosaic issues such as the piece rate hampered the labor movements from developing clear standards for on-the-job conditions, for finding that workers did not agree among themselves, they turned to their more sweeping plans for a new society and/or to improving conditions off the job, mainly through better wages. So workers have not been encouraged to re-evaluate their outlook toward work, and when specific groups have done so they have typically found themselves leaderless, often opposed both by older workers and by the labor movement. Whether this is high tragedy or not depends on one's valuation of the quality of the job satisfactions workers developed with maturing industry. Without belittling these satisfactions, the sense that they are second choice, 'for the likes of us,' so common in 1900 as today, qualifies them seriously. To the extent that specific protest goals failed to change as work itself was becoming modernized, the result of a number of factors bearing on the pre-1914 period particularly, workers were left with an approach that could neither ignore work in favor of other satisfactions or develop full pleasure in it, yet an approach which would also make it difficult to envisage realistic alternatives.
Thus a period in which the framework of labor was being transformed failed to see a complete transformation in class culture. The legacy has been a working class eager to find satisfaction in the job, increasingly able to do so in terms of job choice and family stability, but buffeted by one change after another — hence the enduring tension between hope and reality. In combination with the orientation of the labor movement it would be unable to mount directly job-based protest, in any general movement that was given high priority among other goals. Individuals would escape the class altogether, leaving the worst jobs to other newcomers, but this would only reduce the possibility of corrective action for the class as a whole. A break may come. We see signs of a new, more belligerent stance toward the job. But any widespread reorientation must cut through a powerful if ambiguous outlook, that goes far back in the industrial past and that, for all its weaknesses, has enabled countless workers to get through life without feeling completely useless. It is legitimate to regret a culture
that neither pulled workers away from their jobs nor told them how to make their jobs satisfying. Lacking basic control of the economic system, unwilling to fight the system directly, most workers made do with a mixture of disgruntlement and small pleasures — a mixture that confuses outside observers and serves the class still.
Notes
1. Wil Jon Edwards, From the Valley I Came (London, 1958); Heinrich Herkner, Problème der Arbeiterpsyehologie (Leipzig, 1912).
2. A. L. Levine, Industrial Retardation in Britain (London, 1967).
3. This has been noted as an important element among contemporary workers as well. See Dorothy Wedderburrt and Rosemary Crompton, Workers' Attitudes and Technology (Cambridge, 1972), 118.
4. Ibid., 118 ff.
5. Standish Meacham, ' "The Sense of an Impending Clash": English Working-Class Unrest before the First World War,' American Historical Review (1972), 1343-64.
6. Elise Herrmann, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft in der Wollhutsindustrie (Munich, 1912); see also Clemens Heiss, Die Entlôhnungsmethoden in der Berliner Feinmechanik (Berlin, 1909), 222-3.
7. David Crew, 'Definitions of Modernity: Social Mobility in a German Town, 1880-1901,' Journal of Social History (1973), 51-74.
8. Hans Hinke, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiter im Buchdrutck-gewerbe (Berlin, 1910); Joan Scott, The Glasswarkers of Carmaux (Cambridge, Mass., 1974), 167 ff.
9. Marie Bernays, Auslese und Anpassung der Arbeiterschaft der geschlosene Grossindustrie (Leipzig, 1910), 171 ff.; Charlotte Leubuscher, Der Arbeitskampf der englischen Eisenbahner im Jahre 1911 (Munich, 1913), 48.
10. Crew, 'Modernity,' passim; H. A. Clegg et al., A History of British Trade Unionism since 1889 (Oxford, 1964), I, 348-52; J. Zitzlaff, Arbeitsgleiderung in Maschinenbau Unternehmungen (Jena, 1913); Richard Ehrenberg and Hugo Racine, Krupp'sche Arbeiter-Familien (Jena, 1912), 369 ff.; Eugen Fraenkel, 'Die Lage der Arbeiter in den Werkstâtten der bayerischen Staatsbahne,' Archiv fur Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik (1913), 808 ff.
11. Crew, 'Modernity,' passim; see also Robert Tressell, The Ragged-Trousered Philanthropists (London, 1955), passim.
12. Arthur L. Bowley, The Change in the Distribution of the National Income, 1880-1913 (Oxford, 1920), 11.
13. Daniel Walkowitz, 'Working-Class Women in the Gilded Age:
Factory, Community and Family Life among Cohoes, New York Cotton Workers,' Journal of Social History (1972), 464 ff; Stephan Thernstrom, Poverty and Progress: Social Mobility in a Nineteenth Century City (Cambridge, Mass., 1964); Eric Hobsbawm, 'Custom, Wages and Work Load,' in Labouring Men (New York, 1964).
14. George Dangerfield, The Strange Death of Liberal England (New York, 1961), 233.
15. Adeline Daumard, 'L'Evolution des structures sociales en France à l'époque de l'industrialisation (1815-1914),' in P. Léon, éd., L'Industrialisation en Europe au XIXe Siècle (Paris, 1972), 314—28; R. R. Neuman, 'The Sexual Question and Social Democracy in Imperial Germany,' Journal of Social History (1974); Levine, Retardation, passim; Hobsbawm, 'Custom,' passim.
16. E. H. Phelps Brown, Growth of British Industrial Relations (London, 1959), 8 ff.
17. William Sewell, 'Artisans and Proletarian: Social Change and the Rise of Working-Class Politics in Marseilles,' Past and Present (1974).
18. Alexander Wende, Die Konzentrationbewegung bei den deutschen Gewerkschaften (Berlin, 1913), 56.
19. David Montgomery, 'The "New Unionism" and the Transformation of Workers' Consciousness in America, 1909—1922,' Journal of Social History (1974), passim.
20. Sar A. Levitan, éd., Blue Collar Workers (New York, 1971), 89; Work in America (Cambridge, Mass., 1972), 13 ff.; Wedderburn and Crompton, Attitudes, passim; Jon M. Shepard, Automation and Alienation (Cambridge, Mass., 1971), 26;Ferdynand Zweig, Workers in an Affluent Society (New York, 1962).
21. J. H. Goldthorpe et al., The Affluent Worker in the Class Structure (Cambridge, 1968), passim.
22. Levitan, Blue Collar, 89; Wedderburn and Crompton, Attitudes, 23; J. H. Goldthorpe, 'Attitudes and Behaviour of Car Assembly Workers: A Deviant Case and a Theoretical Critique,' British Journal of Sociology (1966), 240; Goldthorpe et al., Affluent Worker, passim: Caisse national de retraite des ouvriers du bâtiment et des travaux publics, Réalités du troisième âge: Enquête sur les ouvriers retraités du bâtiment et des travaux publiques (Paris, 1968), 16 ff., 88.
23. Levitan, Blue Collar, passim.
24. Hobsbawm, 'Custom,' thus exaggerates and simplifies the conversion to instrumentality.
25. Peter Willmott and Michael Young. Family and Class in a London Suburb (London, 1960), 77 ff. In this sense I find the argument in Goldthorpe et al., Affluent Worker, deficient in its exaggeration of workers' job discontents and particularly in its strange beatification of the lower-middle-class work experience.
26. Jean Daric, Vieillissement de la population et prolongation de la vie active (Paris, 1948), 60 ff. In the late 1950s a poll of Parisian workers showed that 79% of the retired manual workers regretted their lack of work, compared to only 54% in the white collar group. Fourteen percent did not regret it compared to 39% of the white collar group. These differences are admittedly colored by variations in pension fund adequacy, but they are nevertheless suggestive, J.-R. Tréanton, 'Les Réactions à la retraite,' Revue française du travail (1958), 154—5.
27. Work in America, 14.
28. Tre'anton,'Réactions,' 156.
29. Ann Lauran, L'Age scandaleux (Paris, 1971), 21.
30. Caisse nationale de retraite des ouvriers du bâtiment et des travaux publics, Enquête, passim',
31. Robert Blauner, Alienation and Freedom (Chicago, 1964).
32. Goldthorpe et al., Affluent Worker.
33. H. de Man, Joy in Work (1928). See also a French poll of the late 1950s, in which 62% of all manual workers professed to like their work at least somewhat; only 23% said they were really dissatisfied; Tréanton, 'Réaction,' 156.
34. H. De Man, Joy in Work (London, 1928), passim.